63
Review of i nternational case studies of Payment for Ecosystem Services (PES) Project Activity 2.2 for the Project: Developing a piloting model on payments for coastal wetland ecosystem services in Mui Ca Mau National Park in the context of climate change contributing to poverty reduction in local community

Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

       

Review  of  international  case  studies  of  Payment  for  Ecosystem  Services  (PES)    

Project  Activity  2.2  for  the  Project:  

Developing  a  piloting  model  on  payments  for  coastal  wetland  ecosystem  services  in  Mui  Ca  Mau  National  Park  in  the  context  of  climate  change  contributing  to  poverty  reduction  in  

local  community  

   

Page 2: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

2

 THIS DOCUMENT IS SPONSORED BY

     Project  sponsored  by  The  Swedish  International  Development  Cooperation  Agency  in  Vietnam    Project  Partners    Biodiversity  Conservation  Agency,  Vietnam  Environment  Administration,  Ministry  of  Natural  Resources  and  Environment,  Vietnam  Research  Center  of  Forest  and  Wetlands,  Vietnam  Forum  for  Reforms,  Entrepreneurship  and  Sustainability,  Sweden        This  report  prepared  by  Scott  Cole  EnviroEconomics  Sweden  Consulting  (EES)  (www.eesweden.com)    With  assistance  from  Daxam  Sutainability  Services  (www.daxam.se)  Enveco  Environmental  Economics  Consultancy  Ltd  (www.enveco.se)      Citation  BCA,  FORES,  FORWET  2013  Review  of  international  case  studies  of  Payment  for  Ecosystem  Services  (PES),  Stockholm,  Sweden      Project  Team  Ulrika  Stavlöt  Ana  P  Aponte  Scott  Cole  Linus  Hasselström  Daniel  Engström  Stenson    Nguyen  The  Dong  Huynh  Thi  Mai  Nguyen  Chi  Thanh  Nguyen  Tuan  Phu  Nguyen  Tien  Dung  Le  Huu  Phu        

Page 3: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

3

Contacts  Biodiversity  Conservation  Agency,  Vietnam  Environment  Administration,  Ministry  of  Natural  Resource  and  Environment  Management  No  10,  Ton  That  Thuyet  Street,  Cau  Giay  district,  Hanoi,  Vietnam  Tel.:  +  84  4  37956868  Ext.3108    Forum  for  Reforms,  Entrepreneurship  and  Sustainability  Bellmansgatan  10  118  20  Stockholm,  Sweden  Tel:  +46  08  45  22  660  

   

Page 4: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

4

Table  of  Contents  

1.   BACKGROUND  AND  PURPOSE  OF  REPORT   5  

2.   APPROACH   7  

3.   METHODOLOGY  FOR  TECHNICAL  ANALYSIS   8  

4.   RESULTS  OF  INTERNATIONAL  PES  LITERATURE  REVIEW   12  

4.1.   Summary  of  the  findings  of  The  BCA  Report  (Huynh  Thi  2011)   12  

4.1.1.   Review  international  experience  with  PES  for  biodiversity   12  

4.1.2.   Assess  the  potential  application  of  PES  in  Vietnam.   14  

4.1.3.   Propose  a  nationwide  policy  and  a  roadmap  for  PES  in  Vietnam   15  

4.2.   Technical  analysis  of  PES  case  studies   16  

4.2.1.   Background  on  case  studies   16  

4.2.2.   Ecosystem  services  addressed   17  

4.2.3.   Technical  aspects  of  PES  schemes   17  4.2.3.1.   The  ecosystem  service  bought  and  sold   17  4.2.3.2.   The  buyers  and  sellers   18  4.2.3.3.   Contracts  and  payment   19  4.2.3.4.   Determining  price   19  4.2.3.5.   Administration  &  enforcement  of  the  PES  scheme   19  

5.   CONCLUSIONS   21  

REFERENCES   26  

APPENDIX  A  –  FORMAL  SUMMARIES  OF  16  PES  CASE  STUDIES   30    

   

Page 5: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

5

1. Background  and  Purpose  of  report    

The  Government  of  Vietnam  is  pursuing  market-­‐based  approaches  to  environmental  protection,  with  a  strategic  focus  on  Ecosystem  Services  (ES)  such  as  biodiversity  conservation.  Specifically,  the  country’s  vision  is  to  share  the  benefits  of  environmental  services  between  beneficiaries  and  stakeholders.  The  country  has  undertaken  several  pilot  studies  that  apply  a  Payment  for  Ecosystem  Services  (PES)  approach  for  reaching  this  goal  including,  but  not  limited  to1:  

1. Payment  for  landscape  protection  Bach  Ma  National  Park  (2002-­‐2007)  2. Payment  for  carbon  sequestration  in  forests  in  Cao  Phong  Hoa  Binh    (2002-­‐2007)  3. Payment  for  marine  protected  areas  of  Nha  Trang  Bay  (2002-­‐2007)  4. Payment  for  Forest  Ecosystem  Services  in  Lam  Dong  and  Son  La  Provinces  (2008-­‐

2010)  5. Emerging  pilot  studies  related  to  payment  for  ES  provided  by  National  Parks  such  

as  aquaculture  to  raise  revenue  for  Park  activities  (e.g.,  Bidoup  Nui  Ba  NP,  Ca  Ba  NP,  and  Xuan  Thuy  N.P)    

These  pilot  projects  are  driven  in  part  by  Vietnam’s  unique  Biodiversity  Conservation  Law  adopted  in  2008  which  includes,  among  other  things,  a  specific  provision  requiring  users  of  environmental  services  related  to  biodiversity  to  pay  charges  to  service  providers  (see  Article  74).  This  unique  part  of  the  law  paves  the  way  for  the  implementation  of  pilot  studies  related  to  PES.    

Following  the  success  of  the  Payment  for  Forest  Ecosystem  Services  pilot  –  which  improved  living  standards  for  local  people,  reduced  illegal  logging,  provided  forestry  sector  employment,  and  reduced  State  budget  expenses  (Phuc  Xuan  2012)  -­‐-­‐  Vietnam’s  Environment  Agency  is  interested  in  expanding  PES  pilot  programs  to  cover  ES  from  non-­‐forest  ecosystems  (Huynh  Thi  2011).  For  example,  the  Government  of  Vietnam  issued  Decree  No.  99/2010/ND-­‐CP  which  called  for  replicating  the  success  of  Payment  for  Forest  Ecosystem  Services  pilot  to  cover  other  ES  in  the  country.    

Further,  the  Government  of  Vietnam  is  interested  in  combining  continued  economic  development  with  two  additional  goals:  (1)  mitigation  of  climate  change  impacts  –  in  particular  rising  sea  levels  which  underscores  the  value  of  ES  provided  by  coastal  wetlands  –  and  (2)  alleviation  of  rural  poverty.    

The  result  is  this  Mui  Ca  Mau  National  Park  PES  pilot  study  on  coastal  wetlands,  a  Partner-­‐Driven  Cooperation  Grant  from  the  Swedish  International  Development  Agency  (SIDA).2  Vietnamese  partners  on  the  project  include  the  Biodiversity  Conservation  Agency  within  the  Vietnam  Environment  Administration  (BCA),  the  Institute  of  Strategy  

                                                                                                               1  See  e.g.,  Hoang  Minh  Ha  et  al  (2008),  MONRE  (2010),  Nguyen  Thuy  Duong  et  al  (2011),  Phuc  Xuan  (2012).  2  The  project  is  entitled  Developing  a  piloting  model  on  payments  for  coastal  wetland  ecosystem  services  in  Mui  Ca  Mau  National  Park  in  the  context  of  climate  change  contributing  to  poverty  reduction  in  local  community  commenced  on  15  November  2012  and  will  last  one  year.  See  Huynh  Thi  2011.  

Page 6: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

6

and  Policy  on  Natural  Resources  and  Environment  within  Vietnam’s  Ministry  of  Natural  Resources  and  Environment  (ISPONRE),  and  the  Research  Center  of  Forest  and  Wetlands  (FORWET).  The  Swedish  partner  is  Reforms,  Entrepreneurship  and  Sustainability  (FORES)  together  with  their  local  Swedish  experts,  Daxam  Sustainability  Services  (Daxam)  and  EnviroEconomics  Sweden  (EES).  

The  project’s  goal  is  to  establish  a  PES  structure  that  will  enable  poor  local  communities  in  Mui  Ca  Mau  National  Park  to  earn  income  from  livelihood  models  that  rely  on  services  provided  by  coastal  wetlands  and  mangrove  forests  and  then  be  able  to  use  part  of  this  income  to  compensate  the  National  Park  for  the  use  of  these  ES.  The  project  has  four  main  objectives:  

1. Develop  a  livelihood  model  for  20  local  households  aimed  at  reducing  poverty  and  generating  income  for  future  purchase  of  ES  from  the  National  Park;  

2. Develop  a  mechanism  and  administrative  system  for  buyers  and  sellers  of  ES  to  interact  and  conduct  transactions  (PES);  

3. Improve  capacity-­‐building  and  public  awareness  of  PES  development  and  implementation  in  Vietnam  and  Sweden;  and  

4. Create  a  strategic  partnership  and  long-­‐term  cooperation  between  Vietnamese  and  Swedish  partners  on  PES  development.  

The  project’s  work  plan  (BCA  et  al  2012)  specifies  several  deliverables.  FORWET  will  develop  a  pilot  livelihood  model  (Activity  1.6)  and  FORES,  together  with  their  Swedish  experts,  will  develop  a  preliminary  PES  payment  structure  (Activity  2.12).  The  project  will  test  the  PES  structure  and  make  recommendations  for  a  possible  second  phase  of  the  PES  experiment.  The  overall  goal  of  the  PES  structure  is  to  improve  the  cost-­‐efficiency  of  resource  management  and  sustainable  provision  of  ES  from  coastal  wetlands  and  mangrove  forests  in  Mui  Ca  Mau  National  Park.  

The  purpose  of  this  report  is  to  provide  an  intermediate  deliverable  en  route  to  producing  the  proposed  PES  payment  structure  (expected  June  2013).  The  report  identifies  PES  case  studies  on  the  international  level,  summarizes  patterns  that  emerge  from  these  experiments  and/or  pilot  studies  and  identifies  key  lessons  learned.    

   

Page 7: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

7

2. Approach    

Because  BCA  has  already  conducted  an  international  review  of  PES  programs  around  the  world  (Huynh  Thi  2011,    or  hereafter  “The  BCA  Report”),  the  focus  of  this  analysis  is  to  complement  this  report  by  reviewing  technical  issues  related  to  a  PES  payment  structure.    

Therefore,  this  international  review  of  PES  case  studies  is  composed  of  two  parts:  

1. Review  of  previous  findings  on  PES  programs  from  The  BCA  Report,  with  a  focus  on  lessons  learned  in  developing  a  roadmap  for  future  PES  development  in  Vietnam  (The  BCA  Report  is  written  in  Vietnamese);  and  

2. Technical  analysis  of  PES  programs  that  focuses  on  16  case  studies  identified  by  the  authors  of  this  report.  The  technical  analysis  will  cover  issues  relating  to,  for  example,  identifying  buyers  and  sellers,  establishing  prices,  measuring  ecosystem  services,  linking  the  supply  of  ecosystem  services  to  the  activities  of  providers  themselves  (e.g.,  tree  planting  leads  to  carbon  sequestration),  developing  a  payment  structure  and  administration,  ensuring  adequate  monitoring  and  enforcement,  etc.  

The  next  section  focuses  on  the  methodology  for  the  technical  analysis.  

   

Page 8: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

8

 

3. Methodology  for  technical  analysis      

Our  literature  search  aims  to  identify  examples  of  on-­‐going  PES  programs  (“case  studies”)  for  which  sufficient  time  has  passed  to  allow  for  meaningful  evaluation.  The  PES  approach  to  resource  management  has  gained  in  popularity  since  the  influential  article  in  Science  magazine  by  Ferraro  and  Kiss  (2002),  who  argued  for  a  direct  approach  to  conservation.  We  define  a  PES  scheme  by  referring  to  the  commonly-­‐cited  definition  by  Wunder  et  al  (2005),  where  PES  is:  

1. a  voluntary  transaction  where              2. a  well-­‐defined  ES  (or  a  land-­‐use  likely  to  secure  that  service)              3. is  being  ‘bought’  by  a  (minimum  one)  ES  buyer  4. from  a  (minimum  one)  ES  provider    5. if  and  only  if  the  ES  provider  secures  ES  provision  (conditionality).”  

Case  studies  were  found  in  the  peer-­‐reviewed  and  grey  literature.  Our  search  targets  specific  types  of  PES  case  studies,  although  some  case  studies  that  are  slightly  outside  our  focus  were  nonetheless  considered  relevant  to  the  analysis.  The  priority  themes  we  used  to  guide  our  initial  literature  search  include  the  following:  

• Coastal  wetlands  and  marine  ecosystem  focus  • Mangrove  focus  • Vietnam  focus  • PES  programs  that  include  poverty  reduction  goals  • Focus  on  climate  change  mitigation    • Any  PES  experiment  that  provides  valuable  lessons  learned  

Our  search  resulted  in  various  articles  and  studies  investigating  PES  schemes  around  the  world.  We  selected  16  studies  that  met  the  priority  themes  and  described  a  concrete  example  of  an  implemented  or  on-­‐going  PES  scheme.  For  these  studies  we  completed  a  two-­‐page  summary  of  study  results.  The  top  half  of  Table  1  provides  an  overview  of  these  studies  in  alphabetical  order  and  Appendix  A  provides  the  two-­‐page  summaries.    

A  number  of  other  relevant  studies  were  also  collected  and  reviewed  to  enhance  our  case  study  analysis.  These  studies  are  identified  in  the  second  half  of  Table  1.  We  have  cited  these  studies  in  Section  4  (Analysis)  where  appropriate  to  support  the  general  findings  from  both  The  BCA  Report  and  the  technical  analysis  of  the  16  case  studies.    

Table  1  International  PES  case  studies  used  in  the  technical  analysis  

No.   Author     Key  focus  of  PES  case  study  

Summarized  PES  Case  Studies  (see  Appendix  A)  

#1   Asquith  et  al   The  US  Fish  and  Wildlife  Service  and  downstream  irrigators  (supported  by  the  

Page 9: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

9

(2008)   municipality)  pay  landowners  to  preserve  and  protect  forests  in  Los  Negros,  Bolivia.  The  ES  addressed  are  habitat  for  birds  and  stable  water  flows  provided  by  the  forest.      

#2   Barstad  et  al  (2011)  

Free-­‐willing  individuals/NGOs  voluntarily  pay  forest  landowners  in  New  England  to  improve  watershed  management  and  the  supply  of  ES  like  clean  water,  recreation,  and  fish  habitat.  

#3   Barton  et  al  (2009)  

The  Costa  Rica  government  pays  forest  landowners  to  preserve  their  land  for  the  maintenance  of  ES  from  forests.  

#4   Clements  et  al  (2010  )  

Three  case  studies  in  Cambodia:  Program  1  and  2  aims  to  make  farmers  and  villagers  stop  hunting  endangered  species  and  abide  by  a  land-­‐use  plan  by  paying  them  a  share  of  the  entrance  fees  from  an  ecotourism  site  or  allowing  them  to  sell  their  rice  under  a  “Wildlife  –Friendly”  brand  which  gives  them  a  more  favorable  price.  Program  3  pays  locals  to  protect  bird  nests  and  habitats.  The  NGO  “Wildlife  Conservation  Society”  (WCS)  is  in  charge  of  the  program  and  is  also  funding  and  distributing  the  payments.  

#5   Costa  (2011)  Payment  of  landowners  in  Guatemala  (Alta  Verapaz)  for  provision  of  habitat  for  migrant  species,  biodiversity,  and  freshwater  supply  by  governments  and  international  donors  (hypothetical  framework  only).  

#6   Dobbs  and  Pretty  (2008  )  

The  UK  government  pays  farmers  and  other  land  managers  for  a  range  of  environmental  preservation  and  restoration  projects  to  preserve  or  improve  ES  like  habitat  for  birds,  biodiversity,  landscape  beauty  and  historic  preservation.  

#7   Frost  and  Bond  (2008)  

Safari  operators  in  Zimbabwe  pay  farming  communities  in  wildlife  areas  to  refrain  from  exploitation  and  hunting  of  big  game,  which  improve  ESs  related  to  wildlife  habitat  and  aesthetic  views..  

#8   Kosoy  et  al  (2006)  

Programs  in  Honduras,  Nicaragua,  and  Costa  Rica  whereby  water  users  pay  a  fee  to  forest  landowners  to  manage  forests  to  improve  ESs  related  to  water  quality  and  flows.  

#9   Kosoy  et  al  (2008)  

The  Mexican  government  pays  Ejidos  (territory  held  in  common  by  a  group  of  families)  to  increase  and  stabilize  the  flow  of  ES  from  forests,  with  an  emphasis  on  biodiversity  and  carbon  sequestration,  through  different  management  and  preservation  projects.  

#10   Munoz  et  al  (2008)  

Water  users  pay  a  fee  to  the  Mexican  government,  who  distributes  this  to  primary  forest  landowners  to  preserve  forests  and  the  benefits  it  provides  to  the  watershed.  

#11   Pagiola  (2008)  

Firms  pay  forest  landowners  in  Costa  Rica  for  the  preservation  of  their  forests  to  keep  or  improve  the  flow  of  ES  related  to  water  regulation,  biodiversity,  carbon  sequestration  and  landscapes  beauty.  

#12   Phuc  Xuan  To  et  al(2012)  

Three  PES  schemes  in  Vietnam:  (1)  The  government  pays  households  for  forest  protection  and  forest  planting  to  maintain  and  improve  the  ES  these  forests  provides;  (2)  Hydropower  plants  and  (3)  water  supply  organizations  pay  households  for  forest  preservation  to  maintain  water  regulation  and  soil  protection  

#13   Sommerville  et  al  (2010)  

The  NGO  Durrell  pays  eight  communities  in  Madagascar  who  own  local  forest  management  rights  to  refrain  from  exploiting  or  damaging  the  area.  The  program  preserves  biodiversity  and  saves  the  only  remaining  habitat  for  four  endangered  species.        

