3
More from The Economist My Subscription Log in or register Subscribe World politics Business & finance Economics Science & technology Culture Blogs Debate Multimedia Print edition In this section The crash of a titan Polls apart Slowing charge In the stocks Leaks on tap The day of reckoning Ecowaverers Poverty’s long farewell Reprints Feb 28th 2015 | From the print edition Buttonwood Polls apart Voters face constraints on their economic choices THE row about whether to modify Greece’s bailout has provoked claims that democracy is being ignored. The electoral mandate of the Syriza party, it is said, is being overridden by Greece’s creditors. In fact, there have always been limits on voters’ freedom to pursue their desired economic policies. The first is on the ability of the majority to tax the minority, be it highearning individuals or companies. Clearly there is some point beyond which higher taxes lead to lower revenues, as effort is discouraged. There is no general agreement over the point at which diminishing returns set in, but in an age of mobile people and firms, the threshold is probably lower than it used to be. The second limit occurs when countries become dependent on international creditors for finance. They cannot force those creditors to roll over their debts, nor can they dictate the terms on which they borrow. Countries are free, of course, to default on their debts; eventually creditors forgive (or forget) and start lending again. In the short term, however, default is likely to lead to budgetary constraints. Voters may end up with austerity after all. Economic regimes have also evolved over time, as electorates have changed. Before 1918, when the franchise in most democracies was limited to the propertyowning classes, politicians favoured a lowtax, small state. After 1918 universal suffrage brought pressure on governments to intervene more heavily in the economy, providing health care, education and insurance against unemployment. Taxes rose accordingly. After 1945 the experience of the Depression persuaded most governments to opt for Keynesian demand management, allowing deficits to expand in order to ward off recession. But the policy broke down in the mid1970s in the face of simultaneous high inflation and Advertisement Follow The Economist Latest updates » Israel's snap election: The name game Middle East and Africa | 55 mins ago New exhibition: Savage Beauty: Long live McQueen Prospero | 3 hours 29 mins ago The Metropolitan Museum of Art: Wing commander Chipperfield Comment (14) Timekeeper reading list Email Reprints & permissions Print 443 Like

Buttonwood_ Polls Apart _ the Economist

Embed Size (px)

DESCRIPTION

the economist

Citation preview

Page 1: Buttonwood_ Polls Apart _ the Economist

13/3/2015 Buttonwood: Polls apart | The Economist

http://www.economist.com/news/financeandeconomics/21645244votersfaceconstraintstheireconomicchoicespollsapart 1/3

More from The Economist My Subscription Log in or registerSubscribe

World politics Business & finance Economics Science & technology Culture Blogs Debate Multimedia Print edition

In this section

The crash of a titan

Polls apart

Slowing charge

In the stocks

Leaks on tap

The day of reckoning

Ecowaverers

Poverty’s long farewell

Reprints

Feb 28th 2015 | From the print edition

Buttonwood

Polls apartVoters face constraints on their economic choices

THE row about whether to modify Greece’s bailout has provoked claims that democracy isbeing ignored. The electoral mandate of the Syriza party, it is said, is being overridden byGreece’s creditors.

In fact, there have always been limits on voters’ freedom to pursue their desired economicpolicies. The first is on the ability of the majority to tax the minority, be it highearningindividuals or companies. Clearly there is some point beyond which higher taxes lead tolower revenues, as effort is discouraged. There is no general agreement over the point atwhich diminishing returns set in, but in an age of mobile people and firms, the threshold isprobably lower than it used to be.

The second limit occurs when countries become dependenton international creditors for finance. They cannot force thosecreditors to roll over their debts, nor can they dictate the termson which they borrow. Countries are free, of course, to defaulton their debts; eventually creditors forgive (or forget) and startlending again. In the short term, however, default is likely tolead to budgetary constraints. Voters may end up withausterity after all.

Economic regimes have also evolved over time, aselectorates have changed. Before 1918, when the franchise inmost democracies was limited to the propertyowningclasses, politicians favoured a lowtax, small state. After 1918universal suffrage brought pressure on governments tointervene more heavily in the economy, providing health care, education and insuranceagainst unemployment. Taxes rose accordingly.

After 1945 the experience of the Depression persuaded most governments to opt forKeynesian demand management, allowing deficits to expand in order to ward off recession.But the policy broke down in the mid1970s in the face of simultaneous high inflation and

Advertisement

Follow The Economist

Latest updates »

Israel's snap election: The name gameMiddle East and Africa | 55 mins ago

New exhibition: Savage Beauty: Longlive McQueenProspero | 3 hours 29 mins ago

The Metropolitan Museum of Art: Wingcommander Chipperfield

Comment (14) Timekeeper reading list

Email Reprints & permissions

Print

443Like

Page 2: Buttonwood_ Polls Apart _ the Economist

13/3/2015 Buttonwood: Polls apart | The Economist

http://www.economist.com/news/financeandeconomics/21645244votersfaceconstraintstheireconomicchoicespollsapart 2/3

unemployment (“stagflation”). The policy regime took the blame: politicians had given in tothe temptation to set interest rates to gain electoral advantage and this allowed inflation tobuild.

