Buy Now or Buy Later

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 7/21/2019 Buy Now or Buy Later

    1/16

    Journal of Marketing Theory and Practice, vol. 21, no. 4 (fall 2013), pp. 441455 2013 M.E. Sharpe, Inc. All rights reserved. Permissions: www.copyright.com

    ISSN 10696679 (print) / ISSN 19447175 (online

    DOI: 10.2753/MTP1069-6679210407

    In the wake of the most crippling economic downturn

    since the Great Depression, Americans have curbed their

    shopping habits, and retailers are trying to adapt. Experts

    do not expect the financial circumstances and buying prac-tices of the average consumer to bounce back as they have

    after past recessions (International Council of Shopping

    Centers 2009), which means that value-based pricinga

    staple of retailmay be shortsighted (Anderson, Wouters,

    and van Rossum 2010).

    A new consumer requires a new strategy. Instead of sell-

    ing a high volume of the same product at minimal margins

    above cost, it may be more beneficial to implement a pricing

    strategy that will (1) drive customers to visit the store more

    frequently; (2) allow for a smaller inventory, and therefore

    decrease warehouse costs; and (3) maximize profits forparticular items by understanding how scarcity and price

    promotions influence the purchase decision.

    In an effort to protect fragile margins, some retailers have

    begun to lower inventory to avoid offering huge discounts

    on overstocked products; however, rising costs continue

    to exert pressure on these firms (Holmes 2011). Although

    pricing strategy has received a great deal of attention in

    the literature (e.g., Samli and Jacobs 1993), the subarea of

    price promotions is underdeveloped (Sivakumar 1996). The

    current research investigates a pricing strategy that employs

    the counteracting effects of product scarcity and a known

    price decrease on the same purchase decision. Essentially

    the store offers some product in limited supply and then

    lowers the price incrementally over the coming days orweeks until all are sold. The customer has full knowledge

    of the number of items remaining as well as the timing

    and amount of the discount schedule, which is posted on

    a sign or the price tag. A typical price tag on a shirt may

    read: $100April 1 through April 7; $75April 8 through

    April 14; $50April 15 through April 21; $25April 22 and

    after. The strategy combines the techniques of Dutch auc

    tions and price skimming but differs in that there is often

    more than one item and the customer has full knowledge

    of the price decrease.

    The decision is whether to buy the product at the currenthigher price or at the future, lower price, with the implied

    risk of the product no longer being available. This strategy

    is commonly seen in consignment shops, flea markets, and

    garage sales, but we posit that it could be applied to the

    broader retail sector. Specifically, traditional retailers often

    need to sell seasonal merchandise to make room for new

    inventory. This model may help retailers sell their remain-

    ing inventory more quickly and at a higher profit margin

    We call it the steadily increasing discount (SID) model

    because it shares a foundation with Tsiros and Hardestys

    (2010) steadily decreasing discounting (SDD) model for

    ending a price promotion. Whereas the SDD model sug-

    gests that firms can maximize profits by bringing a heavily

    discounted product back to its normal price in steps rather

    than all at once, the SID predicts that firms can maximize

    profits on the front end by gradually arriving at the deep

    discount in similar steps. In short, this pricing strategy

    could be used to speed up the clearance process while

    optimizing profits on those items.

    BUY NOW OR BUY LATER: THE EFFECTS OF SCARCITY ANDDISCOUNTS ON PURCHASE DECISIONS

    Colin B. Gabler and Kristy E. Reynolds

    This research investigates a burgeoning pricing strategy and its effects on purchase behavior. Drawingfrom the expected-utility and prospect theories, we test the counteracting variables of scarcity and futurediscount across two studies. We first implement a flea market scenario to demonstrate that scarcity createsemotional value that increases purchase likelihood. Next, we determine the levels of scarcity and discountthat maximize purchase in a department store context. The findings suggest that the level of discountpredicts the purchase of highly visible products; for less visible products, scarcity drives the decision.These relationships are moderated by involvement with the product class.

    Colin B. Gabler(Ph.D., University of Alabama), Assistant Profes-

    sor of Marketing, College of Business, Ohio University, Athens,

    OH, [email protected].

    Kristy E. Reynolds(Ph.D., University of Alabama), Bruno Profes-

    sor of Marketing, Culverhouse College of Commerce and Business

    Administration, University of Alabama, Tuscaloosa, AL, kreynold@

    cba.ua.edu.

  • 7/21/2019 Buy Now or Buy Later

    2/16

    442 Journal of Marketing Theory and Practice

    Few scholars have investigated the SID model, and even

    fewer retailers have adopted it. Zara International has imple-

    mented a strategy of tantalizing exclusivity (Ferdows,

    Lewis, and Machuca 2004), and Lululemon uses scarcityto attract customers (Mattioli 2012). But like Tsiros and

    Hardestys (2010) model, the SID model does not have a

    foothold in mainstream retailing. The U.S. consumer wants

    fewerbut more specificproducts, and this trend is not

    likely to change in the near future, which means the SID

    could have marketplace potential.

    We begin with a review of the literature on pricing,

    discounts, expected-utility theory, and scarcity. We then

    use prospect theory to form hypotheses that are tested and

    analyzed across two studies. Study 1 isolates the effects

    of scarcity and tests the mediation of emotional value on

    the purchase decision while Study 2 compares the effects

    of product scarcity with that of a known future discount.

    Involvement with the product class is tested as a modera-

    tor in each context (see Figure 1). We conclude the paper

    with a discussion of the important findings, implications

    for theory and managers, limitations, and future research

    directions.

    CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK

    Pricing, Discounts, and Expected-Utility Theory

    The pricing literature demonstrates that when people expect

    a price to rise, they buy now, and when they expect a price to

    drop, they wait for the sale (Jacobson and Obermiller 1990).

    But consumers view prices relative to what they paid in the

    past and what they expect to pay in the future. In effect,

    consumers create their own reference price or standard by

    which they judge the price of an item (Monroe 1973), usu-

    ally forming a range that they deem acceptable for a given

    product (Rao and Sieben 1992). So, when consumers make

    purchases, they are analyzing how much they think they

    should pay for an item relative to what they paid in the past,what the price is now, and what it will be later.

    Consumers use reference prices to make decisions about

    the quality of the product and the monetary sacrifice

    required to make the purchase (Monroe 2003). Generally,

    individuals view a deviation above their reference price

    negatively and a deviation below it positively. But a typical

    reference price is dynamicnot just because of the normal

    fluctuations of supply and demand but because of price

    promotions. Consumer reactions to price promotions are

    not always rational; they can even influence consumers to

    abandon the cost-benefit analysis that usually governs their

    decisions (Frank 2007).

    Expected-utility theory (EUT) says that when consumers

    face uncertain decisions, they try to maximize the expected

    utility of their final assets (von Neumann and Morgenstern

    1947). EUT assumes that, presented with a choice where

    the outcomes are not known, individuals will compare the

    weighted sum of option one versus the weighted sum of

    option two, where the weighted sum is the utility of each

    outcome multiplied by its probability (Mongin 1997).