#14   Turpie  et  al  (2008)  

Water  users  in  South  Africa  pay  a  fee  on  their  water  tariff  that  is  distributed  by  the  government  to  roving  service  providers  who  perform  management  activities  to  improve  ES  flows  from  grasslands  such  as  water  quality.  

#15   Wunder  and  Alban  (2008)  

Two  cases  in  Ecuador:  (1)  Pimampiro:  (2000-­‐2005)  is  a  watershed  scheme  where  municipal  water  users  pay  landowners  in  the  highlands  to  improve  water  quality  and  quantity  of  water  supply;  (2)  PROFAFOR,  (1993-­‐2005)  is  a  carbon-­‐sequestration  program  where  Dutch  electricity  companies  pay  landowners  and  communities  to  re-­‐forest  and  afforest  to  meet  carbon  reduction  goals.  

Page 10: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

10

#16  Zabel  and  Bostedt  (2010)  

The  Swedish  government  compensates  indigenous  Sami  villages  for  allowing  their  reindeer  to  roam  free,  which  can  result  in  predation  by  the  wolverine  and  lynx.  The  compensation  payment  serves  as  an  incentive  for  these  villages  to  refrain  from  hunting  these  two  endangered  species,  thus  protecting  biodiversity.    

Other  relevant  studies  related  to  PES  and  Vietnam          

Huynh  Thi,  Mai  (2011)    

(“The  BCA  Report”)  Study  by  the  Biodiversity  Conservation  Agency  that  considers  a   possible   roadmap   for   using   PES   to   conserve   the   country’s   biodiversity.   Study  analyzed  further  in  Section  4.1  of  this  report.    

Dougill  et  al  (2012)  

A  case  study  of  the  institutional  characteristics  of  three  African  community-­‐based  forest  projects  aiming  for  carbon-­‐storage  and  poverty-­‐reduction  benefits.  Based  on  interviews  and  a  literature  review,  the  study  makes  several  findings  related  to    PES  project  design.  

Gauvin  et  al  (2010)  Study   reviews   China’s   Grain   for   Green   PES   scheme   (largest   in   the   world)   and  examine   whether   the   environmental   and   poverty   alleviation   objectives   of   PES  programs  can  be  achieved  cost  effectively.    

Hawkins  et  al  (2010)  

Study   assesses   the   legal   and   regulatory   frameworks   in   Vietnam   for   mangrove  management  and  the  potential  of  using  PES  in  this  context.  The  study  is  motivated  by   the   government’s   interest   in   using   market   mechanisms   as   a   potential  conservation  tool  and  to  assess  the  viability  of  extending  current  PES  schemes  into  mangrove  forests.      

Hoang  Minh  Ha  (2008)  

A  PES  Booklet  designed   for  Vietnam’s  policy  makers  and  other  stakeholders   that  aims   to   describe   the   on-­‐going   PES   work   in   Vietnam.   The   booklet   has   been  developed   by   ICRAF   Vietnam   and   supported   by   international   and   national  partners,  including  WWF,  IUCN,  CIFOR  and  FSIV.  It  describes  several  on-­‐going  PES  case  studies  in  Vietnam  and  also  summarizes  a  number  of  lessons  learned.  

McElwee  (2010)    

Study  examines  how  landowners  rely  on  forests  in  central  Vietnam  and  considers  the   need   for   income   substitution   for   households   who   lose   access   to   forest  resources  due  to  conservation  efforts  in  or  near  protected  areas;    

McElwee  (2012)    

Given   Vietnam’s   unique   national   law   on   PES,   this   article   considers   how  market-­‐based   instruments   for   forest   conservation  have  expanded   in  Vietnam  and  how   it  may  continue  to  play  out  in  the  future.    

MONRE  (2010)  

Project  funded  by  Global  Environment  Facility  (GEF)  to  evaluate  the  challenges  to  managing  Vietnam’s  network  of  protected  areas,  which  form  a  cornerstone  of  the  country’s  biodiversity  conservation  strategy.  To  secure  a  sustainably  financed  protected  area  network  the  report  suggests,  among  other  things,  that  PES  schemes  may  play  a  vital  role  by  raising  government  revenue,  in  particular  in  coastal  wetland  and  marine  protected  areas.    

MONRE  (2012)  

Vietnam’s  National  Biodiversity  Strategy  and  Action  Plan  to  2020-­‐draft  (with  a  vision  to  2030)  determines  the  objectives  and  tasks  for  the  conservation  and  sustainable  use  of  biological  diversity  in  accordance  with  the  country’s  obligations  as  a  member  to  the  Convention  on  Biological  Diversity.  

Nguyen  Thuy  Duong  et  al  (2011)  

Report   produced   by   Vietnam’s   Institute   of   Strategy   and   Policy   on   Natural  Resources  and   the  environment  (ISPONRE)   that  examines   the  potential   for  using  PES   in   wetland   environments   in   Vietnam.   The   study’s   objective   is   to   develop   a  theoretical   basis   for   a   PES   scheme   based   on   the   environmental   services   that  wetlands   provide   and   to   ensure   this   meets   Vietnam’s   requirements   for   the  conservation  and  sustainable  development  of  wetlands.  

Petheram  and  Campbell  (2011)  

Study   analyzes   local   peoples’   attitudes   and  preferences   related   to   a   hypothetical  introduction  of  PES  scheme  Cat  Tien  National  Park  in  Vietnam.  The  study  assessed  factors   affecting   participants’   willingness   to   participate   in   a   PES   scheme,  preferences  for  the  structure  and  design,  participants’  capacity  to  participate,  and  other  contextual  issues  that  may  affect  program  success.  

Pham  et  al  (2010)   Study  assesses  the  role  of  intermediaries  as  actors  in  facilitating  PES,  which  

Page 11: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

11

include  government  agencies,  non-­‐government  organizations,  international  agencies,  local  organizations  and  professional  consulting  firms.  The  play  important  roles  related  to  service  and  information  providers,  mediators,  arbitrators,  equalizers,  representatives,  watchdogs,  developers  of  standards  and  bridge  builders.    

Wertz-­‐Kanounnikoff  (2006).  

Study  assesses  four  types  of  PES  systems  and  considers  the  economic,  ecological  and  social  considerations  in  developing  each  of  these  types  of  schemes.    

 

The  formal  summary  of  each  PES  case  study  in  Appendix  A  is  based  around  a  consistent  and  project-­‐relevant  set  of  technical  questions.  The  research  team  developed  these  questions  with  an  eye  toward  designing  the  proposed  PES  structure  for  this  project.  These  include:  

• Study  background  o Where  is  the  study  located?    o How  was  funding  obtained  to  start  the  project?    o How  long  did  the  experiment  last?  

• Ecosystem  services  addressed    o Which  ES  are  addressed?  o How  are  they  measured?    o What  are  the  key  threats?    o What  management  activities/action  can  improve  the  flow  of  these  ES?  

• Key  points  tested  or  analyzed    o What  is  bought  and  sold?  o Who  are  the  buyers  and  sellers?  o What  is  the  time  frame  for  project  and  for  payment?  o How  was  price  established?  o What  administrative  structure  was  used  to  deliver  payments  and  enforce  

contracts?  • Key  results    

o Did  it  work?  • Key  lessons  learned    

o What  are  the  relevant  lessons  learned  for  policy  makers?  

   

Page 12: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

12

4. Results  of  International  PES  Literature  Review  Below  we  summarize  some  of  the  key  conclusions  from  the  PES  literature,  including  a  summary  of  the  findings  from  The  BCA  Report  (Section  4.1)  and  the  conclusions  from  our  technical  analysis  (Section  4.2).  The  technical  analysis  is  organized  around  the  project-­‐relevant  set  of  technical  questions  identified  above.    

 

4.1. Summary  of  the  findings  of  The  BCA  Report  (Huynh  Thi  2011)    

The  BCA  Report  (Huynh  Thi  2011)  was  motivated  by  a  need  to  develop  and  implement  a  comprehensive  policy  on  the  payment  for  environmental  services  in  Vietnam,  i.e.,  develop  a  policy  interpretation  and  target  for  Article  74  of  the  BCL.  The  goal  is  to  generate  financial  resources  to  support  the  conservation  of  biodiversity  through  the  use  of  PES.  The  key  objectives  of  this  report  were  to:  

1. Review  international  experience  with  PES  for  biodiversity  (Section  4.1.1)  2. Assess  the  potential  application  of  PES  in  Vietnam  (Section  4.1.2)  3. Propose  a  nationwide  policy  and  a  roadmap  for  PES  in  Vietnam  (Section  4.1.3)  

 

4.1.1. Review  international  experience  with  PES  for  biodiversity    

The  BCA  Report  notes  that  hundreds  of  PES  programs  exist  globally.  Those  in  developed  countries  tend  to  focus  on  payment  to  farmers  to  reduce  the  intensity  of  agricultural  practices,  while  programs  in  developing  countries  frequently  focus  on  payment  of  landowners  for  forest  management  activities.  The  review  covers  PES  programs  in  Latin  America  (e.g.,  Costa  Rica,  Mexico,  Bolivia,  Ecuador,  Honduras,  etc.),  Europe  (buyers  in  Germany  that  purchase  ES  from  landowners  in  Latin  America),  and  Asia  (China,  Indonesia,  Philippines,  Nepal,  etc.).  The  report  classifies  the  these  global  PES  systems  into  four  major  categories  depending  on  the  ecosystem  service  they  focus  on:  

1. Watershed  protection  2. Biodiversity  conservation  3. Carbon  sequestration  4. Landscape/Ecotourism  

In  reviewing  general  lessons  learned  from  these  programs  the  report  identifies  a  number  of  findings:      

• The  PES  model  may  not  be  optimal  in  all  cases.  It  works  best  when  (a)  the  ES  are  clearly  defined  (b)  beneficiaries  can  be  identified  (c)  land-­‐use  and  property  rights  are  clearly  defined  (d)  a  strong  legal  system  exists  and  (e)  natural  resources  can  be  measured  and  valued.  PES  models  are  most  effective  when  the  value  of  ESs  to  beneficiaries  is  high  and  the  cost  of  providing  them  by  suppliers  is  low  (see  Gauvin  et  

Page 13: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

13

al  2010).  In  reality,  the  value  of  ES  may  vary  considerably  and  may  be  a  function  of  geography,  intensity  of  use,  competition,  demand  for,  and  cost  of,  associated  market  goods  that  depend  on  the  ES,  and  the  extent  of  the  market.  

• A  natural  tension  can  arise  between  efficiency  and  fairness  in  a  PES  model.  A  cost-­‐efficient  model  is  one  that  minimizes  transaction  costs  but  reaching  an  environmental  target  may  require  significant  data  collection,  which  can  lead  to  high  transaction  costs.  Moreover,  an  efficient  PES  model  would,  in  some  cases  pay  certain  landowner  more  than  others  if  the  quality  of  their  land  and  ES  provision  is  greater.    This  may  raise  concerns  about  fairness  among  participants  and  affect  acceptance  of  the  model.    

• To  ensure  an  effective  PES  model  the  government  must  play  an  active  and  important  role  in  the  design  and  regulation  of  the  program,  in  particular  in  the  early  stages  of  pilot  testing  and  model  development  when  the  market  infrastructure  is  not  fully  established  (see  also  Cole  et  al  2012).  Key  areas  of  government  involvement  include:  

o Legal  support  that  provides  protection  for  rights  of  local  communities  to  access  resources,  the  framework  for  buying  and  selling  ecosystem  services,  and  the  institutional  infrastructure  for  monitoring  and  enforcement  of  contracts.  

o Policy  support  that  provides  guidance,  lessons  learned  from  case  studies,  technical  support,  implementation  support  including  monitoring,  developing  standards,  supporting  scientific  research  (ecological  studies,  economic  valuation  studies,  etc.)  

o Financial  support,  which  requires  international  partnerships  and  investment.    o General  support  as  intermediaries  that  provide  information,  mediate,  arbitrate,  

represent,  and  provide  tools  that  promote  public  acceptance  and  participation  (see  Pham  et  al  2010).  

• PES  models  may  fail  without  full  participation  and  acceptance  by  the  community  members  whose  livelihood  depends  on  the  land.  This  suggests  that  Vietnam  develop  PES  models  that  include,  and  maximize  the  benefits  to,  poor  communities.  (see  Petheram  and  Campbell  2010).  

• Key  attributes  of  future  PES  models  in  Vietnam:  - Clarify  land  tenure;  - Create  and  strengthen  cooperative  organizations  to  reduce  transaction  costs;  - Identify  flexible  payment  mechanisms  that  are  cost-­‐effective;  - Provide  flexibility  in  land  use  regulations;  - Facilitate  access  to  finance  on  the  local  level;  and  - Invest  in  capacity-­‐building  for  participants  (this  is  frequently  lacking  from  

existing  PES  program,  see  Dougill  et  al  2012).  • Promote  acceptance  through  outreach  and  awareness-­‐raising  efforts.  The  BCA  Report  

notes  that  “The  success  of  PES  mechanisms  are  directly  dependent  on  the  knowledge,  awareness  and  the  public's  willingness  to  pay.”  

• Other  aspects  of  PES  schemes  that  are  important  to  consider:  - PES  model  development  requires  interdisciplinary  input  from  experts  in  

forestry,  ecology,  physics,  environmental  science,  environmental  economics.  This  suggests  that  Vietnam  actively  support  academic  and  scientific  research  in  the  areas  of  ecological  study  and  economic  valuation  of  ES.    

Page 14: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

14

- The  PES  model  must  define  the  ES  and  make  a  clear  link  between  the  current  and  future  use  of  land  and  the  provision  of  the  valued  ES.  This  should  consider  the  local  role  of  providers  and  beneficiaries.  

- Payments  must  offset  the  opportunity  costs  and  benefits  for  the  whole  community.  

- Monitoring  and  enforcement  of  contracts  is  critical.  

The  BCA  Report  also  makes  specific  findings  for  each  of  four  PES  categories  (watershed  protection,  biodiversity  conservation,  carbon  sequestration,  landscape/ecotourism)  in  BCA  Sections  1.2.3.1  -­‐  1.2.3.4  and  specific  findings  related  to  the  PES  model  structure  in  BCA  Sections  1.2.4.1 - 1.2.4.5.

 

4.1.2. Assess  the  potential  application  of  PES  in  Vietnam.    

The  BCA  Report  considers  the  implication  of  these  PES  findings  above  for  the  future  application  of  PES  approach  into  Vietnam  (BCA  Section  1.2.4).    

The  BCA  Report  (BCA  Section  2.4.3)  concludes  that  the  need  and  potential  for  expanding  PES  in  Vietnam  is  strong  given  the  country’s  unique  ecosystems  and  the  valuable  services  they  provide  (e.g.,  in  limiting  natural  disasters,  regulating  climate,  absorbing  CO2,  providing  recreation,  etc.).  Environmental  legislation  in  the  country  has  developed  since  2003  and  provides  a  basis  to  build  upon  the  recent  progressive  policies  associated  with  Biodiversity  Law  (13/11/2008),  the  Forest  PES  pilot  study  (Decision  380/2008),  and  the  policy  to  replicate  the  Forest  PES  success  elsewhere  in  the  country  (Decree  No.  99/2010/ND-­‐CP  24  May  9  2010).  The  need  for  continued  improvement  of  environmental  management  is  underscored  by  the  country’s  rapid  economic  growth,  which  will  increase  pressure  on  natural  resources  while  also  improving  citizens’  standards  of  living  and  demand  for  environmental  services.  

The  potential  for  future  growth  of  PES  models  in  Vietnam  are  connected  to  the  country’s  critical  ecological  assets:  coastal  wetland  ecosystems  and  the  marine  environment  (see  e.g.,  Decree  No.  99/2010/ND-­‐CP  of  September  24,  2010).  Therefore  The  BCA  Report  suggests  that  a  PES  policy  roadmap  should  focus  on  wetlands  (both  coastal  and  inland)  and  marine  ecosystems  to  ensure  sustainable  development  of  the  country’s  valued  resources  while  also  working  towards  poverty  alleviation  (See  BCA  Sections  2.4.1  and  2.4.2)  

Section  2.4.2  of  The  BCA  Report  discusses  the  potential  for  applying  PES  programs  to  coastal  marine  ecosystems,  which  includes  mangrove  forests  (as  well  as  coral  reefs,  sea  grass  beds,  tidal  flats,  and  lagoons).  The  mangrove  ecosystem,  which  is  the  focus  of  this  project,  has  been  adversely  impacted  by  human  activities  in  recent  decades.  MONRE  (2010)  note  that:  

In  coastal  areas,  mangroves  are  cleared  and  land  is  drained  for  aquaculture.  This  expansion  of  arable  land  and  aquaculture  areas  occurs  under  government  policy  guidelines  to  meet  food  demands  for  the  growing  population  and  to  promote  the  

Page 15: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

15

necessary  economic  development  of  the  country  by  increasing  highly  valuable  agricultural  produce  and  seafood  exports.  However,  much  of  the  converted  land  is  of  limited  productivity  and  is  often  abandoned;  this  is  especially  true  of  shrimp  farms  in  mangrove  areas.  (p.  18)  

Since  1943  mangrove  forest  cover  in  Vietnam  has  declined  by  over  60%.  Today,  planted  mangroves  outnumber  natural  mangrove  forests  60%  to  40%  (National  forest  inventory  in  Decision  03/2001/QD/TTg  of  the  Prime  Minister  dated  5/1).  The  mangrove  ecosystem  provides  both  direct  economic  value  (e.g.,  firewood  and  coal)  as  well  as  indirect  values  associated  with  carbon  sequestration,  coastal  fisheries  production,  storm  surge  protection,  protection  against  saltwater  intrusion  into  drinking  water  supplies,  provision  of  biological  diversity  (e.g.,  rare  animals  and  plants)  and  provision  of  recreational  and  eco-­‐tourism  (See  Hawkins  et  al  2010).  Activity  2.7  of  this  Project  will  assess  these  values  in  order  to  inform  the  construction  of  the  PES  payment  structure  for  Mui  Ca  Mau  National  Park.  