Central banks then became the drivers of economic policy, using interest rates to managethe cycle. This made them unpopular when inflation was being squeezed out of the systemin the late 1970s and early 1980s. But as inflation fell and interest rates came down, thecentral bankers were lauded as clever technocrats who had delivered the “greatmoderation” of steady growth and low inflation.

This change was an explicit step away from democratic control of economic policy.Admittedly, governments still define central banks’ mandates and hire the people in charge.But voters who dislike the policies of Janet Yellen and Mario Draghi—the two mostimportant economic decisionmakers in America and Europe—have no direct way of gettingrid of them.

The financial crisis has made central bankers even more useful than before. After 2009most politicians in the developed world were unwilling or unable to deliver fiscal stimulus.Central banks could both provide monetary stimulus and act as willing buyers forgovernment bonds through quantitative easing (QE), making it easier to fund deficits. Thedeal has appeared virtually costfree: it has not produced the hyperinflation that somepredicted. (How all this monetary support is unwound is another matter.)

However, voters in the European countries that opted for the single currency do not have adomestic central bank. It is only now that the European Central Bank is embarking on QE.And, of course, such countries have not been able to devalue their currencies, a step thathelped Iceland on the road to recovery.

The economic critique of the euro zone is wellknown. It is foolish to create a singlecurrency without political or fiscal union. But would Greeks really like the kind of Europeansuperstate that could easily make big fiscal transfers? They might find themselves just aspowerless as they now feel in their negotiations with creditors. Greece, after all, would havea very small weight in a eurozone electorate.

This points to a wider problem. National politicians come to power on the back of economicpromises made to their domestic electorates. But the forces that determine whether theireconomies prosper are global, not local—whether the Chinese economy slows down orspeeds up, what happens to oil supplies and so on. National politicians will be blamed forthe adverse effects of those forces, even though they are not under their control. Thecorrosive effect is to add to voters’ cynicism about politics and undermine support fordemocracy.

Economist.com/blogs/buttonwood

From the print edition: Finance and economics

View all comments (14) Add your comment

More from The Economist

The female body: Shapeshifting

The Ottoman Empire:Heading towards disaster

New York’s bestschools: Asians beware

India’s social ills: How to damageIndia’s reputation

Grammar: The whom

Prospero | Mar 13th, 17:58

Fasting and food: Not by bread aloneErasmus | Mar 13th, 14:37

The Asian Infrastructure InvestmentBank: American poodle to Chinese...Business and finance | Mar 13th, 14:03

Daily chart: Tu casa es mi casaGraphic detail | Mar 13th, 14:01

Law enforcement: A damn punk inFergusonDemocracy in America | Mar 13th, 03:03

More latest updates »

Most commented

Advertisement

Products and events

Have you listened to The Economist Radio onFacebook?The Economist Radio is an ondemand sociallistening platform that allows you to listen, share andrecommend The Economist audio content

Test your EQTake our weekly news quiz to stay on top of theheadlines

In Other WordsTry our new audio app and website, providing

Iran and the bombDear Ayatollah

Latinos in the United States: How to fire upAmericaThe economy: Go slowHillary Clinton's emails: Poor judgmentHealth care in America: Don’t kill Obamacare

1

2

345

443Like

Page 3: Buttonwood_ Polls Apart _ the Economist

13/3/2015 Buttonwood: Polls apart | The Economist

http://www.economist.com/news/financeandeconomics/21645244votersfaceconstraintstheireconomicchoicespollsapart 3/3

AdvisorCompetencyBased Training a…

Jobs.economist.com

Manager, InternalAudit

Jobs.economist.com

Executive Director

Jobs.economist.com

Copyright © The Economist Newspaper Limited 2015. All rights reserved.

Classified ads

Want more? Subscribe to The Economist and get the week's mostrelevant news and analysis.

French politics: The resistible rise ofMarine Le Pen

Houston’s economy: Life in the sprawl

Aldi and Lidl: Tomorrow, not quite theworld

The Economist explains: What isquantitative easing?

reporting and analysis from our correspondentsaround the world every weekday

Want more from The Economist?Visit The Economist estore and you’ll find a rangeof carefully selected products for business andpleasure, Economist books and diaries, and muchmore

Sections

Debate and discussion

Blogs Research and insights

Contact us

Help

My account

Subscribe

Print edition

Digital editions

Events

Jobs.Economist.com

Timekeeper saved articles

United StatesBritainEuropeChinaAsiaAmericasMiddle East & AfricaInternationalBusiness & financeEconomicsMarkets & dataScience & technologySpecial reportsCultureMultimedia library

The Economist debatesLetters to the editorThe Economist Quiz

Buttonwood's notebookDemocracy in AmericaErasmusFree exchangeGame theoryGraphic detailGulliverProsperoThe Economist explains

TopicsEconomics AZStyle guideThe World in 2015Which MBA?MBA ServicesThe Economist GMAT TutorReprints and permissions

The Economist Group »The Economist Intelligence UnitThe Economist Intelligence UnitStoreThe Economist Corporate NetworkIdeas People MediaIntelligent LifeRoll CallCQEuroFinanceThe Economist Store

View complete site index »

Contact us Help About us Advertise with us Editorial Staff Staff Books Careers Site index

Accessibility Privacy policy Cookies info Terms of use

Print edition X

Feb 28th 2015 Feb 21st 2015 Feb 14th 2015 Feb 7th 2015

From the print edition Feb 28th 2015