    All purchase decisions can be seen as a balance between

    two types of this utility maximization. On the one hand,

    consumers manage the pricequality relationship, wanting

    to maximize the value gained for the price incurred. On the

    other hand, they view the purchase as a monetary sacrifice,

    wanting to maximize the utility (or minimize the disutil-

    ity) of spending money (Monroe 2003). When a purchase

    opportunity is unlimited, individuals place more weight

    on the pricesacrifice relationship. Because they have time

    to evaluate other indicators of quality (design, craftsman-

    Figure 1Conceptual Model

  • 7/21/2019 Buy Now or Buy Later

    3/16

    Fall 2013 443

    ship, detail, etc.), consumers view price less as an indica-

    tor of quality and more for the financial burden it incurs

    (Lichtenstein, Bloch, and Black 1988). Utility maximization

    of this relationship occurs when the price represents the

    smallest sacrifice possible. When a purchase opportunity is

    limited, individuals place more weight on maximizing the

    utility of the pricequality relationship (Suri and Monroe

    2003). Because they cannot process as much information,the price tag serves more as an indicator of quality than

    monetary sacrifice and utility maximization hinges more

    on the level of perceived quality (Suri, Kohli, and Monroe

    2007).

    Given an unlimited purchase opportunity, buying a

    discounted product represents a smaller sacrifice, and

    therefore higher utility. Using Jacobson and Obermillers

    (1990) logic, if individuals know that a price will drop in

    the future, they would be less likely to buy the product in

    the present. Thus, the knowledge of an upcoming discount

    should lead to purchase postponement.

    Scarcity, Prospect Theory, and Decisions

    Under Risk

    One way that retailers can limit the purchase opportunity

    is by manipulating scarcity. Scarcity can take the form of

    a purchase limit (e.g., Limit X per customer), a purchase

    precondition (e.g., Product X only available to those who

    buy product Y), a time limit (e.g., Call within the next

    30 seconds!), or the focus of this research, a product limit

    (e.g., Only X number of products remain!) (Inman, Peter,and Raghubir 1997). Brocks (1968) commodity theory pos-

    ited that individuals assign values to commodities based on

    their availability, viewing scarce products as more attrac-

    tive than readily available ones. Furthermore, increases in

    scarcity also lead to increases in perceived value (Cialdini

    1993) and desirability (Lynn 1989).

    Consumers normally prefer to gather information

    before the purchase decision, but retailers can induce

    excess demand to force consumers to decide before they

    are comfortable (DeGraba 1995). Apple creates one of these

    buying frenzies with each iteration of the iPad. Similarly,

    Lululemon purposely keeps a low inventory to drive faster

    purchases (Mattioli 2012). In such a restricted consumer

    setting, consumers often use availability as their main

    source of information to make the decision (Inman, Peter,

    and Raghubir 1997).

    EUT has failed to predict some very common human

    behaviors. One reason is that many studies focus on back-

    ward-looking consumer choices although most research on

    consumption shows that people, in general, are forward

    looking (Hall 1978). Another reason for the theorys lack

    of explanatory power is that money is not always the most

    important outcome in consumer decisions (Bell 1982)

    consider the people waiting in line for the newest release

    at the Apple store. But the main reason that EUT does not

    apply to many situations is that people do not always opt

    to maximize their utility.Numerous nonexpected-utility models have been devel

    oped to address this behavior. For instance, prospect theory

    says that people tend to place more weight on outcomes

    they consider to be certain than on those they consider to

    be probable. Therefore, individuals will more often choose

    a modest gain if it is a sure thing over some probability

    of a larger gain. However, when forced to choose between

    a certain modest loss and some probability of a larger loss

    individuals more often risk the larger loss (Kahneman and

    Tversky 1979).

    Suppose that Apple is selling iPads for $500 today and$450 tomorrow. This pits the certainty of a modest gain

    (full-price iPad) against the probability of a slightly larger

    gain (discounted iPad). Given an infinite number of prod

    ucts, the rational individual would wait for the lower price,

    as predicted by EUT. But what if there were 100 people who

    wanted to buy 10 iPads? Then, an iPad is a scarce com-

    modity, and the probability of obtaining one is 1 in 10, or

    10 percent. If there were 50 iPads, that probability would

    increase to 50 percent; however, if there was only one, i

    would decrease to 1 percent. Scarcity shares a theoretica

    root with probability; the literature tells us that individual

    would perceive more value and desirabilit y in the lone iPad

    than 1 of the 10, and more in 1 of the 10 iPads than 1 of

    the 50 (Cialdini 1993; Lynn 1989). Because people tend to

    overweight outcomes based on their certainty (Kahneman

    and Tversky 1979), and the probability of obtaining an item

    changes with the probability, as scarcity increases, so does

    purchase likelihood. Formally,

    Hypothesis 1: Scarcity positively influences purchase.

    But what if there is a limited number andan upcoming

    discount? Prospect theory suggests that the overweighing

    of certainty favors the risk averse in the domain of gains

    and the risk seeking in the domain of losses (Kahneman and

    Tversky 1979). Risk aversion is a personality trait that, like

    scarcity and pricing discounts, influences the probability

    that an individual will accept uncertainty over certainty

    (Burton et al. 1998). In an experiment, individuals preferred

    a definite one-week vacation to England to a 50 percent

    chance of a three-week vacation to England, France, and

  • 7/21/2019 Buy Now or Buy Later

    4/16

    444 Journal of Marketing Theory and Practice

    Italy. In the iPad scenario, the $500 product would be the

    certain one-week trip and the $450 product the uncertain

    three-week trip. In weighing the two prospects, the former

    is certain, hence increasing its prospect, but the latter has

    greater value, thus increasing its prospect. In general, the

    latter prospect increases or decreases with the number avail-

    able. An individual will be more likely to take the certain

    modest gain (product) over the probability of a larger gain(product plus discount) because the certainty of option 1

    outweighs the added value of option 2.

    Perceived Emotional Value

    Emotions are subjective states of being that involve a

    hedonic component and motivate behavior specific to that

    emotion (Baron 1992). In a shopping context, emotional

    value is the utility derived from the feelings created by

    a product (Sweeney and Soutar 2001), and we use this

    definition in our study. Cialdini (1993) found that peopleassume that something is more valuable if it is less common

    and suggested that scarcity clouds the brain and limits the

    ability to process information. This response is similar to

    that of impulse buying (Rook 1987). Both trigger emotions

    that may lead to purchase based on something other than

    attributes of the product itself. However, impulsivity is typi-

    cally a trait of the individual while scarcity is a situational

    characteristic. Accordingly, under high scarcity conditions,

    the perceived emotional value of a product should be high;

    in a low scarcity condition, the perceived emotional value

    should be low. Therefore,

    Hypothesis 2: Scarcity positively influences perceived

    emotional value.

    When time and quantity are unlimited, one can pay

    more attention to the important information and relevant

    cues. The lack of temporal pressure is associated with extra

    processing (Bozzolo and Brock 1992). In auctions and other

    scenarios where time or quantit y is limited, the emotional

    arousal compromises a persons cognitive ability, which

    decreases the number of information cues one can grasp

    to assess the decision (Dhar and Nowlis 1999). Under suchconditions, this distraction leads to decision making based

    on heuristics (Cialdini 1993). Because emotional value

    serves as a heuristic in the purchase decision, we posit that

    it will act as a mediator between scarcity and purchase.

    Therefore,

    Hypothesis 3: Perceived emotional value mediates the

    relationship between scarcity and purchase.