Finally,  The  BCA  Report  suggests  locations  in  Vietnam  where  a  pilot  PES  program  for  the  marine  environment  may  be  feasible.  Based  the  following  criteria,  Mui  Ca  Mau  National  Park  is  suggested  as  one  of  21  government-­‐owned  protected  areas  that  would  be  an  ideal  testing  ground:  (1)  socio-­‐economic  conditions  suggest  poverty  alleviation  is  a  policy  relevant  objective  (2)  ownership  of  selected  ES  are  clearly  defined  (in  this  case  by  the  State)  and  (3)  an  established  private  market  exists  for  goods  and  services  that  are  dependent,  in  part,  on  the  marine  ES.    

 

4.1.3. Propose  a  nationwide  policy  and  a  roadmap  for  PES  in  Vietnam    

The  final  section  of  the  Report  develops  guidelines  for  a  PES  payment  mechanism  including  the  following  (BCA  Sections  3.2.2,  3.2.3,  Recommendations  and  Conclusions)  

• Future  PES  schemes  should  focus  on  wetlands  and  the  marine  environment.  • The  environmental  services  underlying  a  future  PES  scheme  for  wetlands  could  

potentially  involve  (1)  aquaculture,  seafood,  green  labeling  for  fisheries,  (2)  ecotourism,  and  (3)  water  regulation.  Similarly,  for  the  marine  environment,  relevant  environmental  services  may  include  (1)  aquaculture,  seafood,  green  labeling  for  fisheries  and  (2)  ecotourism.  Hawkins  et  al  (2010)  note  that  in  a  mangrove  PES  scheme  carbon  sequestration  could  be  a  complementary  revenue  source  for  service  providers,  but  due  to  the  ecological  characteristics  of  the  mangrove  habitat  and  absorption,  it  is  best  combined  with  other  ESs  from  mangrove  habitat.    

• The  providers  should  be  selected  based  on  consideration  of  land  ownership  and  management  activities  in  the  area.  The  report  suggests  providers  could  be  protected  areas  (e.g.,  national  parks,  biosphere  reserves,  Ramsar  sites),  communities  themselves,  or  the  aquaculture  producer  association.  

• The  service  users  (beneficiaries)  could  include  mining  enterprises,  seafood  processing  companies,  electricity  companies,  water  supply  companies,  tour  operators,  

Page 16: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

16

restaurants,  resorts,  hotels,  consumers  directly  (retail),  factories  near  the  sea,  NGOs,  visitors/tourists,  cruise  ships,  fishing  boats,  or  other  institutions.  

• The  price  (and  payment  type)  should  consider  several  factors  including:  the  type  of  service,  the  opportunity  costs  for  the  seller  of  undertaking  the  ES-­‐promoting  activity  (i.e.,  active  protection  or  avoided  exploitation),  the  value  to  society  of  the  service  and/or  the  cost  to  society  of  alternative  provision  of  the  service  to  the  buyer,  negotiation  between  provider  and  user  in  accordance  with  relevant  laws,  the  results  of  pilot  studies,  and/or  the  recommendations  for  payment  mechanisms  under  Decree  No.  99/2010/ND-­‐CP.    

• The  payment  type  may  involve  direct  payments  for  the  use  of  environmental  services  to  the  provider  (e.g.,  branding  clean  animal  feed  as  environmentally-­‐friendly,  or  a  premium  for  undertaking  clean  aquaculture  techniques)  or  indirect  payments  (e.g.,  fees  collected  in  an  environmental  trust  and  invested  into  the  community  for  infrastructure,  vocational  training,  short  and  long  term  loans,  etc.).  Additional  funds  could  be  secured  by  soliciting  contributions  from  other  beneficiaries  –  either  voluntary  or  obligatory  -­‐  for  the  restoration  of  ecosystems.    

The  report  suggests  two  possible  roadmaps  for  PES  development  in  Vietnam  and  proposes  a  time  schedule  to  select  the  appropriate  alternative  (2012-­‐2016).  The  two  alternatives  are:  

1. Alternative  1:  Develop  a  common  and  general  policy  framework  for  all  types  of  ES  that  could  be  covered  in  a  future  PES  scheme.  The  framework  would  identify  services,  providers,  beneficiaries,  payment  structure,  etc.  to  support  the  implementation  of  PES  nationwide.  This  alternative  meets  the  requirements  of  the  Law  on  Biodiversity  2008,  but  may  be  time-­‐consuming  to  develop.  Further,  it  maybe  too  general  to  allow  for  application  to  specific  PES  models.    

2. Alternative  2:  Focus  time  and  resources  into  developing  a  policy  for  specific  ESs  such  as  wetlands  or  marine  ecosystems.  This  alternative  can  be  put  into  practice  immediately  and  may  represent  a  more  promising  approach  given  the  importance  of  these  ecosystems  to  Vietnam’s  biodiversity.  However,  this  alternative  may  require  development  of  other  policy  documents  to  meet  the  requirements  specified  in  Article  74  of  the  Law  on  Biodiversity  2008.    

 

4.2. Technical  analysis  of  PES  case  studies  Below  we  summarize  the  results  of  our  technical  analysis  of  the  16  case  studies.  

4.2.1. Background  on  case  studies  Most  of  the  case  studies  we  examined  were  funded  by  governments  or  non-­‐governmental  organizations  (NGOs).  Most  of  the  studies  we  reviewed  were  from  developing  countries  in  Latin  America,  South  America,  Africa  and  Asia  but  also  some  from  Europe  and  USA.      

The  types  of  PES  that  were  most  frequent  in  the  case  studies  were  community-­‐based  tax-­‐payer  funded  markets  and  tax-­‐payer  funded  initiatives  by  the  states  (This  is  also  

Page 17: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

17

supported  by  Cole  et  al  2012).  That  is,  in  most  cases  the  buyer  was  the  government  and  the  sellers  were  individual  landowners,  often  households.    However,  there  were  some  cases  of  voluntary  markets  but  only  a  few  of  them  managed  fully  to  fund  the  scheme.  

The  source  of  funding  for  PES  schemes  vary.  Jindal  and  Kerr  (2007)  note  that  ”payments  for  these  schemes  come  from  private  corporations,  international  NGOs,  research  institutes,  governments,  even  private  individuals”  (p.  2).  In  almost  all  cases  external  funding  is  required  to  jump-­‐start  the  program,  while  on-­‐going  administration  costs  are  covered  by  buyers  through  their  payments.  Because  buyers  are  often  governments  or  NGOs,  the  practical  implication  is  that  the  cost  to  the  taxpayer  of  running  these  types  of  PES  programs  can  be  considerable.  Administration  costs  in  general  are  a  challenge  for  ensuring  a  long-­‐term  and  sustainable  PES  program.  

Many  of  the  PES  programs  have  been  in  place  since  the  late  80s,  while  some  have  started  in  recent  years.  The  majority  have  been  operational  for  several  years,  but  some  lack  extensive  assessment.  Such  studies  require  either  additional  years  in  operation  or  improved  evaluation  studies  to  determine  their  success.  Further,  assessing  the  success  of  PES  programs  was  easier  when  the  program  had  administrative  staff  and  other  infrastructure  to  facilitate  program  evaluation.  

 

4.2.2. Ecosystem  services  addressed    Most  of  the  PES  schemes  are  focusing  on  a  broad  perspective  of  ES,  such  as  ES  from  forests  or  watersheds,  rather  than  a  specific  ES.    The  most  common  ES  addressed  in  the  case  studies  are  ES  from  forests  or  watersheds,  which  both  mainly  focus  on  the  provision  of  water-­‐related  services.    However,  other  studies  focused  on  the  protection  of  habitats  for  endangered  species,  biodiversity  in  general,  carbon  sequestration  and  aesthetic  views.  This  finding  is  consistent  with  the  four  categories  that  The  BCA  report  identify  (see  Section  4.1.1  above).  

While  many  of  the  case  studies  focused  on  water  related  ES  none  of  them  focus  specifically  on  coastal  wetland  areas  or  mangrove  forests.    

 

4.2.3. Technical  aspects  of  PES  schemes      

4.2.3.1. The  ecosystem  service  bought  and  sold      The  most  commonly  occurring  service  bought  and  sold  is  preservation  of  ES  from  forests  or  forested  landscapes,  i.e.,  to  refrain  from  exploitation  or  conversion  of  forests  to  agriculture,  to  abide  by  land-­‐use  plans,  or  to  simply  protect  an  area.  This  is  linked  with  the  above-­‐mentioned  broad  perspective  of  ES  in  the  case  studies  where  forests  provide  a  wide  range  of  ES.  The  most  common  metric  used  is  hectares  of  preserved  forest  but  some  also  measure  quality  changes.    Most  of  these  activities  are  connected  to  the  provision  of  water  and  in  a  great  share  of  the  studies  the  actual  good  bought  is  the  provision  of  water  either  as  an  input  factor  for  a  company  or  for  domestic  use  and  the  preservation  is  only  a  

Page 18: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

18

means  to  achieve  this  objective.  Other  services  bought  and  sold  connected  to  forests  and  forested  watersheds  are  reforestation  and  manual  clearing  of  invasive  plants.    The  most  common  measures  in  these  cases  are  hectares  reforested  or  cleared  but  in  some  case  studies  efforts  were  made  to  translate  number  of  trees  planted  or  protected  into  pounds  of  carbon  sequestrated.    

In  some  cases  the  management  activities  that  sellers  were  required  to  implement  to  improve  the  flow  of  ES  (in  exchange  for  payment)  were  based  on  a  land  management  plan.  For  example,  the  sellers  signed  up  for  different  specific  projects  such  as  no  burning  before  or  after  planting,  planting  of  vegetal  fences,  prevention  and  control  of  forest  fires,  no  extraction  of  wood  products,  implementation  of  organic  agriculture  and  refraining  from  pesticides  or  agro-­‐chemicals.  

Other  common  services  bought  and  sold  is  to  prohibit  land  uses  that  negatively  affect  habitats  for  endangered  species  or  to  prohibit  hunting.  In  one  case  study  local  villagers  are  paid  to  manually  protect  extra  sensitive  habitats  such  as  bird  nests  and  the  metric  used  was  the  number  of  successfully  fledged  chicks.  Petheram  and  Campbell  (2010)  find  that  potential  PES  participants  in  Vietnam  oppose  the  idea  of  payments  for  avoided  resource  use  alone  and  McElwee  (2010)  note  that  PES  schemes  that  restrict  income-­‐generating  resource  use  should  be  balanced  by  alternative  employment  and  sufficient  income  to  ensure  long-­‐term  effectiveness  of  the  PES  scheme.  

In  many  of  the  case  studies  the  metric  used  to  measure  the  level  of  ES  provided/sold  was  not  specified.  Since  ES  measurement  is  a  critical  component  of  a  successful  PES  model,  this  requires  significant  consideration  when  designing  the  PES  model  structure.  

Many  PES  schemes  suffer  from  a  lack  of  scientific  data  that  links  the  activity  of  a  seller  (e.g.,  planting  a  tree)  to  a  measurable  and  quantifiable  increase  in  the  ES  being  sold  (e.g.,  carbon  sequestration  or  water  quality/quantity)  and,  ultimately,  how  this  improvement  affects  human  welfare  (i.e.,  the  value  to  society).  This  is  a  key  area  of  future  research  to  improve  PES  implementation  (Barstad  et  al  2012;  Dougill  et  al  2012).  

 

4.2.3.2. The  buyers  and  sellers  Although  most  buyers  are  government  agencies,  international  NGOs  or  municipalities,  there  were  some  cases  of  private  buyers,  such  as  households  or  firms  that  consume  water,  safari  operators  or  other  tourist  companies.  Petheram  and  Campbell  (2010)  point  out  that  local  PES  participants  in  Vietnam  may  not  trust  that  the  government  has  the  money  to  pay  them  or  that  authorities  would  manage  funds  honestly,  which  is  an  important  consideration  in  designing  the  PES  structure.  

In  nearly  all  case  studies  the  seller  is  either  specified  as  individual  forest  landowners,  land  managers,  local  farmers  or  local  villages  or  farming  communities.  In  the  remaining  cases,  the  seller  was  a  roving  service  provider  who  perform  restoration  on  land  under  any  type  of  ownership.  

Page 19: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

19

Most  PES  programs  cannot  avoid  the  existence  of  non-­‐buying  beneficiaries  who  benefit  from  the  purchases  made  by  actual  buyers  (e.g.,  the  general  public,  firms,  private  and  communal  landowners,  and  other  ES  users  .  This  may  have  implications  for  whether  the  price  paid  for  the  ES  actually  reflects  society’s  value  for  it.    There  were  several  examples  in  the  case  studies  of  two  buyers  for  the  same  service,  which  may  reduce  the  incentives  to  participate  in  PES  programs.  In  other  cases,  sellers  themselves  also  benefit  from  the  activities.    

4.2.3.3. Contracts  and  payment  The  most  common  time  frames  for  contracts  are  between  1-­‐10  years  with  annual  payments.  However  the  length  of  contracts  and  the  time  frames  for  payments  vary  significantly.  The  shortest  contracts  were  one  year  and  the  longest  were  indefinite.  Some  contracts  ran  for  50  to  99  years.  Besides  annual  payments,  some  were  monthly  and  even  daily  (e.g.,  to  local  villagers  who  protected  bird  nests).  

 

4.2.3.4. Determining  price  In  most  studies  the  price  was  determined  by  negotiation  between  the  buyer  and  seller,  often  through  intermediaries  and  agencies  responsible  for  the  programs.  The  benchmark/starting  price  for  the  negotiations  were  often  based  on  incomes  forgone,  average  opportunity  costs  or  costs  for  the  restoration/activities.  None  of  the  articles  specify  in  detail  how  the  price  was  addressed  but  rather  broadly  describe  the  approach  used.  

In  a  few  of  the  case  studies  the  price  was  set  directly  by  the  government  agency  (e.g.,  based  on  the  size  of  the  government  budget)  or  was  determined  based  on  political  considerations.  In  some  of  the  studies  the  prices  were  weighted  according  to  affordability,  assurance  of  supply  and  equity  while  in  some  the  price  was  determined  by  tender  offers.  

 

4.2.3.5. Administration  &  enforcement  of  the  PES  scheme    In  most  of  the  studies  the  payments  are  administered  by  an  intermediate,  often  a  centralized  or  decentralized  governmental  agency  but  also  in  some  cases  NGOs,  which  receive  payments  from  the  buyers  and  distribute  them  to  the  sellers.  For  example  some  water  users  pay  a  fee  that  is  distributed  by  the  intermediary  to  the  sellers.    

In  the  great  majority  of  the  case  studies  the  payment  goes  through  the  intermediary  to  individual  landowners  or  households  but  in  some  cases  the  payments  go  to  villages  or  small  communities,  who  in  turn  decide  whether  to  distribute  the  payments  to  individual  households/landowners  or  make  investments  that  generate  benefits  for  the  village.    Furthermore,  in  a  few  cases  the  sellers  preferred  in-­‐kind  payments  before  payments  in  cash  because  they  did  not  have  a  reliable  way  to  manage  the  cash  and  expected  a  better  return  on  the  in-­‐kind  payments.  

Page 20: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

20

The  intermediary  is  frequently  responsible  for  the  monitoring  and  follow-­‐up  of  projects.  In  places  where  trust  of  institutions  was  lacking  or  in  places  with  high  risk  of  corruption,  monitoring  is  conducted  by  a  group  that  represents  all  parties  (e.g.,  buyers,  sellers,  NGOs,  the  municipality,  government  agency  etc.).  The  group  assesses  if  the  contractual  obligations  have  been  met.  In  some  cases  the  monitoring  is  made  by  non-­‐profit  organizations  or  by  rural  district  councils.  The  costs  of  monitoring  is  either  shared  between  all  parties  or  paid  only  by  the  buyers.  

Very  few  case  studies  describe  how  enforcement  is  performed,  but  some  programs  terminate  the  payments  to  sellers  in  the  case  of  non-­‐compliance.  Others  demand  that  previous  payments  be  paid  back  to  buyers.  

   

Page 21: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

21

 

5. Conclusions    

Future  PES  models  for  mangrove  ecosystems  in  Vietnam’s  coastal  wetlands  and  marine  environment  look  promising.  The  mangrove  ecosystem  provides  significant  value  to  society  in  terms  of  carbon  sequestration,  coastal  fisheries  production,  storm  surge  protection,  protection  against  saltwater  intrusion  into  drinking  water  supplies,  provision  of  biological  diversity  and  eco-­‐tourism.  Further,  Mui  Ca  Mau  National  Park  is  an  ideal  location  for  testing  a  PES  pilot.  However,  none  of  the  case  studies  reviewed  in  this  analysis  focused  on  wetlands  or  mangrove  forests.  Further,  poor  local  landowners  in  nearly  all  case  studies  were  the  sellers  of  ES.  Both  of  these  findings  suggest  that  our  proposed  PES  structure,  which  relies  on  a  livelihood  model  to  generate  income  for  local  landowners  who  then  become  the  buyers  of  ES  –  will  be  breaking  new  ground.  

Recent  work  conducted  by  BCA  and  other  local  Vietnamese  partners  have  made  some  preliminary  suggestions  on  how  to  design  a  PES  model  for  mangroves  in  Vietnam.  Their  work  provides  suggestions  on  the  environmental  services  that  could  underlie  the  PES  model,  the  types  of  providers  and  service  users,  payment  types,  and  factors  to  consider  when  determining  a  price.  This  recent  work  provides  a  valuable  basis  upon  which  this  project  will  build  in  proposing  a  draft  PES  structure  in  June  2013.  

Duplicating  the  success  of  the  Payment  for  Forest  Ecosystem  Services  pilot  for  the  case  of  mangrove  forests  in  Mui  Ca  Mau  National  Park  will  require  an  active  government  role  in  the  early  stages  of  model  development.  Government  agencies  will  have  to  inform  project  participants  about  the  legal,  policy,  and  financial  support  available  and  how  it  can  be  adapted  in  this  case  (see  Section  4.1.1).  Further,  PES  intermediaries  such  as  NGOs,  international  agencies,  researchers,  and  consulting  firms  will  need  to  provide  information  (e.g.,  interdisciplinary  research)  and  other  tools  to  facilitate  participation  by  local  communities  and  other  stakeholders.    

 

There  are,  nonetheless,  several  challenges  to  PES  implementation  in  the  Vietnam  setting.  Some  of  the  early  challenges  identified  in  Ferraro  and  Kiss  (2002)  still  hold  true  today,  not  the  least  in  Vietnam:  

“Potential  obstacles  to  implementing  a  direct  payment  approach  in  developing  na-­‐  tions  include  uncertain  or  inequitable  land  tenure,  limited  experience  with  and  en-­‐  forcement  of  legal  contracts,  and  limited  local  opportunities  for  nonagricultural  in-­‐  vestment  or  employment.  Direct  Payments  may  displace  biodiversity  loss  to  other  areas,  may  be  misappropriated  or  misused,  and  may  create  social  conflict.”  (p.  1718)  

These  issues  are  particularly  relevant  in  the  context  of  future  PES  development  in  Vietnam  and  deserve  special  consideration  in  designing  the  PES  structure.  McElwee  

Page 22: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

22

(2012)  suggest  that  market-­‐based  approaches  to  forest  management  in  Vietnam  are  unlikely  to  succeed  due  to  institutional  factors  such  as  uneven  land  tenure.  PES  development  in  Vietnam  may  be  further  challenged  by  the  lack  of  well-­‐defined  property  rights,  which  is  known  to  make  PES  implementation  difficult.  For  example,  if  poor  farmers  do  not  have  the  security  that  they  "own"  the  improvements  made  to  their  land,  they  may  not  have  the  incentive  to  undertake  activities  as  ES  providers.  Hawkins  et  al  (2010)  point  out  a  possible  restriction  in  applying  PES  for  mangrove  management  in  Vietnam  given  that  the  State  is  responsible  for  distributing  benefits  from  forest  resources  to  local  people  and  other  stakeholders.  The  implication  is  that  the  only  feasible  “seller”  in  a  PES  scheme  is  the  State  (under  some  rare  exceptions  private  owners  could  perhaps  participate),  which  may  limit  some  of  the  creativity  needed  to  develop  an  innovative  and  effective  PES  scheme.  Further,  trust  of  the  government  in  Vietnam  in  implementing  a  PES  may  be  weak  according  to  the  hypothetical  PES  assessment  conducted  in  Cat  Tien  National  park  in  Vietnam  (Peteram  and  Campbell  2011).  To  the  extent  that  central  or  local  institutions  lack  credibility  in  Vietnam  –  which  are  critical  for  the  administration  of  payments,  monitoring  of  contracts,  enforcement,  etc.  –  this  may  present  a  further  challenge  for  PES  models.  Finally,  Vietnam  faces  the  challenge  of  seeking  income  and  employment  substitution  for  PES  sellers  (landowners)  who  lose  access  to  forest  resources  and  where  PES  payments  are  not  sufficient  (McElwee  2010).  

A  specific  challenge  related  to  a  PES  development  for  mangrove  forest  was  pointed  out  by  an  international  expert3  who  suggested  that  participants/households  may  be  both  buyers  of  mangrove  goods  and  services  (shrimp  habitat,  storm  protection,  etc.),  and  sellers  of  mangrove  conservation  (participation  in  mangrove  protection  and  re-­‐planting,  etc.).  This  is  an  important  point  to  consider  in  the  development  of  our  combined  PES  structure  and  livelihood  model  for  Mui  Ca  Mau  National  Park.  

There  are  also  general  challenges  to  PES  model  development,  such  as  measuring  the  quantity  or  quality  of  ESs  bought  or  sold.  For  example,  many  case  studies  relied  on  percent  forest  cover  as  a  proxy  (“metric”)  for  the  level  of  ES  that  the  forest  provides  such  as  carbon  sequestration,  biodiversity,  water  quantity/quality,  habitat  for  species,  etc.    However,  a  key  weakness  in  many  of  the  case  studies  we  reviewed  was  a  lack  of  scientific  data  that  links  the  activity  of  a  seller  (e.g.,  planting  a  tree  to  increase  forest  cover)  to  a  measurable  and  quantifiable  increase  in  the  relevant  ES  (e.g.,  biodiversity,  carbon  sequestration,  etc.)  and,  ultimately,  how  this  improvement  affects  human  welfare  (i.e.,  the  value  to  society).  Besides  tree  planting,  this  link  is  relevant  for  a  variety  of  other  activities  that  service  providers  may  undertake  such  as  the  effect  of  stream  buffers  on  water  quantity/quality,  the  effect  of  preventing  or  controlling  forest  fires  on  biodiversity,  the  benefits  of  organic  agriculture  on  habitat  quality,  etc.  

Another  general  challenge  to  PES  development  is  the  need  for  patience  from  policy  makers.    Despite  the  fact  that  many  of  the  programs  we  reviewed  had  been  in  effect  for  several  years  it  was  nonetheless  difficult  to  make  any  definitive  evaluations  about  

                                                                                                               3  See  box  26  in  MONRE  (2012),    Jake  Brunner,  IUCN,  August  2012.    

Page 23: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

23

project  success.  Some  PES  programs  can  take  years  to  become  institutionally  established  and  ripe  for  evaluation.  Furthermore,  there  can  be  significant  time  delays  between  ecosystem  restoration  (e.g.  tree  planting)  and  ecosystem  maturation  and  subsequent  economic  benefits  to  the  community.  

Finally,  some  challenges  are  hard  to  predict.  Despite  well-­‐intentioned  efforts  PES  systems  may  succeed  or  fail  based  on  un-­‐controllable  external  factors.  For  example,  a  program  that  pays  landowner  not  to  convert  native  vegetation  to  agricultural  land  in  Ecuador  benefited  from  the  fact  that  international  beef  prices  reduced  the  profitability  of  expanding  current  cattle  operations  (Wunder  and  Alban  2008).  In  another  PES  program  in  Ecuador  runaway  inflation  (due  to  a  financial  system  that  is  connected  to  the  US  dollar)  increased  program  costs  and  affected  the  overall  program  outcome.  

The  stated  policy  objective  may  influence  the  structure  of  the  PES  model.  The  primary  motivation  for  PES  development  is  to  improve  management  of  a  country’s  resources  by  creating  incentives  for  improving  the  flow  of  ES.  The  Government  of  Vietnam  has  additional  policy  objectives  that  include  poverty  reduction  and  an  increase  in  government  revenues.  A  key  empirical  question  is  whether  these  three  objectives  can  be  accomplished  simultaneously  or  whether  there  may  be  trade-­‐offs  or  conflicts  between  them.    

Some  of  the  empirical  research  addressing  possible  conflicts  between  these  goals  has  come  to  mixed  conclusions.  Few,  if  any,  PES  programs  have  focused  exclusively  on  poverty  reduction  or  increase  in  government  revenues,  but  Pagolia  (2008)  point  out  that  despite  this,  some  studies  have  shown  that  PES  can  be  positive  for  poor  areas.    However  Wunder  and  Alban  (2008)  suggest  that  while  the  two  projects  in  Ecuador  achieved  poverty  reduction  as  an  ancillary  benefit,  diluting  environmental  objectives  with  other  objectives  may  reduce  program  efficiency,  indicating  that  a  trade-­‐off  may  be  inevitable  (see  also  Landell-­‐Mills  and  Porras  (2002)  and  Gauvin  et  al  (2010)).  More  empirical  research  may  be  needed  to  address  this  issue.  An  even  more  relevant  question  for  this  project  is  how  the  multiple  policy  objectives  associated  with  proposed  PES  development  in  Vietnam  may  affect  the  design  and  structure  of  the  PES  model  we  proposed  in  Activity  2.12.  

Monitoring  and  enforcement  are  critical  to  program  success,  but  this  is  true  of  any  regulatory  approach,  not  just  PES.  For  example,  some  countries  have  chosen  to  implement  PES  in  addition  to,  or  as  an  alternative  to,  a  “command  and  control”  approach.  Importantly,  implementing  a  PES  approach  does  not  preclude  the  need  for  monitoring;  to  the  contrary,  enforcement  is  essential  to  ensure  credibility  of  a  relatively  new  and  innovative  approach.    

While  command  and  control  relies  on  the  “stick,”  PES  relies  on  the  “carrot”  to  influence  behavior,  but  both  require  enforcement.  Some  PES  case  studies  we  reviewed  tried  to  improve  the  environmental  outcome  by  “layering”  a  PES  approach  (e.g.,  paying  a  landowner  to  refrain  from  illegal  activity)  on  top  of  a  command  and  control  approach  (e.g.,  strictly  forbidding  a  landowner  from  the  illegal  activity).  A  better  alternative  might  be  to  increase  enforcement  of  the  command  and  control  instrument  or  to  raise  the  

Page 24: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

24

penalty  for  non-­‐compliance.  Wunder  and  Alban  (2008)  point  out  that  if  pre-­‐existing  regulatory  approaches  were  actually  enforced  some  PES  programs  may  be  unnecessary.  This  comes  back  to  the  need  for  strong  institutions  and  legal  frameworks.  One  study  noted  that  the  threat  of  enforcing  command-­‐and-­‐control  regulations  drove  the  sellers  back  to  the  negotiating  table  since  they  felt  they  might  lose  the  economic  incentives  inherent  in  the  PES  scheme.  

Fairness  concerns  must  be  actively  addressed.  An  efficient  PES  model  –  i.e.,  one  that  obtains  the  greatest  environmental  protection  at  the  lowest  cost  to  society  –  may  require  “differentiated  payments”  i.e.,  some  service  providers  may  receive  a  higher  price  than  others  if  they  are  able  to  produce  a  higher  level  or  quality  of  ES.  Some  participants  may  perceive  differentiated  payments  to  be  unfair.  To  manage  issues  of  fairness  and  to  ensure  long-­‐term  program  success,  Vietnam  must  consider  the  distributional  impacts  across  participants  (see  Dougill  et  al  2012).  Further,  they  must  actively  promote  the  benefits  of  PES  to  generate  public  support.  PES  case  studies  in  Vietnam  indicate  that  some  individuals  perceive  that  the  community  benefits  more  than  their  own  families.  In  other  cases,  only  a  portion  of  interested  households  participated  due  to  lack  of  information  about  the  existence  of  the  program.  In  still  other  cases,  information  only  reached  former  local  officials.  And  in  a  unique  case  in  Madagascar,  certain  participants  in  positions  of  local  political  power  received  a  higher  level  of  net  benefits  from  the  PES  program.  These  outcomes  and  the  associated  perceptions  can  undermine  the  success  of  PES  and  underscore  the  importance  of  active  measures  to  promote  public  acceptance  and  the  need  for  good  governance  at  all  levels.  

One  way  of  generating  acceptance  for  PES  programs  is  to  ensure  program  flexibility  for  participants.  While  PES  aims  to  improve  the  quality  of  life  for  participants  –  either  as  an  improved  flow  of  ES  for  buyers  (and,  in  many  cases,  sellers  as  well)  or  as  augmented  income  for  sellers  –  the  benefits  of  some  PES  schemes  may  best  be  measured  in  non-­‐monetary  terms,  including  improved  community  interaction,  bequest  values,  improved  human  capital  or  a  strengthening  of  individual  or  collective  motivation  for  environmental  protection.  Alternatively,  payment  mechanisms  may  be  in-­‐kind  (e.g.,  payment  of  livestock  or  other  valued  commodities)  instead  of  monetary.  This  type  of  flexibility  may  help  garner  support  and  acceptance  for  the  program.  

Fairness  concerns  also  arise  if  a  PES  model  excludes  potential  buyers  who  nonetheless  benefit  from  the  PES  program.  These  so-­‐called  “non-­‐paying  beneficiaries”  are  those  who  benefit  from  the  sellers’  provision  of  an  ES  but  are  not  required  to  pay  (sometimes  called  “free  riders”).  In  some  cases  it  may  be  difficult  to  get  these  participants  to  pay  their  portion  of  the  benefits  they  receive,4  which  underscores  the  importance  of  identifying  all  potential  buyers  during  the  PES  structure  and  design  phase.  

                                                                                                               4    This  may  be  explained  by  the  fact  that  ES  are  public  goods,  i.e.,  goods  that  provide  benefits  to  all  in  society.  It  is  challenging  to  get  individuals  to  pay  for  the  public  goods  because  there  is  an  incentive  to  “free  ride”  off  others  who  pay  for  and  provide  the  good.    The  result  is  that  public  goods  like  ESs  are  often  under-­‐supplied.  This  is,  of  course,  the  primary  motivation  for  PES  models  –  i.e.,  to  increase  the  supply  of  ES.  

Page 25: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

25

In  addition  to  buyers  and  sellers  themselves,  there  can  be  some  winners/losers  in  terms  of  the  institutions  that  carry  out  the  PES.  Sometimes  local  agencies  or  intermediaries  may  be  seen  as  pioneers  for  their  innovative  work  (“winners”),  while  others  may  be  seen  as  “losers”  if  the  PES  program  becomes  too  expensive  or  immediate  results  are  not  forthcoming.    

PES  pilot  design  is  important  for  future  evaluation.    Few  of  the  PES  case  studies  that  we  reviewed  considered  how  to  design  a  PES  structure  so  as  to  allow  for  effective  evaluation  in  the  future.  In  our  proposed  PES  structure  we  will  consider  how  to  incorporate  key  data  to  measure  program  success  over  time,  thus  improving  the  likelihood  that  the  model  can  adapt  and  survive  over  the  long  term.    

Page 26: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

26

References  Asquith,  N.  M.,  Vargas,  M.  T.,  &  Wunder,  S.  (2008).  Selling  two  environmental  services:  In-­‐kind  payments  for  bird  habitat  and  and  watershed  protection  in  Los  Negros,  Bolivia  .  Ecological  Economics  65  ,  pp.  675-­‐684.  

Biodiversity  Conservation  Agency  (BCA),  Institute  of  Strategy  and  Policy  on  Natural  Resources  and  Environment  (ISPNRE),  Ministry  of  Natural  Resources  and  Environment  (MONRE),  Research  Center  of  Forest  and  Wetlands  (FORWET),  Reforms,  Entrepreneurship  and  Sustainability  (FORES).  2012.  Developing  a  piloting  model  on  payments  for  coastal  wetland  ecosystem  services  in  Mui  Ca  Mau  National  Park  in  the  context  of  climate  change  contributing  to  poverty  reduction  in  local  community.  Project  workplan  submitted  to  Swedish  International  Development  Agency.  July.  Hanoi  

Barstad,  W.,  Dassler,  L.,  Gartner,  T.,  Gunn,  J.,  Russ,  M.,  Sleeper,  D.,  et  al.  (2012).  Northern  Forest  Watershed  Services:  Parallel  Pilot  Initiatives  Providing  Incentives  for  Forest  Management  and  Conservation  on  Private  lands.  American  Forest  Foundation.  

Barton,  D.,  Faith,  D.,  Rusch,  G.,  Acevedo,  H.,  Paniagua,  L.,  &  Castro,  M.  (2009).  Environmental  service  payments:  Evaluating  biodiversity  conservation  trade-­‐offs  and  cost-­‐efficiency  in  the  OSA  Conservation  Area,  Costa  Rica.  Journal  of  Environmental  Management  90  ,  901-­‐911.  

Clements,  T.,  Ashish,  J.,  Nielsen,  K.,  Dara,  A.,  Setha,  T.,  &  Milner-­‐Gulland,  E.  (2010).  Payments  for  biodiversity  conservation  in  the  context  of  weak  institutions:  Comparison  of  three  programs  from  Cambodia.  Ecological  Economics  69  ,  pp.  1283-­‐1291.  

Cole,  S.,  Hasselström,  L.,  Engkvist,  F.,  &  Söderqvist,  T.  (2012).  Using  markets  to  supply  ecosystem  services,  How  to  make  it  happen.  Stockholm:  FORES.  

Costa,  M.  M.  (2011).  A  participatory  framework  for  conservation  payments.  Land  Use  Policy  28  ,  pp.  423-­‐433.  

Dobbs,  T.  L.,  &  Pretty,  J.  (2008).  Case  study  of  agri-­‐environmental  payments:The  United  Kingdom.  Ecological  Economics  65  ,  pp.  765-­‐775.  

Dougill,  A.  J.,  Stringer,  L.  C.,  Leventon,  J.,  Riddell,  M.,  Rueff,  H.,  Spracklen,  D.  V.,  et  al.  (2012).  Lessons  from  community-­‐based  payment  for  ecosystem  service  schemes:  from  forests  to  rangelands.  Philosophical  transactions  of  the  royal  society  b-­‐biological  sciences  367  ,  pp.  3178-­‐3190.  

Engel,  S.,  &  Palmer,  C.  (2008).  Payments  for  environmental  services  as  an  alternative  to  logging  under  weak  property  rights:  The  case  of  Indonesia.  Ecological  Economics  65  ,  pp.  799-­‐809.  

Ferraro,  P.  J.,  &  Kiss,  A.  (2002).  Direct  Payments  to  Conserve  Biodiversity.  Science  Magazine  298  ,  1718-­‐1719.  