    Involvement with Product Class

    In the marketing literature, involvement is defined as the

    importance of a product or decision to an individual (Mittal

    1995). Involvement creates a state of arousal or motivation

    and drives us to process information more thoroughly

    (Rothschild 1984). Enduring involvement is ongoing; it is

    independent of a specific occasion, and it usually enforcesan individuals self-concept (Richins and Bloch 1986).

    While scarcity limits our ability to process informa-

    tion, it also creates two key antecedents of involvement,

    perceived risk and perceived pleasure value (Laurent and

    Kapferer 1985), each of which is fundamental in deter-

    mining the complexity and extensiveness of the cognit ive

    process (Celsi and Olson 1988). When an item is scarce,

    its perceived pleasure value increases as does the perceived

    risk of missing out on the opportunity (Bloch and Richins

    1983). An individual involved with the product class will

    process information more readily because the productand

    consequently the decisionare both more important and

    interesting.

    If an individual is involved with music, he or she cares

    about it and most likely is knowledgeable about it (Brucks

    1985). For these individuals, a scarce album would likely

    have a higher pleasure value and risk associated with its

    purchase. However, scarcity alone would not cause low-

    involvement individuals to suddenly become interested

    in music, so the pleasure value and risk will not change

    for them. Thus, scarcity will heighten the importance of

    a product for high-involvement individuals but not low-

    involvement individuals. Formally,

    Hypothesis 4: Involvement with the product class

    moderates the positive relationship between scarcity

    and purchase such that when involvement is high this

    relationship is strong and when involvement is low, this

    relationship is weak.

    STUDY 1

    Sample and Procedure

    Based on a pretest, we developed manipulations for high

    and low scarcity as well as the choice of product for the

    main study. The sample consisted of 247 undergraduate

    students at a large southeastern university. The students

    completed the survey in class using paper and pencil. When

    finished, they were given extra credit and debriefed about

    the purpose of the study. Their average age was 21 with a

    range from 18 to 35, with 45 percent male and 55 percent

  • 7/21/2019 Buy Now or Buy Later

    5/16

    Fall 2013 445

    female. The subjects identified their favorite musical art-

    ist or band and the dollar amount they would spend on

    an album of that bands first concert. Then we presented

    them with a CD-purchasing scenario. Random assignment

    to one of two scarcity conditions (high-low) placed the

    respondents at a flea market where they found that CD for

    $5 higher than the price they identified. The low-scarcity

    condition had three CDs while the high-scarcity conditionhad one. The scenario read that the flea market offered

    any unsold items at half-price the following Saturday, and

    asked subjects to decide between purchasing the CD that

    day or next week.

    Measures

    Laurent and Kapferers (1985) three-item scale (= 0.85)

    was used to measure involvement with the product classand

    Sweeney and Soutars (2001) five-item scale (= 0.91) was

    used to measure perceived emotional value. As discussed,certain individuals are more prone to buy on impulse than

    others. For that reason, Rook and Fishers (1995) modified

    impulse buying scale (= 0.91) was included as a covari-

    ate so that the emotional response of scarcity could be

    isolated. Consumers also differ on their general aversion

    to risk. Therefore, Burton et al.s (1998) four-item risk aver-

    sionscale (= 0.76), which measures the degree to which

    an individual avoids taking risks in life, was included as

    a covariate. The survey also contained a manipulation

    check for scarcity (The number of CDs at the flea market

    is . . .) using a seven-point scale ranging from (1 = low)

    to (7 = high). Appendix A contains the scenario and scale

    items after purification.Purchasewas measured as a binary

    response variable (yes/no).

    Analysis and Results

    Participants in the high-scarcity scenario described the

    CD as significantly (F(1,245) = 27.415;p < 0.001) scarcer

    (M = 5.52) than those in the low-scarcity scenario (M= 4.59).

    An interesting finding was that the amount the participants

    were willing to spend positively influenced both their likeli-

    hood to purchase (p < 0.01) and the perceived emotional

    value assigned to the CD (p < 0.001). The only gender dif-

    ference that emerged was that women placed significantly

    more emotional value than men on the CD (p < 0.05) .

    Sixty-three of the 120 respondents (53 percent) on the

    low-scarcity condition chose to buy the CD while 93 of the

    127 respondents (73 percent) on the high-scarcity condition

    chose to buy the CD (2(1,245) = 11.484,p = 0.001). This

    supports H1; despite the knowledge of a future discount

    scarcity positively influences purchase behavior. We imple

    mented Baron and Kennys (1986) three-step regression

    procedure to determine if perceived emotional value medi-

    ated the relationship between scarcity and purchase, adding

    the covariates in each step to demonstrate unique variance

    (Neubert et al. 2008). While ordinary least squares regression

    was appropriate for step 1, steps 2 and 3 required binarylogistic regression. Using a procedure developed by (MacK

    innon and Dwyer 1993), the coefficients were multiplied by

    the standard deviation of the predictor variable and then

    divided by the standard deviation of the outcome variable

    This step allowed the authors to compare continuous and

    binary variables in the same analysis (see Table 1).

    The results from step 1 support H2. Essentially, the scarcer

    the CD, the more emotional value the respondents attached

    to owning it. Step 2 replicates H1 while step 3 included both

    scarcity and perceived emotional value and tested their

    relationship with purchase. The beta for scarcity droppedwith the addition of perceived emotional value; however, i

    remained significant (p < 0.05), which exhibits partial media

    tion and support for H3. This is evidence that scarcity led

    consumers to purchase the CD, in part because they placed

    more emotional value on the idea of owning the CD.

    Finally, it is worth noting that the average amount that

    respondents were willing to spend on the CD was $23. The

    scenario specifically asked if they would pay $5 more than

    that amount. Five dollars represents an increase of 22 percen

    to the average self-reported price of $23. Therefore, scarcity

    did not just lead people to buy the CD at their upper limit

    the respondents were willing to spend, on average, 22 per-

    cent more thantheir upper limit.

    A Sobel (1982) test confirmed that the indirect effect was

    significant. The test statistic was 2.01 and was significant on

    both the one-tail (p < 0.05) and two-tail (p < 0.05). These

    results indicate that the indirect effect of the independent

    variable, scarcity, on the dependent variable, purchase

    through the mediator, perceived emotional value, was

    significant. Thus, we can conclude that the regression was

    significant on all levels.

    To test the moderating effect of involvement with the

    product class, a median split was performed to create high

    and low levels. A t-test confirmed that a high-involvement

    respondent was significantly more involved (M = 6.54)

    than someone with a low level of involvement (M= 4.49

    t(1,244) = 21.03,p < 0.001), which allowed us to treat the

    high and low levels as unique variables. Next, we conducted

    a mean difference test on both levels of involvement for the

    high- and low-scarcity conditions. We found support for H4

  • 7/21/2019 Buy Now or Buy Later

    6/16

    446 Journal of Marketing Theory and Practice

    confirmed by a difference of proportions test (Z= 0.406,

    p< 0.001). For high involvement individuals, those in the

    high-scarcity condition bought the CD 85 percent of the

    time compared to those in the low-scarcity condition who

    bought the CD 53 percent of the time. Conversely, for low

    involvement individuals, the purchase percentages did not

    change significantly as a result of the scarcity condition

    (53 percent in low-scarcity condition; 61 percent in the

    high-scarcity condition). Interestingly, in the low-scarcity

    condition, the same percentage (53 percent) of individuals

    chose to buy the CD regardless of their level of involvement

    with the product class. This means that for those with low

    involvement, the relationship between scarcity and purchase

    was not just weak, but actually nonexistent (see Figure 2).

    STUDY 2

    Study 2 was conducted to assess how the relationships from

    Study 1 might change when the level of discount is also

    manipulated. A more traditional retail setting (shopping

    for jeans in a department store) was chosen to increase

    generalizability.

    Suppose that the iPad, originally priced at $500, soldfor $375 the next day. This pits the certainty of a modest

    gain (just the iPad) against the probability of an even larger

    gain (iPad + 25 percent discount). Finally, imagine that the

    iPad sold for $250 the next day. This pits the certainty of

    a modest gain (just the iPad) against the probability of a

    much larger gain (iPad + 50 percent discount). Based on

    weighted probabilities, the first prospect remains the same

    while the second prospect gains value as the incentive, or

    discount, increases (Kahneman and Tversky 1979). Conse-

    quently, the value of the first prospect decreases relative to

    the second. At some threshold, the value added of prospect

    two outweighs the certainty of prospect one.

    Consumers use the level of perceived risk as a factor in

    product decision making (Bettman 1973), and individuals

    use availability to estimate that level of risk (Tversky and

    Kahneman 1973). We predict that when there is a lot of the

    product in stock and the manager puts that product on a

    high future discount, the risk is low, and thus the incentive

    to wait is large. If the discount was low, the possible savings

    would not be worth the wait; if fewer products were avail-

    able, the risk that they would be purchased would be high

    (Folkes 1988). In both cases, the incentive to wait decreases.

    Therefore, the most ideal time to wait for the sale is when the

    scarcity is low and the future discount is high. Conversely,

    the most ideal time for a consumer to buy the productor

    when the incentive to wait is smallestis when the product

    is scarce and the future discount is low. Formally:

    Hypothesis 5: Those in the low-scarcity and high future

    discount condition are least likely to purchase while those

    in the high-scarcity and low future discount conditionare most likely to purchase.

    As discussed, involvement is the importance of a deci-

    sion based on an individuals specific needs, values, and

    interest in that product (Zaichkowsky 1985). An unimport-

    ant purchase decision is then, by definition, uninvolving

    (Richins and Bloch 1986). Scarcity implies a perceived risk,

    which would heighten the relevance of that product to ones

    values and interests (Bloch and Richins 1983). Similar to

    Table 1

    Regression Analysis for Study 1

    Dependent Variable: Purchase

    Step 1: IV Med Step 2: IV DV Step 3: IV/Med DV

    Variable S.E. VIF S.E. S.E.

    Control Variables

    Risk Aversion 0.185 0.060* 1.000 0.060 0.122 0.030 0.131Impulse Buying 0.054 0.055 1.000 0.115 0.113 0.094 0.117

    Independent Variable

    Scarcity 0.167** 0.135 1.000 0.898*** 0.273 0.771* 0.282

    Mediator Variable

    Perceived Emotional Value 0.505*** 0.141

    Adjusted R2or Nagelkerke R2 0.054 0.068 0.141

    F(df) or (df) 5.668 (3, 242)** 12.499 (2, 244)* 26.804 (3, 243)***

    Notes:IV = independent variable; Med = mediator variable; DV = dependent variable; VIF = variance inflation factor; S.E. = standard error; df = degrees

    of freedom. Listwise n= 247. Standardized betas are reported. *p< 0.05; **p< 0.01; ***p< 0.001.

  • 7/21/2019 Buy Now or Buy Later

    7/16

    Fall 2013 447

    Study 1, we predict scarcity to accentuate the importance

    of the decision for high-involvement individuals in the

    clothing product category, making the decision more risky,

    interesting, and relevant.

    Low involvement with a product class translates to less

    arousal or motivation to process information (Rothschild

    1984). It means that the product is not as essential to ones

    self-concept (Richins and Bloch 1986) and the decision isnot as important. Therefore, for low-involvement individu-

    als, scarcity will not make the weight of the decision more

    salient. We predict it will extenuate the interest, risk, and

    importance of the decision. In fact, when consumers have

    low involvement with a product, price often acts as the

    main indicator of quality (Monroe 1973), and consequently,

    determines behavior. Studying red wine, Zaichkowsky

    (1985) found that low-involvement individuals placed more

    emphasis on price than high-involvement individuals. In

    essence, the deviation below the reference price was the

    predictor of purchase for these consumers (Winer 1986).In this study, the discount is the price cue, and we predict

    it will drive behavior for low-involvement consumers.

    Conversely, high-involvement consumers care more about

    product attributes and are willing to pay for them (Lich-

    tenstein, Bloch, and Black 1988). Generally, higher prices

    are deemed more acceptable by consumers with high

    involvement than low involvement (Bloch, Sherrell, and

    Ridgway 1986); therefore, the effect of the discount should

    be minimal for these individuals. Therefore,

    Hypothesis 6: Involvement with the product class moder-

    ates the negative relationship between future discountand purchase such that when involvement is low this

    relationship is strong and when involvement is high, this

    relationship is weak.

    Sample and Procedure

    To test H5 and H6, we manipulated both scarcity and

    future discount in a retail shopping scenario and analyzed

    their effects on the purchase decision. We conducted a

    pretest to uncover shopping habits that would adversely

    affect the data, such as hiding or reserving the product,and addressed these issues in the final scenario. For the

    main study, we employed Bitner, Booms, and Tetraults

    (1990) student recruitment method to identify subjects,

    first training them and then giving each a URL (Uniform

    Resource Locator) to present to their recruit. The students

    had the opportunity to recruit two people to participate,

    receiving extra course credit for each respondent. To vali-

    date the recruited sample, we contacted 10 percent of the

    respondents to verify their participation in the study and

    uncovered no problems.

    The participants accessed the survey through a secure

    Web site, which generated a random combination of manip

    ulations each time the URL was clicked. The recruits could

    only access the link once. The identification, recruitment

    and data collection period lasted two weeks, resulting in a

    total of 423 respondents. The mean age was 30 and ranged

    from 18 to 64, with 60 percent female and 40 percent male

    The scenario first asked the subjects to imagine that they

    needed a new pair of jeans and to identify their go-to

    brand. It then asked how much they would be willing to

    spend for a pair of jeans from that brand in the exact style

    fit, color, etc., that you are looking for. The mean pricewas $67 while both the mode and median were $50.

    The scenario placed the respondents at a store where they

    found that exact pair of jeans at the price they identified

    We manipulatedscarcityat high and low conditions, with

    ten pairs of jeans representing the low condition and two

    pairs representing the high condition. To manipulate future

    discount, the scenario contained the line Above the table

    hangs a sign that reads, All jeans 50%-off [25%-off, 10%

    off] next Saturday, which created high, moderate, and

    low conditions. The Web site then randomly assigned each

    respondent to one of the two scarcity conditions and oneof the three future discount conditions before presenting

    them with two choices: Buy the jeans today or Come

    back next Saturday to buy the jeans.

    Measures

    Laurent and Kapferers (1985) three-item scale (= 0.91)

    was again used to measure the involvement with the produc

    Figure 2Moderating Effect of Involvement for Study 1

    Low Scarcity

    High Scarcity

  • 7/21/2019 Buy Now or Buy Later

    8/16

    448 Journal of Marketing Theory and Practice

    class. Rook and Fishers (1995) modified impulse buyingscale

    (= 0.94) was included as a covariate. The survey also con-

    tained a manipulation check for scarcity (The number of

    pairs of jeans on the table is . . .) and future discount. (The

    discount being offered is . . .) using a seven-point scale

    ranging from (1 = low) to (7 = high). Appendix B contains

    the scenario and scales items after purification.