Page 27: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

27

Frost,  P.  G.,  &  Bond,  I.  (2008).  The  CAMPFIRE  programme  in  Zimbabwe:  Payments  for  wildlife  services.  Ecological  Economics  65  ,  pp.  776-­‐787.  

Gauvin,  C.,  Uchida,  E.,  Rozelle,  S.,  Xu,  J.,  &  Zhan,  J.  (2010).  Cost-­‐effectiveness  of  payments  for  ecosystem  services  with  dual  goals  of.  Environmental  Management  ,  pp.  488-­‐501.    

Hawkins,  S.,  Xuan  To,  P.,  Xuan  Phuong,  P.,  Thu  Thuy,  P.,  Duc  Tu,  N.,  Van  Cuong,  C.,  et  al.  (2010).  ROOTS  IN  THE  WATER:  Legal  Frameworks  for  Mangrove  PES  in  Vietnam,From  the  Katoomba  Group’s  Legal  Initiative  Country  Study  Series.  Washington  DC:  Forest  Trends.  

Hoang  Minh  Ha,  Meine  van  Noordwijk,  Pham  Thu  Thuy.  2008.  Payment  for  environmental  services:  experience  and  lessons  learned  in  Vietnam.  Hanoi,  Vietnam.  World  Agroforestry  Centre  (ICRAF).  33  p.  (Document  exists  in  both  English  and  Vietnamese)  

Huy  Dung,  N.,  &  Van  Dung,  V.  (2007).  Current  status  of  biodiversity  conservation  in  Vietnam  –  links  with  Sustainable  development  and  climate  change.  Hanoi:  Forest  Inventory  and  Planning  Institute  (FIPI).  

Huynh  Thi,  Mai  (2011).    Research  on  methodology  and  possible  application  of  PES  for  biodiversity  conservation  in  Vietnam.  Produced  for  Vietnams  Biodiversity  Conservation  Agency.    Đề  tài  “Nghiên  cứu  cơ  sở  lý  luận  và  thực  tiễn  đề  xuất  các  nội  dung  của  cơ  chế  chi  trả  dịch  vụ  môi  trường  liên  quan  đến  đa  dạng  sinh  học”  

Jindal,  Rohit  and  John  Kerr.  2007.    Payments  for  biodiversity  conservation.  USAID  PES  Brief  2.3.  October.  

Kosoy,  N.,  Corbera,  E.,  &  Brown,  K.  (2008).  Participation  in  payments  for  ecosystem  services:  Case  studies  from  the  Lacandon  rainforest,  Mexico.  Geoforum  39  ,  pp.  2073-­‐2083.  

Kosoy,  N.,  Martinez-­‐Tuna,  M.,  Muradian,  R.,  &  Martinez-­‐Alier,  J.  (2006).  Payments  for  environmental  services  in  watersheds:  Insights  from  a  comparative  study  of  three  cases  in  Central  America.  Ecological  Economics  ,  pp.  446-­‐455.  

Landell-­‐Mills,  N.,  Porras,  I.T.  (2002).  Silver  bullet  or  fools'  gold?  A  global  review  of  markets  for  forest  environmental  services  and  their  impact  on  the  poor.  Instruments  for  sustainable  private  sector  forestry  series.  IIED,  London.  

McElwee,  P.  D.  (2012).  Payments  for  environmental  services  as  neoliberal  market-­‐based  forest  conservation  in  Vietnam:  Panacea  or  problem?  Geoforum  43  ,  pp.  412-­‐426.  

McElwee,  P.  D.  (2010).  Resource  use  among  rural  agricultural  households  near  protected  areas  in  Vietnam:  the  social  costs  of  conservation  and  implications  for  enforcement.  Environmental  Management  45  ,  pp.  113-­‐131.  

(MONRE)  Ministry  of  Natural  Resources  and  the  Environment  Vietnam.  2010.  Removing  Barrier  Hindering  Protected  Area  Management  Effectiveness  in  Viet  Nam-­‐Project  

Page 28: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

28

Document.  UNDP  Project  document.  PIMS  3965:  ATLAS  VNM10  Award:  00059640  Project  :  00074659  

(MONRE)  Ministry  of  Natural  Resources  and  the  Environment  Vietnam.  2012.  Vietnam’s  National  Biodiversity  Strategy  and  Action  Plan  to  2020  (with  a  vision  to  2030).  Hanoi.  

Muñoz-­‐Piña,  C.,  Guevara,  A.,  Torres,  J.  M.,  &  Braña,  J.  (2008).  Paying  for  the  hydrological  services  of  Mexico's  forests:  Analysis,  negotiations  and  results.  Ecological  Economics  65  ,  pp.  725-­‐736.  

Nguyen  Thuy  Duong  et  al  (2011).  Rationale  research,  practice  and  proposed  mechanism  for  payment  for  ecosystem  services  in  the  wetland  environment.  Prepared  for  ISPONRE  Vietnam.  Hanoi.  December.    

Pagiola,  S.  (2008).  Payments  for  environmental  services  in  Costa  Rica.  Ecological  Economics  65  ,  pp.  712-­‐724.  

Petheram,  L.,  &  Campbell,  B.  M.  (2010).  Listening  to  locals  on  payments  for  environmental  services.  Journal  of  Environmental  Management  91  ,  1139-­‐1149.  

Pham,  T.T.,  P.,  Campbell,  B.  M.,  Garnett,  S.,  Aslin,  H.,  &  Hoang,  M.  H.  (2010).  Importance  and  impacts  of  intermediary  boundary  organizations  in  facilitating  payment  for  environmental  services  in  Vietnam.  Environmental  Conservation  37  ,  pp.  64-­‐72.  

Sommerville,  M.,  Jones,  J.  P.,  Rahajaharison,  M.,  &  Milner-­‐Gulland,  E.  (2010).  The  role  of  fairness  and  benefit  distribution  in  community-­‐based  Payment  for  Environmental  Services  interventions:  A  case  study  from  Menabe,  Madagascar.  Ecological  Economics  69  ,  pp.  1262-­‐1271.  

The  National  Assembly  of  the  Socialist  Republic  of  Vietnam.  (2008).  Biodiversity  Law,  No.  20/2008/QH12.  Vietnam.  

Turpie,  J.,  Marais,  C.,  &  Blignaut,  J.  (2008).  The  working  for  water  programme:  Evolution  of  a  payments  for  ecosystem  services  mechanism  that  addresses  both  poverty  and  ecosystem  service  delivery  in  South  Africa.  Ecological  Economics  65  ,  pp.  788-­‐798.  

Wendland,  K.,  Honzák,  M.,  Portela,  R.,  Vitale,  B.,  Rubinoff,  S.,  &  Randrianarisoa,  J.  (2010).  Targeting  and  implementing  payments  for  ecosystem  services:  Opportunities  for  bundling  biodiversity  conservation  with  carbon  and  water  services  in  Madagascar.  Ecological  Economics  69  ,  pp.  2093-­‐2107.  

Wertz-­‐Kanounnikoff.  2006.  Payments  for  environmental  services  –  –  a  solution  for  biodiversity  conservation?  Iddri  –  Idées  pour  le  débat  N°  12/2006.  

Wunder,  S.  (2005).  Payments  for  environmental  services:  Some  nuts  and  bolts.  Jakarta:  CIFOR  Center  for  International  Forestry  Research.  

Wunder,  S.,  &  Albán,  M.  (2008).  Decentralized  payments  for  environmental  services:  The  cases  of  Pimampiro  and  PROFAFOR  in  Ecuador.  Ecological  Economics  65  ,  pp.  685-­‐698.  

Page 29: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

29

Xuan  To,  P.,  Dressler,  W.  H.,  Mahanty,  S.,  Thuy  Pham,  T.,  &  Zingerli,  C.  (2012).  The  Prospects  for  Payment  for  Ecosystem  Services  (PES)  in  Vietnam:  A  Look  at  Three  Payment  Schemes.  Human  Ecology  40  ,  pp.  237-­‐249.  

Zabel,  A.,  Bostedt,  G.,  &  Stefanie,  E.  (2010).  Outcomes  and  Determinants  of  Success  of  a  Performance  Payment  Scheme  for  Carnivore  Conservation.  Umeå:  Centre  for  Environmental  and  Resource  Economics  CERE.  

 

 

 

 

 

   

Page 30: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

30

Appendix  A  –  Formal  summaries  of  16  PES  case  studies    

P E S i n t e r n a t i o n a l C a s e S t u d y s u m m a r y # 1 : A s q u i t h e t a l . ( 2 0 0 8 )

Asquith  et  al.  2008.Selling  two  environmental  services:  In-­‐kind  payments  for  bird  habitat  and  watershed  protection  in  Los  Negros,  Bolivia.    

Location,  type  of  PES,  time  frame,  funding,  etc.  • Los  Negros,  Bolivia.  Program  started  2003  and  no  end  date  is  decided.  Contracts  are  still  

running.  • Funded  by  the  NGO,  Fundacion  Natura  Bolivia.  US$  40  000  startup  and  US$  3000  

annually.    • Participation  is  voluntary.  Annual  contracts  prohibit  tree  cutting,  hunting  and  forest  

clearing  on  enrolled  lands.    

What  are  the  ecosystem  services  (ES)  addressed  and    • ES  from  forested  watershed.  Biodiversity  (mainly  bird  habitat)  and  stabile  water  flows.  

What  management  activity  or  restoration  is  possible  to  improve  the  flow  of  these  ES?  • Make  landowners  willing  to  preserve  and  protect  the  forests  in  the  area  by  paying  them  

to  not  exploit  it  or  convert  it  to  agricultural  land.  What  is  the  current  or  future  threat  to  these  ES?  • Tree  cutting,  hunting  and  illegal  land  encroachment.  Both  from  landowners  and  from  

migrants  from  the  Bolivian  highlands.  Landless  migrants/immigrants  clear  land  illegally  on  land  owned  by  other  farmers.  They  consider  land  not  delimited  by  barbed  wire  as  unused  and  available  for  colonization.  

K e y p o i n t s t e s t e d

(1)  what  good/service  is  actually  bought  and  sold  and  how  is  it  measured  (what  metric)?  • The  service  sold  is  “to  not  exploit  the  forest”.  It  is  measured  as  preserved  forest/  ha.    • The  service  bought  is  essentially  the  same.  (2)  Who  are  the  buyers  and  sellers  (providers)?  Are  there  non-­‐buying  beneficiaries  ?  • Buyer  1:  The  US  Fish  and  Wildlife  Service  are  paying  for  the  protection  of  habitat  for  

migratory  bird  species.    • Buyer  2:  The  actual  buyers  are  downstream  irrigators  but  they  are  only  paying  a  small  

share  (per  diem  and  food)  for  independent  monitors  of  the  conservation  area.  The  Municipality  of  Pampagrande  are  paying  the  main  part  for  conservation  of  the  same  upland  forest  vegetation  that  helps  maintain  dry-­‐season  water  supply.  The  project  aims  to  make  the  irrigators  pay  the  total  sum  for  the  service  in  the  future.  

• Sellers:  Forest  landowners  who  receive  in-­‐kind  payments  in  the  form  of  beehives,  apicultural  training  and  barbed  wire.  

• Non-­‐buying  beneficiaries:    Isn´t  really  discussed  in  the  article  but  the  downstream  irrigator’s  incentives  to  pay  may  have  been  decreased  since  there  are  two  buyers  for  the  

Page 31: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

31

same  service.  “Someone  is  already  paying  for  the  service”.  Free-­‐riding  is  a  weakness  of  dual-­‐service  scheme´s.  

(3)  How  long  is  the  contract/program  designed  for?  Time  frame  for  payment?  • The  contracts  signed  with  the  sellers  ranged  in  duration  from  1-­‐10  years  but  were  never  

longer  than  10  years.  This  is  to  minimize  pre-­‐existing  fears  of  land  appropriation.  The  payments  are  made  once  annually.    

(4)  How  was  the  price  addressed  or  determined?  • No  formal  economic  analysis  has  been  done.    Vargas  (2004)  carried  out  semi-­‐structured  

interviews  with  landowners  where  he  found  that  70%  of  downstream  landowners  had  a  non-­‐zero  WTP.    

• The  in-­‐kind  payments  were  decided  during  a  meeting  between  the  environmental  committees  of  Santa  Rosa  and  Los  Negros.  They  agreed  payments  of  1  beehive  for  every  10  ha  of  forest  protected  for  a  year.  It´s  equivalent  to  US$3/ha/year.  The  PES  recipients  specifically  rejected  the  option  of  payment  in  cash.  Some  landowners  have  been  paid  by  barbed  wire  instead  of  beehives.  

(5)  How  are  payments  structured?  Who  administers,  monitors  and  enforces  system?    • In-­‐kind  payments  are  made  annually.  A  “project  control  team”  including  one  member  

from  each  party  (buyers,  sellers,  the  NGO,  and  the  Municipality)  assesses  whether  the  parcel  has  been  effectively  conserved.  The  cost  for  this  “team”  is  shared  between  the  parties.  The  team  writes  a  report  to  a  board  (including  members  from  all  parties),  which  makes  final  recommendations  on  how  to  deal  with  any  infractions.  

R e s u l t s

Did  it  work?  • 46  farmers  are  currently  being  paid  to  protect  2774  ha  of  cloud-­‐forest  in  the  watershed  

area.  • Only  one  infraction  so  far.  A  landowner  constructed  a  road  through  a  part  of  his  

conservation  parcel.  Very  mild  penalty.  1  year  exclusion  from  the  program.  • Too  early  to  say  if  the  WTP  of  downstream  water  users  are  big  enough  to  cover  the  

upstream  opportunity  costs  of  land.  The  municipality  is  now  paying  the  main  part  of  this  service.  

• The  scheme  clearly  improves  the  income  for  most  upstream  participants  (sellers).  • How  their  livelihoods  have  been  affected  by  the  scheme  depends  on  how  skillful  the  

landowners  are  when  it  comes  to  handling  beehives.  L e s s o n s l e a r n e d

• Even though in-kind payments are preferred by most of the landowners, some of the landowners are asking for other kinds of payments. Other payment-methods have to be investigated.

• The dual-service approach may deteriorate the incentives but were necessary to get enough funding to get started.

• Landowners  may  only  protect  areas  that  weren´t  good  enough  to  use  for  something  else  (very  steep  or  remote  areas).  No  opportunity  cost  for  them.

Page 32: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

32

• Instead of starting the project with intensive data collection the project started with a “learning by doing” approach by piloting payments of US$1800 to earn local goodwill.

• More ecological knowledge is needed. Mainly about the relationship between the conservation of the forest and how this influence the water flow. This may increase the incentives for the irrigators to participate. Now they bear a big risk because they can´t be certain that they are paying for something that influence the flow.

 

P E S i n t e r n a t i o n a l C a s e S t u d y s u m m a r y # 2 : B a r s t a d e t a l ( 2 0 1 2 )

Barstad  et  al.  2012.  Parallel  Pilot  Initiatives  Providing  Incentives  for  Forest  Management  and  Conservation  on  Private  Lands.  Final  Report  for  Conservation  Innovation  Grant  NRCS-­‐69-­‐3A75-­‐9-­‐149.  December.  

Location,  type  of  PES,  time  frame,  funding,  etc.  • New  England,  USA  (Upper  Connecticut  Watershed  &  Crooked  River).  Short  pilot  project  

2010-­‐2011.  Summarizes  three  different  case  studies  in  one  report.  • Pilot  project  only  to  test  market-­‐based  approaches.  Funded  by  $500,000  Conservation  

Innovation  Grant  in  2009  granted  by  American  Forest  Foundation  What  are  the  ecosystem  services  (ES)  addressed    • ES  from  forested  watersheds:  clean  water,  recreation,  aesthetic  benefits,  fish  habitat,  

bird  habitat,  groundwater  re-­‐charge,  etc.  

What  management  activity  or  restoration  is  possible  to  improve  the  flow  of  these  ES?  • forested  buffers  around  streams  to  prevent  erosion  and  to  provide  shade/cover,  erosion  

control,  flood  management,  improve  access  for  recreation,  establish  protected  areas  • or  improved  water  treatment  practices  restoration…  What  is  the  current  or  future  threat  to  these  ES?  • development  pressures  leading  to  fragmentation  of  landscapes,    • pollution  from  aging  municipal  water  treatment  plants  /  overflow  during  storm  events;    • non-­‐point  source  water  pollution  from  land  management  activities;  • proposed  dam  construction;  • spread/invasion  of  noxious  species;  K e y p o i n t s t e s t e d

(1)  what  good/service  is  actually  bought  and  sold  and  how  is  it  measured  (what  metric)?  • Either  (1)  no.  of  trees  planted  (2)  no.  of  restoration  projects  completed  (3)  no.  of  acres  

of  habitat  conserved  or  habitat  buffers  restored  (4)  No.  of  recreational  access  points  protected.  Metrics  were  easy  to  measure  but  no  clear  measure  of  ES  level.  However,  one  effort  was  made  to  translate  no.  of  trees  into  pounds  of  carbon  sequestered.  

(2)  Who  are  the  buyers  and  sellers  (providers)?  Are  there  non-­‐buying  beneficiaries  ?  • Buyers:  free-­‐willing  individuals/NGOs  that  voluntarily  pay  for  ES  from  forested  

watersheds.    

Page 33: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

33

• Sellers:  Forest  landowners  who  received  payment  to  improve  management.  The  US  Forest  Service  sold  a  “nature  experience”  to  buyers  (e.g.,  come  help  us  monitor  fish  populations)    

• Beneficiaries:  Many  others  beneficiaries  that  didn’t  pay,  e.g.,  businesses,  river  users  etc.  Even  sellers  themselves  benefit    

(3)  How  long  is  the  contract/program  designed  for?  Time  frame  for  payment?  • 1  yr  project  pilot  only.  