    Analysis and Results

    Both of the manipulations were successful. The partici-

    pants in the high-scarcity scenario described the jeans as

    significantly (F(1, 425) = 23.03,p < 0.001) scarcer (M= 4.50)

    than those in the low-scarcity scenario (M= 3.67). Similarly,

    the discount was rated as significantly different at each

    level (Mhi= 5.39, M

    mod= 4.29, M

    lo= 3.42,F(2, 424) = 53.22,

    p < 0.001). To determine whether scarcity and future

    discount produced a significant interaction, we tested a

    binary logist ic model. We entered three blocks separately;

    starting with the covariate (impulse buying), followed by

    the manipulated scarcity and future discount variables,and finally the interaction. We assessed the overall model

    fit after each addition.

    The first model with just impulse buying was significant

    and predicted 63.6 percent of the purchase outcomes. The

    second model, which contained the manipulated indepen-

    dent variables, showed superior fit as both the block and

    the model were significant and the percentage of correct

    predictions increased 3.1 points to 66.7 percent. The final

    block, which included the interaction term, was not signifi-

    cant and actually had less predictive power (66.3 percent),

    allowing interpretation of coefficients from model 2. To

    achieve probabilities, we used the formula, P= 1/exp(b),

    where the expected beta is the effect of the independent

    variable on the odds ratio. The resulting probability is

    the change in likelihood that an individual will purchase

    given an increase in that variable. As seen in Table 2, those

    in the high scarcity condition were 1.36 times more likely

    to buy than those in the low-scarcity condition (p < 0.01),which replicates H1 from Study 1. Those in the high future

    discount condition were 0.74 times less likely to buy than

    those in the moderate future discount condition, who were

    0.74 times less likely to buy than those in the low future

    discount condition (p < 0.01).

    We used a difference of proport ions test to analyze H5.

    Each of the six conditions produced a proportion of those

    who chose to buy the jeans. Comparing this proport ion to

    the overall proportion determined if there was a significant

    difference in any one condition. The low-scarcityhigh

    future discount condition yielded the lowest purchaseprobability (48.5 percent), which represents a significant

    difference (p < 0.05) from the average of 62.6 percent. The

    high-scarcitymoderate future discount condition yielded a

    slightly larger purchase probability (72.4 percent) than the

    high-scarcitylow future discount condition (71.2 percent).

    Because these two percentages are not significantly different

    from one another and the high-scarcitylow future discount

    is significantly different from the low-scarcityhigh future

    Table 2

    Overall Logistic Regression Results for Study 2

    Dependent Variable: Purchase

    Model 1 Model 2 Model 3

    Variable Coefficient Wald Coefficient Wald 1/exp() Coefficient Wald

    Constant 0.439 2.78 0.492 3.39 0.507 3.57

    Impulse Buying 0.290*** 15.22 0.310*** 16.66 1.36 0.314*** 16.94Scarcity 0.289** 7.47 1.34 0.286** 7.29

    Discount 0.304* 5.63 0.74 0.300* 5.46

    ScarcityDiscount 0.103 0.64

    Model 2(df) 16.01 (1) 29.21 (3) 29.85 (4)

    Block 2(df) 13.13 (2) 0.64 (1)

    Hosmer and Lemeshow

    2(df)9.78 (8) 5.70 (8) 14.94 (8)

    Percent Correct

    Predictions

    63.6 66.7 66.3

    Nagelkerke R2 0.05 0.09 0.09

    Notes:The Wald statistics are distributed chi-square with 1 degree of freedom. *p < 0.05; **p < 0.01; ***p < 0.001.

  • 7/21/2019 Buy Now or Buy Later

    9/16

    Fall 2013 449

    discount condition (p < 0.01), we demonstrate partial sup-

    port for H5 (see Table 3).

    To test H6, as well as replicate the results of H4, we

    performed a median split to create high and low levels of

    involvement. The t-test confirmed that the high-involvement

    group was significantly more involved (M = 5.85) than

    the low-involvement group (M = 3.49, t(1,418) = 27.34,

    p < 0.001).Using binary logistic regression, we attempted to repli-

    cate H4 with the new data. In Study 1, scarcity affected those

    with high involvement and had no effect on those with low

    involvement. In this scenario, we found the opposite effect.

    For individuals reporting low involvement with clothing,

    scarcity was the driver of purchase (1/exp(b) = 1.56), mean-

    ing that regardless of discount, low-involvement individuals

    were 1.56 times as likely to buy the jeans when scarcity was

    high than when it was low (p < 0.01). Furthermore, high-

    involvement individuals were more influenced by the level

    of the discount (1/exp(b) = 0.65) as the respondents were0.65 times less likely to buy a pair of jeans at each discount

    interval (p < 0.05) (see Tables 4 and 5).

    In essence, low involvement increased the salience of

    scarcity while high involvement increased the salience of the

    discount, which is opposite of the predicted effects in H4

    and H6. When the product class was music, high involve-

    ment was pronounced by scarcity. The decision was more

    risky and interesting, leading to a greater proportion of the

    respondents to purchase the CD. However, with clothing,

    scarcity had a significant effect on the low-involvement

    individuals while the high-involvement individuals were

    affected by the level of discount. These counterintuitive

    findings is addressed in the next section.

    GENERAL DISCUSSION

    Theoretical Implications

    While demographics and personal characteristics certainly

    influence purchase behavior in a retail setting, this research

    asserts that the purchase scenario itself can have a major

    impact on the decision. Mazumdar, Raj, and Sinha (2005)

    suggest that context plays an important role in the purchaseprocess, and discount and scarcity certainly fall into that

    category. Auction research has examined scarcity and future

    price increases (Campbell 1999), but in this research we set

    out to investigate the counteracting effect of scarcity and

    a future price discount in the same scenario.

    Theoretically, we demonstrate another instance in which

    EUT fails to predict choice behavior. We find that prospect

    theory better explains the way consumers react to the

    counteracting variables. In Study 1, scarcity led people to

    choose the certain modest gain (product at full price) over

    some probability of a larger gain (product at discounted

    price). One reason for this behavior is that consumers attach

    emotional value to a product based on its availability and

    use this heuristic in the purchase scenario. Our findings

    show that not only will individuals pass up a discount

    but they will even purchase a product at a higher price

    than their upper limit. In Study 2, when discount was also

    manipulated, individuals were more likely to risk a certain

    modest gain for the chance of a larger one, depending on

    the size of the discount.

    Managerial Implications

    Promotional discounts are effective because most consum

    ers want to purchase products at the lowest price possible

    However, firms generally want to sell products at the high

    est price possible and as soon as possible. Our study show

    that by framing the purchase scenario with the dual aspects

    of scarcity and future discount, consumers will generally

    forsake small discounts to avoid missing the opportunity

    to purchase the product. This means that firms can either

    manipulate their inventory, their pricing schedule, or both

    in order to maximize profitability. Suppose a retailer has a

    large stock of a product it needs to sell to make room for

    incoming merchandise. When creating the pricing structurefor this item, our results suggest that the retailer will sell

    more of that product at full price by advertising a low future

    discount on the product. However, if that product is scarce

    a larger discount will yield a higher full-price purchase

    rate, and therefore maximize profit margin on the product

    Furthermore, because individuals attach emotional value

    to scarce products, managers can use this knowledge to lay

    out the message in the most emotion-provoking way.