(4)  How  was  the  price  addressed  or  determined?  • Cost  as  proxy  for  value;  no  attempt  to  value  ES  per  se.  e.g.,  cost  of  planting  a  tree  (which  

included  material,  labor  and  monitoring)  or  the  cost  of  proposed  restoration  project.    (5)  How  are  payments  structured?  Who  administers,  monitors  and  enforces  system?    • Willing  individuals/NGOs  go  on-­‐line  and  pay  for  a  tree  or  contribute  to  a  restoration  

project.    • Contracts  with  landowners  verified  tree  planting.  Monitoring  done  by  local  nonprofit  

partners.  Independent  verification  from  the  American  Carbon  Registry.  These  costs  were  paid  by  “buyers”  through  their  contribution  to  the  program  (included  in  cost  of  a  “tree”).  

R e s u l t s

Did  it  work?  

• Innovative  and  new  project  without  huge  success,  but  expectations  were  low.  • Voluntary  participation  made  it  difficult  to  generate  market  activity.  Lacked  regulatory  

driver  to  encourage  buyers  to  participate,  which  prevented  strong  incentives  for  sellers  to  change  behavior.  Social  media  was  used  to  promote  voluntary  purchases  

• Tree-­‐planting  activity  was  attractive  because  it  provides  multiple  ES  benefits.  Important  that  participants  understand  all  co-­‐benefits  and  their  value  because  tree  planting  is  expensive.    

• Forest  landowners  willing  to  plant  trees  if  given  financial  support.  Contacts  with  local  env  groups  facilitated  planting  activity  and  also  allowed  input  from  experts  to  prioritize  certain  areas  for  planting.  Existing  relationships  between  sellers  and  NGOs  are  key.  

• Difficult  to  encourage  all  beneficiaries  to  become  buyers  (free-­‐riders).  Must  convince  beneficiary  that  their  activity  depends  on  ES  and  costs  will  rise  in  future  in  absence  of  ES  

L e s s o n s l e a r n e d

• Need  an  environmental  threat  and  imminent  regulatory  pressure  to  create  critical  mass  -­‐-­‐  otherwise  voluntary  participation  is  difficult  to  motivate.  

• Need  significant  demand  –  were  too  many  individual  residential  users  instead  of  a  large  user  (e.g.,  water  utility,  brewery,  semi  conductor  manufacturer,  etc.).  

• Need  clear  links  between  (1)  human  activity  (tree  planting)  ßà  improvement  in  ES  (cleaner  water)  ß  à  (3)  subsequent  impact  on  human  welfare  (value  for  the  change)  

• Invest  in  the  right  places:  Use  existing  conservation  priorities  and  experts  • Market  to  buyers  à  Talk  with  potential  buyers  (utilities,  businesses  and  residents)  

about  perception  and  knowledge  of  ES,  threats  or  risks  they  see,  and  what  they  plan  to  

Page 34: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

34

do  about  them.  Inquire  about  willingness  to  pay  and  their  expected  returns  (financial  or  otherwise)    

• Market  to  sellers  à  Talk  with  sellers  about  their  opinions  on  length  of  commitment,  amount  of  payment,  activity/restoration  practice,  etc.  

• Look  for  existing  payment  infrastructure  instead  of  trying  to  build  it  new.  

P E S i n t e r n a t i o n a l C a s e S t u d y s u m m a r y # 3 : B a r t o n e t a l ( 2 0 0 9 )

Barton  et  al  2009.  Environmental  service  payments:  Evaluating  biodiversity  conservation  trade-­‐offs  and  cost-­‐efficiency  in  the  Osa  Conservation  Area,  Costa  Rica  

Location,  type  of  PES,  time  frame,  funding,  etc.  • Costa  Rica,  Osa  Conservation  Area  (ACOSA)  in  the  Brunca  region.  • Tax-­‐payer  funded  markets.  The  PES  program  in  Costa  Rica  (PSA)  is  funded  by  tax  

revenue  (3,  5%  of  the  fossil  fuel  tax)  and  by  donations  from  GEF/World  Bank  Ecomarkets  project  and  German  Kfw  support.  

• The  study  assesses  the  cost-­‐efficiency  of  PES  allocations  in  ACOSA  in  the  period  1999-­‐2003.  

• The  articles  focus  on  methodological  questions  where  the  algorithm  TARGET  is  the  main  focus.  

What  are  the  ecosystem  services  (ES)  addressed  and    • ES  from  forests  in  general.  Not  further  specified.  What  management  activity  or  restoration  is  possible  to  improve  the  flow  of  these  ES?  • Conservation  of  forests.  What  is  the  current  or  future  threat  to  these  ES?  • Mainly  conversion  to  agricultural  land  and  tree  cutting  K e y p o i n t s t e s t e d

(1)  what  good/service  is  actually  bought  and  sold  and  how  is  it  measured  (what  metric)?  • The  service  bought  is  no.  of  ha  of  forest  preserved.  • The  service  sold  is  to  preserve  the  forest.    (2)  Who  are  the  buyers  and  sellers  (providers)?  Are  there  non-­‐buying  beneficiaries  ?  • Buyers:  Government  through  FONAFIFO  (Costa  Rican  National  Forestry  Financing  

Fund).  Not  further  specified  in  the  paper  but  FONAFIFO  sometimes  acts  as  an  intermediary  between  private  buyers  and  seller.  

• Sellers:  Landowners  • Non-­‐buying  beneficiaries:  N/A  (3)  How  long  is  the  contract/program  designed  for?  Time  frame  for  payment?  • The  assessment  in  the  study  is  made  on  the  years  1999-­‐2003.  • Time  frame  for  payment  N/A.  

(4)  How  was  the  price  addressed  or  determined?  

Page 35: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

35

• Prices  in  the  program  are  approximately  based  on  national  averages  for  opportunity  costs  of  forgone  cattle  pasture  and  the  direct  financial  cost  of  the  different  forestry  activities  promoted.  Establishment  of  forest  plantations,  agro-­‐forestry  systems).  No  differentiated  incentives.  

(5)  How  are  payments  structured?  Who  administers,  monitors  and  enforces  system?    • No  information  about  how  payments  are  structured.  ACOSA  is  responsible  for  

coordinating  the  conservation  efforts  in  all  public  protected  land  in  the  area.  FONAFIFO  is  the  national  governmental  organization  responsible  for  administration  and  monitoring.    

R e s u l t s

Did  it  work?  • Target  was  found  to  be  a  flexible  and  rapid  way  of  evaluating  PES  allocation  scenarios,  

habitat  connectivity  versus  biodiversity  representation  and  opportunity  costs.  • In  the  ACOSA  area,  the  study  finds  that  the  PES  allocation  criteria  in  COSTA  RICA  for  

2002-­‐2003  are  more  than  twice  as  cost-­‐efficient  as  the  criteria  applied  during  1999-­‐2001,  in  terms  of  biodiversity  representation  and  opportunity  cost  to  agricultural  and  forestry  sectors.  

• The  GIS-­‐based  multiple  criteria  scoring  approach  considered  by  Costa  Rican  authorities  achieves  a  compromise  between  habitat  connectivity  and  biodiversity  representation  that  is  close  to  the  TARGET  solution  when  policy  makers  put  a  relatively  high  importance  of  opportunity  costs.  

L e s s o n s l e a r n e d

• Conservation  area  authorities  can  improve  cost-­‐efficiency  further  by  using  biodiversity  complementary  and  opportunity  cost  as  explicit  ranking  criteria  for  PES.

• Despite  lacking  survey  data,  a  GIS-­‐based  TARGET  approach  can  be  a  useful  tool  for  regional  level  assessments.

• The  advantages  of  an  approach  based  on  GIS  data  increases  with  the  size  of  the  area  and  the  number  of  biodiversity  attributes  considered.

• To  rank  individual  PES  applications,  survey  data  is  needed  to  correctly  specify  net  opportunity  costs  of  alternative  uses  of  land,  labor  and  capital  and  finer  scale  definitions  of  biodiversity  attributes.

 

P E S i n t e r n a t i o n a l C a s e S t u d y s u m m a r y # 4 : C l e m e n t s e t a l ( 2 0 1 0 )

Clements  et  al.  2010.  Payments  for  biodiversity  conservation  in  the  context  of  weak  institutions:  Comparison  of  three  programs  from  Cambodia    

Location,  type  of  PES,  time  frame,  funding,  etc.  • Cambodia,  Comparison  of  3  programs  (1.  Community-­‐based  ecotourism  2.  Agri-­‐

environmental  payments  3.  Direct  contracts  for  bird  nest  protection).  Program  1  started  2004,  Program  2  started  2007  and  program  3  started  2002.  

• The  programs  are  funded  by  the  NGO  “Wildlife  Conservation  Society”  (WCS).  Program  1  is  partly  funded  by  a  “village  fund”  (no  more  info  than  that)  Program  2  no  info  about  

Page 36: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

36

funding  and  Program  3  is  funded  by  US$25  000/year.  Program  1  and  2  aims  to  be  financial  sustainable.  No  information  of  initial  fund.  

• No  ending  date  decided.    

What  are  the  ecosystem  services  (ES)  addressed  and    • Program  1  and  2:    ES  from  forests,  focusing  on  habitat  for  endangered  species.  • Program  3:  Protecting  bird  nests,  not  entire  habitats.    

What  management  activity  or  restoration  is  possible  to  improve  the  flow  of  these  ES?  • Program  1  and  2:  Pay  villagers  for  stop  hunting  endangered  species  and  abiding  by  a  

land-­‐use  plan.    • Program  3:  Protect  bird  nests  from  egg  collectors  by  hiring  local  protectors.  

What  is  the  current  or  future  threat  to  these  ES?  • Hunting,  habitat  destruction,  human  disturbance.  K e y p o i n t s t e s t e d

(1)  what  good/service  is  actually  bought  and  sold  and  how  is  it  measured  (what  metric)?  • Program  1:  The  service  sold  is  that  local  villagers  will  stop  hunting  endangered  species  

and  that  they  abide  the  land-­‐use  plan.  No  information  about  how  the  service  is  measured.  

• The  service  bought  is  that  the  area  will  be  preserved.  • Program  2:  The  service  sold  is  that  farmers  keep  to  the  land-­‐use  plan  and  no-­‐hunting  

rules.  They  are  then  allowed  to  sell  rice  through  a  village  committee.  They  get  preferential  prices  by  bypassing  middlemen  and  selling  to  hotels  under  the  “Wildlife-­‐Friendly”  certification  system.  

• The  service  bought  is  “ecological”  or  “good”  rice.    • The  services  sold  in  both  cases  are  measured  by  ensuring  that  the  sellers  are  abiding  the  

rules.  • Program  3:  The  service  sold  is  to  protect  nests.  It  is  measured  by  looking  if  the  chicks  

successfully  fledge.  • The  service  bought  is  the  protection  of  nests  and  as  a  result  preserved  species.  

   (2)  Who  are  the  buyers  and  sellers  (providers)?  Are  there  non-­‐buying  beneficiaries  ?  • Program  1:  The  sellers  are  local  villagers.  • The  buyers  are  tourists  (mainly  birdwatchers)  who  pay  fees  to  visit  the  area.    They  pay  

for  one  days  visit.  • Program  2:  The  sellers  are  local  farmers  • The  buyers  are  tourist  hotels  and  a  marketing  association.  • Program  3:  The  sellers  are  local  villagers.  • The  buyers  are  WCS  who  are  paying  for  the  reporting  of  nest  and  protection  of  nests.  • No  information  of  non-­‐buying  beneficiaries.  (3)  How  long  is  the  contract/program  designed  for?  Time  frame  for  payment?  • Program  1:  No  specific  time  frame.  Payments  when  they  sell.  

Page 37: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

37

• Program  2:  No  specific  time  frame.  Payments  when  they  sell.  • Program  3:  No  specific  time  frame.  Payments  daily.  

(4)  How  was  the  price  addressed  or  determined?  • Program  1:  Entrance  fees  of  US$  30  per  person  if  they  see  all  key  species.  Otherwise  

US$  15.  No  info  about  how  the  price  was  determined.    • Program  2:  The  price  offered  was  initially  200%  of  the  price  offered  by  the  old  buyer  

(middlemen).  The  middlemen  later  raised  their  price  but  the  price  offered  by  the  program  was  still  higher  (55-­‐65%).  The  payment  value  was  set  based  on  the  market  premium  available  for  the  products.  Not  opportunity  costs.  

• Program  3:  Only  information  is  that  the  value  is  determined  by  WCS  and  that  it  costs  US$  25  000  yearly.  No  recognition  of  the  birds’  value  has  been  done.    

(5)  How  are  payments  structured?  Who  administers,  monitors  and  enforces  system?    • Program  1:    WCS  monitors  and  supports  elected  village  committees,  governmental  

authorities  and  the  private  tourist  sector.  All  these  are  involved  in  the  process.  The  village  committees  are  the  ones  who  are  in  charge  at  the  site  and  are  responsible  of  management  of  income  and  local  enforcement  of  the  land-­‐use  plan.  

• Program  2:  Payments  are  made  after  the  village  committee  has  monitored  the  farmers.  External  verification  by  the  marketing  association.  

• Program  3:  Monitored  and  administered  by  WCS  directly.  R e s u l t s

Did  it  work?  • Program  1  and  2  became  institutionally  effective  after  a  few  years  of  operation.  They  are  

more  long-­‐term  and  indirect  than  program  3.  • Program  3  provided  very  rapid  protection  for  many  species  that  were  at  risk  of  local  

extinction.    • A  substantial  increase  in  species  populations  are  observed  for  both  the  bird  nest  and  

ecotourism  program  which  is  very  promising  given  the  context  of  the  general  ongoing  in  species  abundance  in  Cambodia.  

• A  full-­‐scale  evaluation  of  the  programs  requires  a  counterfactual  comparison  once  they  have  been  in  operation  for  several  years.  

 L e s s o n s l e a r n e d

• Under  conditions  of  high  uncertainty  over  threats  and  potential  impacts  of  interventions,  less  specific  payment  programs  that  reward  a  set  of  outcomes  may  be  more  effective  than  a  tightly  targeted  program.

• Program  1  and  2  with  an  increased  institutional  diversity  had  a  more  sustainable  outcome  at  the  cost  of  reducing  the  payments  that  were  made  to  local  people,  because  revenue  was  also  required  to  fund  the  other  organizations  for  monitoring,  enforcement  and  supporting  roles.

• Direct  payments  to  some  individuals  may  fail  to  generate  support  for  conversation.   • Payment  programs  that  are  structured  to  facilitate  intrinsic  motivations  are  more  likely  

to  be  successful.  

Page 38: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

38

 

P E S i n t e r n a t i o n a l C a s e S t u d y s u m m a r y # 5 : ( C o s t a 2 0 1 1 )

Máñez  Costa,  M.,  2011.  A  participatory  framework  for  conservation  payments.  Land  Use  Policy  28:  423-­‐433.  

Location,  type  of  PES,  time  frame,  funding,  etc.  • A  watershed  in  a  mountain  area  in  Guatemala  (Alta  Verapaz).  • NOTE:  The  study  is  a  simulation  of  potential  impacts  of  a  PES  system.  What  are  the  ecosystem  services  (ES)  addressed  and    • Habitat  for  migrant  species,  biodiversity,  freshwater  supply.  What  management  activity  or  restoration  is  possible  to  improve  the  flow  of  these  ES?  • Re-­‐vegetation  and  soil  conservation  is  needed  to  protect  from  rainfall-­‐erosion.    What  is  the  current  or  future  threat  to  these  ES?  • Erosion  leads  to  damaged  habitats  and  bad  water  quality  in  the  nearby  river  basin  

(which  is  used  as  a  water  reservoir).  K e y p o i n t s t e s t e d

(1)  what  good/service  is  actually  bought  and  sold  and  how  is  it  measured  (what  metric)?  • For  example:  Area  of  eco-­‐farming  (without  further  definition),  natural  forest  

preservation,  living  fences,  living  barriers.  (2)  Who  are  the  buyers  and  sellers  (providers)?  Are  there  non-­‐buying  beneficiaries  ?  • Buyer:  Not  specified  • Seller:  Farmers  • Beneficiaries:  Public  (3)  How  long  is  the  contract/program  designed  for?  Time  frame  for  payment?  • Up  to  ten  years  was  simulated.  (4)  How  was  the  price  addressed  or  determined?  • It  was  varied  to  simulate  market  response  to  varying  prices.  (5)  How  are  payments  structured?  Who  administers,  monitors  and  enforces  system?    • N/A  R e s u l t s

Did  it  work?  • Conservation  payments  may  be  suitable  for  reducing  poverty  and  improving  the  

management  of  ES.  • Participatory  frameworks  are  useful  when  designing  a  PES  system.  L e s s o n s l e a r n e d

Page 39: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

39

• Local  input  is  needed  when  designing  payment  schemes  that  are  supposed  to  compensate  land  managers  for  promoting  “good”  environmental  management.  Just  economic  knowledge  on  opportunity  costs  is  not  sufficient  for  predicting  participation  in  the  market.

• Farmers  would  be  willing  to  bid  a  higher  or  lower  amount  of  land  units  for  conservation  depending  on  the  price  that  is  offered  but  mainly  depending  on  the  characteristics  of  their  farming  system.  I.e.:  the  heterogeneity  of  farming  systems  is  perhaps  more  important  than  price.  Different  farmers  will  respond  in  different  ways  to  any  given  price.

• Risk  is  an  important  factor.  For  some  farmers,  PES  is  seen  as  a  more  constant  flow  of  incomes  than  income  from  other  sources,  thus  participating  in  the  PES  market  may  be  an  attractive  option.