    Table 3

    Proportion of Subjects Who Chose to

    Purchase for Study 2

    Discount

    Scarcity

    Total

    (Percent)

    Low

    (Percent)

    High

    (Percent)

    Low 66.2 71.2** 68.8Moderate 56.5 72.4** 64.5

    High 48.5+ 60.3 54.6

    Total 57.2 67.9 62.6

    +p < 0.05: represents a significant difference in relative to the total

    average cell. **p < 0.01: represents a significant difference relative to

    the low-scarcityhigh future discount cell.

  • 7/21/2019 Buy Now or Buy Later

    10/16

  • 7/21/2019 Buy Now or Buy Later

    11/16

    Fall 2013 451

    low involvement magnified the effect of scarcity when the

    decision involved clothing. Jeans, and clothing in general,

    are a more visible product, and consequently, they imply a

    greater social risk (White 1966). Low involvement entails a

    low knowledge (Brucks 1985) and low motivation to process

    (Rothschild 1984). Brannon and Brock (2001) found that

    when motivation and knowledge are low, scarcity results

    in consumers paying more attention to task-relevant cues.Those with a lack of motivation and knowledge about cloth-

    ing and fashion are more likely to use the availability as a

    task relevant cue of its value and desirability, and ultimately,

    as a driver of purchase.

    High-involvement consumers, by contrast, are not as

    reliant on that cue. They may also shop more often, follow

    the trends, and know whether or not the product is worth

    the price. These individuals tend to be product experts.

    They pay more attention to product information, spend

    more time processing that information, and put forth more

    effort to the search process (Forehand and Deshpand2001) to ensure that they make a wise choice (Celsi and

    Olson 1988). A wise choice, in this case, means evaluating

    all the alternatives, perhaps looking online, and making

    sure they get the best price for the product. After all, even

    high-involvement individuals seek low prices (Lichtenstein,

    Bloch, and Black 1988), which could be why the discount

    had a greater effect on this group.

    The consumers level of involvement is therefore a

    vital consideration for retailers looking to implement the

    SID pricing schedule. While involvement is an individual

    characteristic, some product categorieslike clothingare

    intrinsically more involving than others. Lichtenstein,

    Bloch, and Black point out: A buyer may feel quite differ-

    ently about purchasing a higher-priced brand of peas than

    about purchasing a higher-priced television (1988, p. 245).

    These highly visible product categories are more likely to

    have high-involvement shoppers who are less susceptible

    to scarcity but are very conscious of the pricing structure.

    For less visible products, involvement may not be as high,

    meaning individuals will place more weight on availability

    and use scarcity as a decision cue. Managers should use

    this information to cater a SID schedule to their specific

    product.

    Finally, the successful implementation of the SID pricing

    schedule requires a change in all aspects of the business.

    Zaras success stems from the integration of its pricing

    model to each function of the supply chain (Ferdows, Lewis,

    and Machuca 2004). Their distribution centers have to be

    responsive, their databases accurate and current, their staff

    well-trained, and their designers cutt ing-edge and prolific.

    It is easier to carry a large volume of the same product than

    it is to carry a large assortment of products; but to truly

    work in the retail sector, an extensive product breadth

    must balance the lack of product depth. That way, when a

    rack with three dresses runs out, customers will not leave

    the store; they will find another rack with three different

    dresses. Being out of stock is no longer a liability, but may

    actually become an asset. Pricing promotions also typicallyincrease store traffic (Pan and Zinkhan 2006), and this has

    been true in the case of Zara. The constant turnover of new

    and unique products attracts more frequent visits than a

    store with low product turnover.

    One word of caution. Often when consumers miss a

    bargain, they decide not to purchase that product at the

    normal price because it would serve as a reminder of the

    missed opportunity (Sevdalis, Harvey, and Yip 2006). While

    Tsiros and Mittal (2000) found that regret positively influ

    ences repurchase intentions, a fine line separates positively

    influencing repurchase behavior and negatively affectingattitudes toward the company. A key component of the SID

    model is transparency and truthfulness. Managers must be

    up front about the discount as well as the stock of products

    For instance, customers may feel manipulated if a retailer

    carried dozens of a style of jeans but only placed a few on

    the sales floor at one time. The unique cues of this pricing

    schedule make it relevant only for products that will not be

    replenished in the near future. Finally, the SID model shares

    a foundation with Tsiros and Hardestys (2010) SDD model

    and could effectively dovetail to this strategy to create a

    comprehensive promotional pricing schedule.

    Limitations and Future Research

    While academic journals have validated the student

    recruitment method and student data in general, it poses

    a limitation in this study. Future research might test the

    SID model in an actual retail setting so that real choices

    could be observed. In this study, we isolated the effects of

    scarcity and future discount into one purchase decision

    respondents had a choice of buying the product now or a

    the later date. Thus, this study is a snapshot of one interva

    in the SID schedule. To fully assess the applicability of the

    SID model, purchase decisions would have to be assessed

    and measured at different intervals throughout the course

    of the promotion.

    Because the effect of involvement differed based on

    the product type, this construct and how it relates to scar

    city and future discount warrants further investigation

    Lichtenstein, Bloch, and Black (1988) note that involvemen

  • 7/21/2019 Buy Now or Buy Later

    12/16

    452 Journal of Marketing Theory and Practice

    is product specific and varies across products and situa-

    tions, and clearly this was the case in our study. A study

    could be developed where the effects of scarcity and future

    discount are measured across several industries/product

    types to determine if involvement is industry or product

    type specific.

    Other moderators may be especially pertinent to the SID

    model. For instance, the same discount can yield differentresponses when presented as either dollar-off or percentage-

    off (Estelami 2003). In both the EUT and prospect theory,

    how the message is framed and interpreted largely deter-

    mines the behavioral response. Future research should

    consider message framing and conflict of decision, as well as

    deal proneness, need for uniqueness, regret, and repurchase

    intentions. Finally, while the SID model may prove effective,

    by its very nature of promoting sales that may never come

    to fruition, it warrants ethical consideration.

    REFERENCES

    Anderson, James C., Mark Wouters, and Wouter van Rossum

    (2010), Why the Highest Price Isnt the Best Price, Sloan

    Management Review,51 (2), 6976.

    Baron, Jonathon (1992), The Effect of Normative Beliefs on Antici-

    pated Emotions,Journal of Personality and Social Psychology,

    63 (2), 320330.

    Baron, Reuben M., and David A. Kenny (1986), The Moderator-

    Mediator Variable Distinction in Social Psychological

    Research: Conceptual, Strategic, and Statistical Consider-

    ations,Journal of Personality and Social Psychology,51 (6),

    11731182.

    Bell, David E. (1982), Regret in Decision Making Under Uncer-tainty, Operations Research,20 (5), 961981.

    Bettman, James (1973), Perceived Risk and Its Components: A

    Model and Empirical Test, Journal of Marketing Research,

    10 (2), 184190.

    Bitner, Mary Jo, Bernard H. Booms, and Mary Stanfield Tetrault

    (1990), The Service Encounter: Diagnosing Favorable and

    Unfavorable Incidents,Journal of Marketing,54 (1), 7184.