 

P E S i n t e r n a t i o n a l C a s e S t u d y s u m m a r y # 6 : D o b b s a n d P r e t t y ( 2 0 0 8 )

Dobbs  and  Pretty  2008.  Case  study  of  agri-­‐environmental  payments:  The  United  Kingdom  

Location,  type  of  PES,  time  frame,  funding,  etc.  • The  United  Kingdom.  Evaluation  of  two  agri-­‐environmental  payments  programs.  • ESA  (The  Environmentally  Sensitive  Areas  program)  started  1986.  In  2003  the  

payments  were  UK£53  million.  • CSS  (Countryside  Stewardship  Scheme)  started  1991.  In  2003  the  payments  were  

UK£52  million.  • Funds  came  from  the  EU  and  the  UK  government.  About  half  from  each.  • Voluntary  incentive-­‐based  scheme.  What  are  the  ecosystem  services  (ES)  addressed  and    • Improved  habitat  for  birds,  biodiversity,  landscape  beauty,  historic  preservation,  restore  

neglected  land  or  features  and  create  new  habitats.  

What  management  activity  or  restoration  is  possible  to  improve  the  flow  of  these  ES?  • Reversion  of  cropland  to  grassland,  management  of  meadows,  managing  moorland.  

What  is  the  current  or  future  threat  to  these  ES?  • Conversion  of  unexploited  land  to  cropland.  K e y p o i n t s t e s t e d

(1)  what  good/service  is  actually  bought  and  sold  and  how  is  it  measured  (what  metric)?  • Service  bought  is  a  broad  range  of  environmental  restoration  and  preservation  projects.  

No  metric  specified.  • Service  sold  is  the  provision  of  landscapes  and  to  carry  out  different  management  

practices.  No  metric  specified.  

(2)  Who  are  the  buyers  and  sellers  (providers)?  Are  there  non-­‐buying  beneficiaries  ?  • Buyers:  The  UK  government  through  the  ESA  program.  • Sellers:  Farmers  and  other  land  managers.  

Page 40: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

40

(3)  How  long  is  the  contract/program  designed  for?  Time  frame  for  payment?  • Ten  year  voluntary  contract  with  annual  payments.  (4)  How  was  the  price  addressed  or  determined?  • Rates  are  based  on  capital  costs  and  incomes  forgone  and  can  be  adjusted  to  accomplish  

scheme  objectives.  Incomes  forgone  for  various  practices  are  established  on  a  “typical”  farm  for  a  wide  geographic  area.  Within  each  area  the  payments  are  tiered.    Individual  contract  payments  reflect  the  particular  capital  structures  and  management  practices  agreed  to  in  each  contract.  

(5)  How  are  payments  structured?  Who  administers,  monitors  and  enforces  system?    • A  government  agency  monitors  and  can  terminate  contracts  in  the  cases  of  non-­‐

compliance  and  also  demand  recovery  of  all  money  previously  paid.    • No  info  about  how  payments  are  structured.  R e s u l t s

Did  it  work?  • Incentives  offered  have  induced  enrollment  of  substantial  portions  (40-­‐90%)  of  eligible  

areas  in  England  ESAs  characterized  by  grazing  and  generally  less  intensive  agriculture,  but  enrollment  has  been  lower  in  areas  characterized  by  more  intensive  arable  production.  

• Most  of  the  UK  ESA  schemes  made  positive  contributions  to  “greening  the  edges”.    • ESAs  are  seen  to  be  most  successful  in  maintaining  the  environmental  capital  that  

already  exists  than  to  adding  or  enhancing  that  capital.  • Public  administrative  costs  for  the  ESA  scheme  were  18%  of  the  total  costs  for  the  

scheme.  • There  are  uncertainties  if  the  farmers  will  continue  the  preservation  after  the  contracts  

expire  but  in  a  study  slightly  more  than  half  of  the  participating  farmers  thought  they  would  continue  to  farm  in  the  same  way  as  during  the  contract  period.  

• The  larger  farmers  got  more  incomes  from  the  ESA  scheme  than  smaller  farmers.  • The  CSS  scheme  appeared  to  have  had  limited  impacts  on  arable  farming  practices.    • Two  thirds  of  the  participants  in  the  CSS  scheme  said  they  would  definitely  re-­‐apply  

when  their  current  contract  expires  meaning  the  payment  levels  were  adequate  for  these  farmers.  

L e s s o n s l e a r n e d

• The  scheme  had  problems  to  deal  with  whole  watersheds  because  this  needs  cooperation  and  participation  of  many  farmers  with  different  orientations  and  incomes.

• The  scheme  had  also  problems  to  attract  farmers  in  more  productive  arable  areas. • The  CAP  (The  European  Union’s  Common  Agricultural  Policy)  protects  farmers  too  well  

to  find  it  economically  attractive  to  make  the  major  farming  system  changes  that  would  be  called  for  to  participate  in  the  payment  schemes.

• To  attractive  these  farmers  it  would  probably  need  such  high  payment  rates  that  they  would  be  deemed  politically  unacceptable.

 

Page 41: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

41

P E S i n t e r n a t i o n a l C a s e S t u d y s u m m a r y # 7 : F r o s t a n d B o n d ( 2 0 0 8 )

Frost  and  Bond  2008.  The  CAMPFIRE  program  in  Zimbabwe:  Payments  for  wildlife  services  

Location,  type  of  PES,  time  frame,  funding,  etc.  • Zimbabwe,  Program  Campfire  (Communal  Areas  Management  Program  for  Indigenous  

Resources).    • Started  1989  and  continues  to  operate  today.  • Community  based  PES,  but  the  article  discuss  if  the  program  really  is  a  PES.  Depends  on  

definition  of  PES.  “Campfire  was  never  conceived  of  as  a  PES  program  though  it  exhibits  many  PES-­‐like  features”.  ß  INTERESTING  TO  NOTE  IN  OUR  SUMMARY  

• Main  funder  is  USAID  (United  States  Agency  for  International  Development).  USAID  spent  around  US$  25.2  million  during  1989-­‐2003.  This  was  not  only  for  the  program  but  also  for  natural  resource  management  in  general.  No  specific  amount  of  funding  for  the  program  is  available.  All  funding  are  for  start-­‐up  costs.  

What  are  the  ecosystem  services  (ES)  addressed  and    • ES  addressed  is  landscape  beauty  (aesthetic  views)  and  wildlife  habitat.  Mainly  for  safari  

hunting.  What  management  activity  or  restoration  is  possible  to  improve  the  flow  of  these  ES?  • To  not  damage  or  exploit  the  area  and  to  restrict  hunting.  What  is  the  current  or  future  threat  to  these  ES?  • Main  threats  are  transformation  of  habitats  to  agricultural  land  and  that  farmers  

considered  wild  animals  as  pests  and  were  therefore  hunting  them.  K e y p o i n t s t e s t e d

(1)  what  good/service  is  actually  bought  and  sold  and  how  is  it  measured  (what  metric)?  • The  service  sold  is:  that  the  citizens  of  the  communities’  won´t  hunt  or  harass  wildlife,  to  

limit  expansion  of  crops  and  livestock  and  confine  settlement  to  agreed  zones.    • The  service  bought  is  the  right  to  access  the  area  and  to  do  safari  trips  in  this  preserved  

area.  SO  IT  IS  MANDATORY  RIGHT  ?  

(2)  Who  are  the  buyers  and  sellers  (providers)?  Are  there  non-­‐buying  beneficiaries  ?  • Buyers:  Safari  operators  that  buy  rights  for  eco-­‐tourism  and  safari  hunting.  • Sellers:  Farming  communities  whose  land-­‐use  determines  the  fate  of  wildlife.  • Non-­‐buying  beneficiaries:  N/A  

(3)  How  long  is  the  contract/program  designed  for?  Time  frame  for  payment?  • Program  started  1989  and  can  potentially  continue  indefinitely.  In  most  of  the  cases  the  

safari  operators  pay  an  annual  lease  fee  for  the  concession  plus  a  trophy  fee  for  each  animal  shot  from  an  annual  quota.  In  other  cases  the  safari  operators  pay  a  percentage  of  gross  income.  

(4)  How  was  the  price  addressed  or  determined?  • Safari  operators  buy  the  rights  through  tender  offers.    SO  IT  IS  BASED  ON  COMPETITIVE  

Page 42: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

42

BIDS?  INTERESTING  …  

(5)  How  are  payments  structured?  Who  administers,  monitors  and  enforces  system?    • A  RDC  (Rural  District  Councils)  administers  the  program.  Authorized  by  the  government  

as  intermediaries.  Under  them  there  is  a  “ward”  (sub-­‐district  administrate  unit  with  six  villages)  that  receives  50%  of  the  revenues  that  in  turn  decides  if  they  are  going  to  pay  individual  families  or  invest  in  agreed  community  development  projects.  

• The  monitoring  hasn´t  been  extensive.  RDC  relied  on  the  safari  operators  to  make  proper  payments.  Most  agreements  have  held  so  far.  

• No  information  about  monitoring  the  service  sold.  R e s u l t s

Did  it  work?  • There  has  been  no  extensive  assessment  about  the  effects  on  conservation  of  wildlife  

and  wildlife  habitat.  The  indicators  looked  at  is  population  rates  of  some  species  compared  to  other  areas.    

• The  population  of  species  in  the  concerned  areas  has  been  stabile  while  there  in  other  parts  of  Zimbabwe  has  been  a  decline  in  population  rates.  

• A  substantial  amount  of  prime  wildlife  habitat  has  been  converted  to  settlement  and  agricultural  lands  in  parts  not  involved  in  the  project.  

• The  direct  financial  impact  on  poverty  has  been  marginal.  KEY  RELEVANT  CONCLUSION  FOR  US  

• The  amount  paid  to  individual  families  has  been  small  and  therefore  most  of  the  money  has  been  kept  at  ward-­‐level  to  make  “bigger”  development  investments.  

• The  project  has  grown  rapidly  since  the  start  and  are  now  supporting  some  777  000  households.  WOW  VERY  BIG  COMPARED  TO  OUR  PROJECT  FOCUSING  ON  20  HOUSEHOLDS  

L e s s o n s l e a r n e d

• Community-­‐level  commercial  transactions  can  seldom  be  pursued  in  isolation. • Non-­‐differentiated  payments  weaken  incentives.  An  advantage  with  the  non-­‐

differentiated  approach  is  that  it  minimizes  the  risk  for  envy  and  internal  division.  GOOD  POINT  

• Start-up costs are high and may need to be underwritten. To meet the cost of creating a supportive environment for PES solely from payments runs the risk of raising costs to buyers to unaffordable levels. KEY FOR OUR SUMMARY

• Competitive bidding allows producers to hold on to rents. Creating a more competitive buyer environment in which providers have greater bargaining power is a significant challenge to emerging PES schemes.

• Schemes must be flexible and adaptive. To not insist on rigid adherence to some preconceived plan can make it work better.

• A decentralized management can strengthen the feeling of ownership and increase the providers’ incentives.

 

Page 43: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

43

P E S i n t e r n a t i o n a l C a s e S t u d y s u m m a r y # 8 : K o s o y e t a l ( 2 0 0 6 )

Kosoy  et  al  2008.  Payments  for  environmental  services  in  watersheds:  Insights  from  a  comparative  study  of  three  cases  in  Central  America  

Location,  type  of  PES,  time  frame,  funding,  etc.  • Three  case  studies.  Location:  Jesus  de  Otoro  (Honduras),  San  Pedro  del  Norte  

(Nicaragua),  Heredia  (Costa  Rica).  Fieldwork  was  carried  out  July  to  December  2004.  • The  Jesus  de  Otoro  program  started  2001,  Funded  by  Swiss  international  cooperation  

(no  more  info)  US$30  000  for  design  and  setup.  • Heredia  started  2002.  No  info  about  funder.  Total  fund  US$  32  000  for  design  and  setup.    • San  Pedro  del  Norte  started  in  2003.  Seed  fund  provided  by  the  Program  for  Sustainable  

Agriculture  in  Hillsides  of  Central  America  (PASOLAC).  Total  fund  US$10  000  for  initial  setup.  

What  are  the  ecosystem  services  (ES)  addressed  and    • ES  from  forests  in  all  three  case  studies.  Mainly  water  related  ES.  What  management  activity  or  restoration  is  possible  to  improve  the  flow  of  these  ES?  • Jesus  de  Otoro:  No  burning  before,  during  or  after  planting.  Planting  of  vegetal  fences,  

irrigation  ditches  and  terraces.  Establishment  of  agroforestry  systems.  Production  of  organic  fertilizers.  Implementation  of  organic  agriculture.  Forest  protection  and  reforestation.  

• Heredia:  Prevention  and  control  of  forest  fires.  No  hunting  or  extraction  of  forest  products.  No  extraction  of  wood  products.  No  forest  conversion  to  agriculture  or  cattle  ranching.  Reforestation.  

• San  Pedro  del  Norte:  Manage  and  conserve  the  forested  areas.  Prevention  and  control  of  forest  fires.  Restricted  timber  extraction.  Implementation  of  a  management  plan.  Livestock  raising  is  not  allowed.  Subsistence  crop  farming  is  allowed  only  in  one  hectare  per  provider,  without  the  use  of  pesticides  and  agro-­‐chemicals.  

What  is  the  current  or  future  threat  to  these  ES?  • Not  specified  but  can  be  deduced  from  above.  K e y p o i n t s t e s t e d

(1)  what  good/service  is  actually  bought  and  sold  and  how  is  it  measured  (what  metric)?  • Households  pay  for  water  (mᶟ  or  just  a  fixed  amount  every  month)  and  the  intermediary  

pay  providers  for  abiding  the  criteria  mentioned  above.  • The  service  sold  is  that  the  land  owners  will  fulfill  that  agreement.  

 (2)  Who  are  the  buyers  and  sellers  (providers)?  Are  there  non-­‐buying  beneficiaries  ?  • Buyers:  Jesus  de  Otoro:    1269  water  using  households.  Heredia:  48,667  water  using  

households  and  one  private  beverage  company  (Florida  Ice  and  Farm  Co)  San  Pedro  del  Norte:  125  water  using  households.  

• Sellers:  Landowners  in  all  three  cases.  • Non-­‐buying  beneficiaries:  N/A  

Page 44: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

44

(3)  How  long  is  the  contract/program  designed  for?  Time  frame  for  payment?  • No  info  about  length  of  the  program.    Payments  are  either  made  monthly  as  a  fixed  fee  

or  as  a  pay  as  you  go  fee  for  every  mᶟ  you  buy  which  is  added  to  your  water  bill.  

(4)  How  was  the  price  addressed  or  determined?  • Jesus  de  Otoro:  The  fee  was  decided  through  voting  of  representatives  from  the  different  

water  sectors  in  town.  • Heredia:  The  fee  charged  to  users  was  decided  on  political  grounds.  • San  Pedro  del  Norte:  The  fee  was  decided  through  a  participatory  process  in  the  Water  

Committee,  which  includes  representatives  from  different  water  sectors  in  the  area.  

(5)  How  are  payments  structured?  Who  administers,  monitors  and  enforces  system?    • Households  pay  for  water  (mᶟ  or  just  a  fixed  amount  every  month)  and  the  intermediary  

(  pay  providers  for  abiding  the  criteria  mentioned  above.  • Jesus  de  Otoro:  Intermediary:  The  local  Council  for  Administration  of  Water  and  

Sewage  Disposal(JAPOE)  • Heredia:  Intermediary:  ESPH  S.A  a  public  local  enterprise  for  water  provision  and  

sanitation.  • San  Pedro  del  Norte:  Intermediary:  The  Water  Committee  (a  local  committee  who  was  

created  as  a  response  to  an  earlier  inefficient  public  enterprise.  • No  information  about  monitoring  or  enforcing.  R e s u l t s

Did  it  work?  • No  evaluations  of  the  change  in  ES  are  made  in  the  article.  • The  amount  received  from  the  PES  scheme  constitutes  less  than  2  %  of  gross  annual  

income  for  most  providers,  in  the  three  cases.    • Most  providers  do  not  think  that  the  amount  they  receive  is  fair.  • Opportunity  costs  were  larger  than  the  actual  or  potential  payment  (the  article  is  also  

measuring  different  opportunity  costs  and  compare  them  with  the  payments).    • The  degree  of  compensation  is  negative  since  the  opportunity  costs  were  higher  than  

the  actual  payment.  L e s s o n s l e a r n e d

• Why do providers participate when compensations are negative? • If rational actors, the negative result is a methodological artifact. • If actors are assumed to be agents with “bounded rationality” the providers may have seen the

payment as a support for activities that they would have done even if the payments were absent. The payment can in either way play a significant role in reinforcing good environmental stewardship.

• There are doubts about the cost effectiveness of the payments in relation to alternative tools because of the fact that landholders that already were committed to forest conservation are more likely to participate in the program than landholders prone to deforestation and urbanization. This may have to do with attitudes towards the environment.

• Intangibles may play a very critical role in the design and performance of PES schemes.

Page 45: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

45

• The relationship between land uses and hydrological dynamics is probably the most critical technical challenge of water-related PES schemes.

• Due to the uncertainty of the relationship between expanded forest cover and increased groundwater flow and, PES schemes that aims to increase water availability by these actions should be avoided.

• PES schemes are more likely to be effective when they tackle water quality problems since there are less technical uncertainty and less divergence between public expectations and scientific evidence on the relationship between land use and water quality.

• In the cases analyzed in the article the effects on upstream income is small, and in one of the cases the PES go to wealthy providers.

• Calculation of upstream opportunity cost of forest cover based on on-farm profits in general overestimates actual willingness to accept compensation among providers.

 

 

P E S i n t e r n a t i o n a l C a s e S t u d y s u m m a r y # 9 : K o s o y e t a l ( 2 0 0 8 )

Kosoy  et  al  2008  Participation  in  payments  for  ecosystem  services:  Case  studies  from  the  Lacandon  rainforest,  Mexico.  

Location,  type  of  PES,  time  frame,  funding,  etc.  • Mexico,  four  case  studies  looks  at  communities  that  implemented  the  program    and  

compared  them  with  four  that  didn´t.  Aims  to  answer  :  What  decides  if  Ejidos´  (territory  held  in  common  by  a  group  of  families)  decide  to  join  or  reject  a  PES  initiative?  