    Bloch, Peter H., and Marsha L. Richins (1983). A Theoretical

    Model for the Study of Product Importance Perceptions,

    Journal of Consumer Research,47 (3), 6981.

    , Daniel L. Sherrell, and Nancy M. Ridgway (1986), Consumer

    Research: An Extended Framework, Journal of Consumer

    Research,13 (1), 119126.

    Bozzolo, Anita, and Timothy C. Brock (1992), UnavailabilityEffects on Message Processing: A Theoretical Analysis and

    Empirical Test,Basic and Applied Social Psychology,13 (1),

    93101.

    Brannon, Laura A., and Timothy C. Brock (2001), Limiting Time

    for Responding Enhances Behavior Corresponding to the

    Merits of Compliance Appeals: Refutations of Heuristic-

    Cue Theory in Service and Consumer Settings,Journal of

    Consumer Psychology,10 (3), 133146.

    Brock, Timothy C. (1968), Implications of Commodity Theory

    for Value Change, inPsychological Foundations of Attitudes,

    Anthony G. Greenwald, Timothy C. Brock, and Thomas M.

    Ostrum, eds., New York: Academic Press, 243275.

    Brucks, Merrie (1985), The Effects of Product Class Knowledge on

    Information Search Behavior,Journal of Consumer Research,

    12 (1), 116.

    Burton, Scot, Donald Lichtenstein, Richard Netemeyer, and Judith

    Garretson (1998), A Scale for Measuring Attitude Toward Pri-

    vate Label Products and an Examination of Its Psychological

    and Behavioral Correlates,Journal of the Academy of Marketing

    Science,26 (4), 293306.

    Campbell, Margaret C. (1999), Perceptions of Price Unfairness:

    Antecedents and Consequences,Journal of Marketing Research,

    36 (2), 187199.

    Celsi, Richard L., and Jerry C. Olson (1988), The Role of Involve-

    ment in Attention and Comprehension Processes,Journal of

    Consumer Research,15 (2), 210224.

    Cialdini, Robert B. (1993),Influence: Science and Practice,New York:

    HarperCollins.

    DeGraba, Patrick (1995), Buying Frenzies and Seller-Induced Excess

    Demand,Journal of Economics,26 (2), 331342.

    Dhar, Ravi, and Stephen M. Nowlis (1999), The Effects of Time

    Pressure on Consumer Choice Deferral,Journal of Consumer

    Research,6 (4), 389405.

    Estelami, Hooman (2003), The Effect of Price Presentation Tactics

    on Consumer Evaluation Effort of Multi-Dimensional Prices,

    Journal of Marketing Theory and Practice,11 (1), 115.

    Ferdows, Kasra, Michael A. Lewis, and Jose A.D. Machuca (2004),

    Rapid-Fire Fulfillment, Harvard Business Review,82 (11),

    104110.

    Folkes, Valerie S. (1988), The Availability Heuristic and Perceived

    Risk,Journal of Consumer Research,15 (1), 1323.

    Forehand, Mark R., and Rohit Deshpand (2001), What We

    See Makes Us Who We Are: Priming Self-Awareness and

    Advertising Response,Journal of Marketing Research,38 (3),

    336348.

    Frank, Robert H. (2007), The Natural Economist: In Search of Explana-

    tions for Everyday Enigmas,New York: Basic Books.Hall, Robert E. (1978), Stochastic Implications of the Life Cycle-

    Permanent Income Hypothesis: Theory and Evidence,Journal

    of Political Economy,86 (6), 971988.

    Holmes, Elizabeth (2011), Retailers to Rein in Discounts, Wall

    Street Journal,July 8 (available at http://online.wsj.com/article/

    SB10001424052702303544604576431572289761998.html).

    Inman, J. Jeffrey, Anil C. Peter, and Priya Raghubir (1997), Framing

    the Deal: The Role of Restrictions in Accentuating Deal Value,

    Journal of Consumer Research,24 (1), 6879.

    International Council of Shopping Centers (2009), How the

    Recession Has Impacted Consumer Shopping Habits, 2009

    Shopping Habits Report, New York.

    Jacobson, Robert, and Carl Obermiller (1990),The Formation of

    Expected Future Price: Reference Price for Forward-LookingCustomers,Journal of Consumer Research,16 (4), 420432.

    Kahneman, Daniel, and Amos Tversky (1979), Prospect Theory:

    An Analysis of Decision Under Risk,Econometrica,47 (2),

    263291.

    Laurent, Gilles, and Jean Nol Kapferer (1985), Measuring Con-

    sumer Involvement Profiles,Journal of Marketing Research,

    22 (1), 4153.

    Lichtenstein, Donald R., Peter H. Bloch, and William C. Black

    (1988), Correlates of Price Acceptability,Journal of Consumer

    Research,15 (2), 243252.

  • 7/21/2019 Buy Now or Buy Later

    13/16

    Fall 2013 453

    Lynn, Michael (1989), Scarcity Effects on Desirability: Mediated

    by Assumed Responsiveness?Journal of Economic Psychology,

    10 (2), 257274.

    MacKinnon, David P., and James H. Dwyer (1993), Estimating

    Mediated Effects in Prevention Studies,Education Review,

    36 (4), 144158.

    Mattioli, Dana (2012), Lululemons Secret Sauce Wall Street

    Journal,March 22 (available at http://online.wsj.com/article/

    SB10001424052702303812904577295882632723066.html).

    Mazumdar, Tridib, S.P. Raj, and Indrajit Sinha (2005), Reference

    Price Research: Review and Propositions,Journal of Market-

    ing,69 (4), 84102.

    Mittal, Banwari (1995), A Comparative Analysis of Four Scales

    of Consumer Involvement,Psychology & Marketing,12 (7),

    663682.

    Mongin, Philippe (1997), Expected Utility Theory, inHandbook

    of Economic Methodology,John Bryan Davis, D. Wade Hands,

    and Uskali Maki, eds., London: Edward Elgar, 342350.

    Monroe, Kent B. (1973), Buyers Subjective Perceptions of Price,

    Journal of Marketing Research,10 (1), 7080.

    (2003), Pricing: Making Profitable Decisions, 3d ed., Burr

    Ridge, IL: Irwin.

    Neubert, Mitchell J., K. Michelle Kacmar, Dawn S. Carlson, Law-

    rence B. Chonko, and James A. Roberts (2008), Regulatory

    Focus as a Mediator of the Influence of Initiating Structure

    and Servant Leadership on Employee Behavior,Journal of

    Applied Psychology,93 (6), 12201233.

    Pan, Yue, and George Zinkhan (2006), Determinants of Retail

    Patronage: A Meta-Analytic Perspective,Journal of Retailing,

    82 (3), 229243.

    Rao, Akshay, and Wanda A. Sieben (1992), The Effect of Prior

    Knowledge on Price Acceptability and the Type of Infor-

    mation Examined, Journal of Consumer Research, 19 (2),

    256270.

    Richins, Marsha L., and Peter H. Bloch (1986), After the New

    Wears Off: The Temporal Context of Product Involvement,

    Journal of Consumer Research,13 (2), 280285.Rook, Dennis W. (1987), The Buying Impulse,Journal of Con-

    sumer Research,14 (2), 189199.

    , and Robert J. Fisher (1995), Normative Influences on

    Impulsive Buying Behavior,Journal of Consumer Research,

    22 (3), 305313.

    Rothschild, Michael L. (1984), Perspectives on Involvement:

    Current Problems and Future Directions, in Advances in

    Consumer Research,vol. 11, Thomas C. Kinnear, ed., Provo,

    UT: Association for Consumer Research, 216217.

    Samli, A. Coskun, and Laurence W. Jacobs (1993), Internationa

    Pricing Decisions: A Diagnostic Approach,Journal of Market

    ing Theory and Practice,1 (4), 2941.

    Sevdalis, Nick, Nigel Harvey, and Michelle Yip (2006), Regret

    Triggers Inaction Inert iaBut Which Regret and How?Brit

    ish Journal of Social Psychology,45 (4), 839853.

    Sivakumar, K. (1996), Tradeoff Between Frequency and Depth of

    Price Promotions,Journal of Marketing Theory and Practice

    4 (1), 18.

    Sobel, Michael E. (1982), Asymptotic Confidence Intervals for

    Indirect Effects in Structural Equations Models, in Socio

    logical Methodology, Samuel Leinhart, ed., San Francisco

    Jossey-Bass, 290312.

    Suri, Rajneesh, and Kent B. Monroe (2003), The Effects of Time

    Constraints on Consumers Judgments of Prices and Prod

    ucts,Journal of Consumer Research,30 (1), 92104.

    , Chiranjeev Kohli, and Kent B. Monroe (2007), The Effects

    of Perceived Scarcity on Consumers Processing of Price

    Information,Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science

    35 (1), 89100.

    Sweeney, Jillian C., and Geoffrey N. Soutar (2001), Consume

    Perceived Value: The Development of a Multiple Item Scale,

    Journal of Retailing,77 (2), 203220.

    Tsiros, Michael, and David M. Hardesty (2010), Ending a Price

    Promotion: Retracting It in One Step or Phasing It out Gradu

    ally,Journal of Marketing,74 (1), 4964.

    , and Vikas Mittal (2000), Regret: A Model of its Antecedent

    and Consequences in Consumer Decision Making,Journa

    of Consumer Research,26 (4), 401417.

    Tversky, Amos, and Daniel Kahneman (1973), Availability: A

    Heuristic for Judging Frequency and Probability, Cognitive

    Psychology,5 (2), 201232.

    von Neumann, John, and Oskar Morgenstern (1947), Theory o

    Games and Economic Behavior,2d ed., Princeton: Princeton

    University Press.

    White, Irving S. (1966), The Perception of Value in Products,

    in On Knowing the Consumer,J.W. Newman, ed., New YorkWiley, 90106.

    Winer, Russel S. (1986), A Reference Price Model of Brand Choice

    for Frequently Purchased Products, Journal of Consume

    Research,13 (2), 250256.

    Zaichkowsky, Judith Lynn (1985), Measuring the Involvemen

    Construct,Journal of Consumer Research,12 (3), 341352.

  • 7/21/2019 Buy Now or Buy Later

    14/16

    454 Journal of Marketing Theory and Practice

    APPENDIX A

    Scenario and Items for Study 1

    A lot of people have a favorite musical band or artist. Think about your favorite band or artist and write it here

    __________________.

    About how much would you be willing to spend for a live CD of this band or artists first-ever performance? Please

    write the amount here __________________.

    Now imagine that this Saturday morning you go your local flea market and find that CD [three of them in fact] except

    it is priced $5 higher than what you wrote above. You know that the flea market has a policy of selling any unsold items

    at half off the following Saturday, but you have no idea if [any of] the CD[s] will still be there next week. You cannot hide

    a CD, place one on hold, or do anything of that nature. Would you purchase a CD that day or come back the following

    Saturday with the hope that at least one was left and you could buy it for half off?

    Table A1

    Scale Items with Factor Loadings and Reliabilities for Study 1

    Involvement with Product Class (Laurent and Kapferer 1985)

    The clothes I buy are very important to me.For me, it matters what clothes I own.

    Clothes are an important part of my life.

    0.85

    0.910.88

    0.85

    Perceived Emotional Value (Sweeney and Soutar 2001)

    This CD is one that I would enjoy.

    Buying this CD would make me want to listen to it.

    Owning this CD would make me feel good.

    Owning this CD would give me pleasure.

    I would feel relaxed about owning this CD.

    0.91

    0.85

    0.86

    0.89

    0.90

    0.81

    Risk Aversion (Burton et al. 1998)

    I dont like to take risks.

    Compared to most people I know, I like to gamble on things.

    Compared to most people I know, I like to live on the edge.

    I have no desire to take unnecessary chances on things.

    0.76

    0.74

    0.82

    0.85

    0.60

    Impulse Buying (Rook and Fisher 1995)I often buy things spontaneously.

    Just do it describes the way I buy things.

    I often buy things without thinking.

    I see it, I buy it describes me.

    Buy now, think about it later describes me.

    Sometimes I feel like buying things spur of the moment.

    I buy things according to how I feel at the moment.

    I carefully plan most of my purchases.

    Sometimes I am a bit reckless about what I buy.

    0.910.80

    0.85

    0.86

    0.86

    0.80

    0.67

    0.72

    0.56

    0.72

    Note: Items anchored by 1 = strongly disagree to 7 = strongly agree.

  • 7/21/2019 Buy Now or Buy Later

    15/16

    Fall 2013 455

    APPENDIX B

    Scenario and Items for Study 2

    Imagine that you need a new pair of jeans, and that this Saturday you go to the mall in search of a pair. A lot of people

    have a favorite or go-to brand when it comes to jeans. Think about your favorite brand or a brand you like and write

    it here ________________________.

    Imagine that the brand you wrote above sells one pair of jeans that has the exact style, fit, color, etc., that you are

    looking for. About how much would you be willing to spend for a pair of these jeans? Please write the amount

    here ________________________. (If you cannot think of a specific brand, write how much youd pay for a really nice pair

    of jeans with the exact style, fit, color, etc. you like)

    Now imagine that you enter a store that is running a promotion on the brand of jeans that you wrote above. You soon

    find a table display with 10 [2] pairs of the exact style, fit, color, etc., that you are looking for in your size. Above the table

    hangs a sign that reads, All jeans 50% off [25% off, 10% off] next Saturday. Keeping in mind that this pair of jeans wil

    not be available in other stores or online,you begin to debate purchasing the jeans today or coming back next Saturday for

    the discount.

    Table B1

    Scale Items with Factor Loadings and Reliabilities for Study 2

    Involvement with Product Class (Laurent and Kapferer 1985)

    The clothes I buy are very important to me.

    For me, it matters what clothes I own.

    Clothes are an important part of my life.

    0.91

    0.85

    0.85

    0.82

    Impulse Buying (Rook and Fisher 1995)

    I often buy things spontaneously.

    Just do it describes the way I buy things.

    I often buy things without thinking.

    I see it, I buy it describes me.

    Buy now, think about it later describes me.

    Sometimes I feel like buying things spur of the moment.

    I buy things according to how I feel at the moment.Sometimes I am a bit reckless about what I buy.

    0.94

    0.79

    0.86

    0.85

    0.86

    0.83

    0.80

    0.820.78

    Note: Items anchored by 1 = strongly disagree to 7 = strongly agree.

  • 7/21/2019 Buy Now or Buy Later

    16/16

    Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without

    permission.