• Community  based  PES.  A  program  called  (PSA-­‐CABSA).  The  budget  for  PSA-­‐CABSA  is  negotiated  in  Congress  every  year.  

• Started  2004  and  is  still  running.  • Government  funds  but  no  info  about  total  sum.    

What  are  the  ecosystem  services  (ES)  addressed  and    • Biodiversity  and  carbon  fixation.  

What  management  activity  or  restoration  is  possible  to  improve  the  flow  of  these  ES?  • Conservation  of  local  natural  resources.  • Establish  a  private  reserve  for  protection  of  birds.  • Reforest  24  %  of  degraded  pasture  lands.  • Protect  the  forest  commons.    

What  is  the  current  or  future  threat  to  these  ES?  • Land  conversion    K e y p o i n t s t e s t e d

Page 46: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

46

(1)  what  good/service  is  actually  bought  and  sold  and  how  is  it  measured  (what  metric)?  • Case  study  1.  Service  sold  is  conservation  of  local  natural  resources  by  establishing  an  

eco-­‐tourism  site  for  bird  watching.  • Case  study  2.  Service  sold  is  to  establish  a  private  reserve  for  the  protection  of  birds.  • Case  study  3.  Preservation  of  1450  ha  of  fragmented  common  forests.    • Case  study  4.  Protection  of  the  forest  commons.  S  

(2)  Who  are  the  buyers  and  sellers  (providers)?  Are  there  non-­‐buying  beneficiaries  ?  • Buyers:  The  government  through  the  program  PSA-­‐CABSA.  • Sellers:  Ejidos  (territory  held  in  common  by  a  group  of  families)  • Non-­‐buying  beneficiaries:  N/A  

(3)  How  long  is  the  contract/program  designed  for?  Time  frame  for  payment?  • Case  study  1:  The  Ejido  will  receive  500,000  Mx$  over  5  years.  

(27,000Mx$/household/year)  • Case  study  2:  The  Ejido  will  receive  325,000Mx$  over  5  

year.(15,500Mx$/household/year)  • Case  study  3:  The  Ejido  will  receive  600,000  Mx$  /year  over  5  years.  (10,500  

Mx$/household/year.  • Cas  study  4:  Annual  transfers  to  the  Ejido  of  618,000  Mx$  over  a  5  year  period.  

(4)  How  was  the  price  addressed  or  determined?  • Set  by  the  PSA-­‐CABSA  or  the  government.  Not  further  specified.    

(5)  How  are  payments  structured?  Who  administers  monitors  and  enforces  system?    • CONAFOR  (Mexico´s  National  Forestry  Commission),  which  is  below  PSA-­‐CABSA,  sets,  

monitors  and  enforces  the  contractual  agreements  through  a  number  of  verifiers  who  are  hired  to  evaluate  project  development  on-­‐site.  CONAFOR  work  as  an  intermediary,  funding  project  design  and  implementation.  

• If  Ejidos  fail  to  comply  with  project  activities  CONAFOR  cancel  payments.  R e s u l t s

Did  it  work?  • There  have  been  problems  with  communication  between  CONAFOR  officials  and  the  

participants,  which  has  resulted  in  many  applications  being  turned  down  due  to  not  meeting  eligibility  criteria.  

• A  significant  factor  explaining  some  Ejidos  unwillingness  to  participate  in  PES  relates  to  the  inability  to  self-­‐organize  and  develop  project  applications.  

• Ejidos  with  rules  about  forest  conservation  already  in  place  had  a  higher  tendency  to  participate  than  Ejidos  without  rules.  Existing  infrastructure  helps  to  determine  success  of  program…interesting,  good  to  note.  

• PES  may  support  the  permanence  of  future  generations  in  rural  areas  by  strengthening  alternative  employment  sources.  

• Many Ejidos emphasized bequest values as important for their decisions.    

Page 47: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

47

L e s s o n s l e a r n e d

• The  relationship  between  Ejido  leaders  and  CONAFOR  verifiers  had  to  be  strengthened  in  order  to  avoid  jeopardizing  their  long-­‐term  commitment  to  the  project.  

• The information provided to the Ejido leaders has been critical to encourage participation. The eligibility criterion has to be well explained to the providers.

• The size of the Ejidos may be an important factor promoting participation. Small Ejidos seemed more prone to get involved than larger ones.

• It is important to look beyond the idea of “incentives” to move towards “motivations”. • Involvement in PES may not always be a matter of compensating for opportunity costs, but

rather a question of how non-monetary individual and collective motivations can be further strengthened.

 

P E S i n t e r n a t i o n a l C a s e S t u d y s u m m a r y # 1 0 : M u ñ o z e t a l ( 2 0 0 8 )

Muñoz  et  al.  2008.  Paying  for  the  hydrological  services  of  Mexico's  forests:  Analysis,  negotiations  and  results  

Location,  type  of  PES,  time  frame,  funding,  etc.  • Mexico,  2003-­‐2005.  The  Payment  for  Hydrological  Environmental  Services  (PSAH)  

Program.  • Government  acts  as  single  buyer  on  behalf  of  water  users.  • US$26  million  yearly.  Funded  through  an  earmarked  portion  of  federal  fiscal  revenues  

from  water  fees.  What  are  the  ecosystem  services  (ES)  addressed  and    • ES  from  forests  with  focus  on  water  services.  What  management  activity  or  restoration  is  possible  to  improve  the  flow  of  these  ES?  • Preservation  of  forests.  What  is  the  current  or  future  threat  to  these  ES?  • Conversion  of  forests  to  agriculture  and  cattle  ranching.  K e y p o i n t s t e s t e d

(1)  what  good/service  is  actually  bought  and  sold  and  how  is  it  measured  (what  metric)?  • Water  users  buy  water,  and  pay  a  specific  fee  to  the  government  who  in  turn  pays  the  

providers.  • The  service  sold  is  that  the  providers  will  preserve  the  forest  they  own.  It  is  measured  in  

preserved  forest/ha.  (2)  Who  are  the  buyers  and  sellers  (providers)?  Are  there  non-­‐buying  beneficiaries  ?  • Buyer:  Water  users  through  the  government.  • Sellers:  Landowners  with  primary  forest  cover  (forests  in  good  state  of  conservation)  • Non-­‐buying  beneficiaries:  N/A  

Page 48: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

48

(3)  How  long  is  the  contract/program  designed  for?  Time  frame  for  payment?  • Providers’  signs  up  for  5  years.  The  payments  were  made  annually.  (4)  How  was  the  price  addressed  or  determined?  • The  price  was  based  on  estimations  of  average  annual  opportunity  costs  from  growing  

corn  and  for  livestock  production.  After  that,  negotiations  took  place  between  the  intermediary  INE  (Instituto  Nacional  de  Ecologica)  and  CONAFOR  (The  Director  General  of  the  National  Forestry  Commission)  and  the  providers.  After  the  negotiations  the  price  was  determined  as  US$  27,  3/ha/year  for  all  forests  except  cloud  forests,  which  received  US$36,4/ha/year.  

(5)  How  are  payments  structured?  Who  administers,  monitors  and  enforces  system?    • Direct  payments  annually  to  the  providers  through  the  intermediary  CONAFOR.  • Monitoring  is  made  by  the  intermediary  and  participants  that  do  not  fulfill  their  

assignment  will  not  receive  payment  at  the  end  of  the  year,  no  matter  how  small  the  change.  

R e s u l t s

Did  it  work?  • More  than  900  applications  were  received  in  the  first  year,  offering  closely  to  600  000  

ha.  Budget  constraints  allowed  less  than  a  third  of  these  applications.’  • The  program  has  reported  no  deforestation  in  participating  areas.  These  numbers  might  

be  a  bit  hard  to  believe  in  and  may  be  a  result  of  the  current  low-­‐resolution  monitoring  methods.  

• 78%  of  the  payments  went  to  forests  owned  by  people  living  in  population  centers  with  high  or  very  high  marginalization.  

• There  appears  to  be  a  bias  against  the  poorest  of  the  poor:  the  very  highly  marginalized  are  under-­‐represented  relative  to  the  highly  marginalized.  

 L e s s o n s l e a r n e d

• Public  knowledge  about  the  ecological  relationships  is  critical  for  policy  design  and  the  design  of  PES  schemes.

• More price differentiation would bring in more environmental benefits than a fixed payment system.

• Landowners might reduce deforestation in participating territories but increase it in other areas. This might not be a big problem if the “other areas” are less important to preserve.

• If barriers exist for the very highly marginalized to participate the program should be complemented with an outreach and support campaign to ensure that the poorest can participate on equal terms.

• Even though the system with the government as an intermediary can be effective and easy to implement the companies should be tried for their true willingness to pay.

• A nation-wide program can be more easily implemented but might not be tailored good enough to local needs and conditions, and not linking directly contributions by users and payments to the forest owners that provide most of their ES. A more decentralized scheme

Page 49: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

49

can handle these obstacles.

 

P E S i n t e r n a t i o n a l C a s e S t u d y s u m m a r y # 1 1 : P a g i o l a ( 2 0 0 8 )

Pagiola    2008.  Payments  for  environmental  services  in  Costa  Rica.  

Location,  type  of  PES,  time  frame,  funding,  etc.  • Entire  country  of  Costa  Rica.  The  article  broadly  summarizes  the  experiences  of  PES  in  

Costa  Rica.  The  PES  program  in  Costa  Rica  is  called  the  PSA  program.  It  started  in  1997  and  is  still  ongoing.  The  PSA  program  is  funded  by  tax  revenue  (3,  5%  of  the  fossil  fuel  tax,  US$10  million  a  year),  a  loan  from  the  World  Bank  and  a  grant  from  Global  environment  facility  (GEF).  Total  amount  not  available.  

• Types  of  PES  are  mainly  taxpayer-­‐funded  markets  but  also  voluntary  markets  and  regulatory  compliance  markets.  The  payments  for  the  services  are  mainly  financed  by  taxes  and  water  tariffs.  Other  incomes  are  those  coming  from  selling  carbon  emission  rights  to  the  World  Bank  Carbon  Emission  Fund  and  the  incomes  coming  from  firms  paying  to  preserve  important  watersheds.    

What  are  the  ecosystem  services  (ES)  addressed  and    

• The  ES  addressed  are  broadly  defined  as  ES  provided  by  forest  such  as  water  services,  biodiversity,  carbon  sequestration  and  landscapes.    

What  management  activity  or  restoration  is  possible  to  improve  the  flow  of  these  ES?  • Mainly  conservation  of  forests,  that  will  help  maintain  all  the  ES  that  comes  from  the  

above.  

What  is  the  current  or  future  threat  to  these  ES?  • Not  a  specific  definition  of  the  threats  but  mainly  exploitation  of  forest  that  includes  

conversion  to  pasture  and  clearing  forest.      K e y p o i n t s t e s t e d

(1)  what  good/service  is  actually  bought  and  sold  and  how  is  it  measured  (what  metric)?  • The  service  bought  is  no.  of  ha  of  forest  preserved.  • Service  sold  is  to  preserve  the  forest.  

 

(2)  Who  are  the  buyers  and  sellers  (providers)?  Are  there  non-­‐buying  beneficiaries  ?  • Buyers:  Firms  that  use  water  as  an  input  in  their  production  (either  buying  due  to  self-­‐

interest  to  preserve  an  important  watershed  (as  they  perceive  it),  or  because  they  are  obligated  to  pay  water  fees).  Firms  that  have  to  buy  permits  of  carbon  emissions  and  

Page 50: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

50

organizations  or  firms  that  pay  for  ES  for  ethical  or  publicity  reasons  (voluntarily).  So  there  is  nothing  mandatory  about  this  program?  This  is  a  key  issue  to  take  up  in  the  PM,  i.e.,  are  most  PES  voluntary  or  mandatory  and  what  does  this  imply  about  the  success  of  the  program?    

• Sellers:  Forest  Landowners  who  receive  payment  for  preserving  the  area.  • Non-­‐buying  beneficiaries:  Not  discussed  in  the  article.  (3)  How  long  is  the  contract/program  designed  for?  Time  frame  for  payment?  • Contracts  are  mainly  yearly  and  the  payments  are  also  yearly.  The  program  is  

continuing  indefinitely.  

(4)  How  was  the  price  addressed  or  determined?  

• Not  really  discussed  in  the  article  more  than  that  it  is  “set  by  an  executive  decree”.  (5)  How  are  payments  structured?  Who  administers,  monitors  and  enforces  system?    

• The  PSA  program  is  managed  by  FONAFIFO,  a  semiautonomous  agency  with  independent  legal  status.  The  board  of  FONAFIFO  is  composed  of  three  public  representatives  and  two  representatives  from  the  private  forest  sector.    

• FONAFIFO  has  a  relative  degree  of  autonomy  but  it  remains  subject  of  some  governmental  restrictions.  FONAFIFO  has  eight  regional  offices  that  handle  applications,  monitor  implementation  and  sign  contracts.  FONAFIFO  are  responsible  but  sometimes  hire  other  agencies  to  do  monitoring  for  them.  

• Initial  payments  can  be  requested  at  contract  signing  but  subsequent  annual  payments  are  made  after  verification  of  compliance.    

 R e s u l t s

Did  it  work?  • It´s  hard  to  summarize  the  results  when  the  perspective  of  the  article  is  so  broad  but  the  

main  parts  is:  • The  PSA  program  has  been  and  is  very  successful.  Even  though  the  program  is  only  

partly  financed  by  service  users,  progress  has  been  made  when  it  comes  to  getting  the  actual  users  of  the  services  to  pay.    

• A  new  water  tariff  will  make  the  direct  payments  increase  as  a  share  of  the  whole.  • Many  users  want  to  free-­‐ride  on  the  efforts  made  by  the  government  and  other  users.  

Where  there  are  many  users  of  a  service  it  is  harder  to  get  the  users  to  pay.    • Although  it  is  not  designed  as  a  poverty  reduction  program  some  studies  has  shown  that  

the  effects  of  the  program  can  be  positive  for  poor  areas.  The  results  of  the  effects  have  been  mixed.      

• Hard  to  measure  the  impact  on  forest  conservation  due  to  other  changes  (legal,  information  etc.).    The  new  harder  environmental  legislation  may  have  been  possible  only  because  of  the  PSA  carrot.  

• Studies  have  found  that  PSA  recipients  have  higher  forest  cover  than  others.      

L e s s o n s l e a r n e d

Page 51: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

51

• The biggest lesson learned is to be flexible and adapt to different situations. • The link between preserved forests and the ES –performance has to be investigated more

closely. This will probably make more users willing to participate. • Familiarity with the PES approach seems to make users more willing to participate. • Important to make the income streams as constant as possible. The fossil fuel tax may be

insecure in the future. More direct payments are preferred. • Efficiency  and  long-­‐term  sustainability  demand  that  understanding  of  how  different  

land  use  practices  contribute  to  environmental  services  be  substantially  improved.    

P E S i n t e r n a t i o n a l C a s e S t u d y s u m m a r y # 1 2 : P h u c X u a n e t a l ( 2 0 1 2 )

Phuc  Xuan  et  al  2012.  The  Prospects  for  Payment  for  Ecosystem  Services  (PES)  in  Vietnam:  A  Look  at  Three  Payment  Schemes  

Location,  type  of  PES,  time  frame,  funding,  etc.  • The  article  examines  the  development  and  implementation  of  three  nationally  

supported  PES  schemes  in  Vietnam.  • Case  study  1:  Ba  Vi  National  Park  in  Hanoi  metropolitan  Area.  Government  supported  

incentive  payment  scheme.  Started  in  the  early  1990s.  Totally  funded  by  government.    • Case  study  2:  Lam  Dong  province  located  at  the  source  of  the  Dong  Nai  River.  

Regulatory  compliance  markets  were  companies  have  to  pay  an  environmental  service  fee  for  the  use  of  the  ES.  Started  in  2008.  Start  up  costs  funded  by  government.  

• Case  study  3:  Son  La  province.  Same  market  type  as  case  study  2.  Start  up  costs  funded  by  government.  

What  are  the  ecosystem  services  (ES)  addressed  and    • Case  study  1:  ES  from  forests.  • Case  study  2:  Water  regulation,  soil  protection  and  scenic  landscape  provided  by  the  

forests.  Carbon  sequestration  and  biodiversity  conservation  were  considered  too  complex  to  measure.  

• Case  study  3:  Water  regulation  and  soil  protection  provided  by  the  forests.  What  management  activity  or  restoration  is  possible  to  improve  the  flow  of  these  ES?  • Case  study  1:  Forest  planting,  and  forest  protection  (not  further  specified)  • Case  study  2:  Preservation  of  forests.    Not  specified  how.  • Case  study  3:  Preservation  of  forests.    Not  specified  how.  

What  is  the  current  or  future  threat  to  these  ES?  • Case  study  1:  Not  specified  (people  use  the  forests  for  their  livelihood).  • Case  study  2:  Not  specified  (the  area  is  used  for  hydropower  plants)  • Case  study  3:  Large  areas  of  forest  in  the  province  have  been  cleared  for  hydropower  

plants.    

K e y p o i n t s t e s t e d

Page 52: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

52

(1)  what  good/service  is  actually  bought  and  sold  and  how  is  it  measured  (what  metric)?  • Case  study  1:  Service  bought/sold  is  forest  protection  and  forest  planting.  Measured  in  

ha.  • Case  study  2:  Service  bought  is  the  stabile  provision  of  water  to  the  hydropower  plants  

that  can  be  used  in  the  production  of  electricity.  Measured  in  m  ³.  Service  sold  is  stabile  provision  of  water  by  conservation  of  forests  (ha).  

• Case  study  3:  Service  bought  is  the  stabile  provision  of  water  to  the  hydropower  plants  that  can  be  used  in  the  production  of  electricity.  Measured  in  m  ³.  Service  sold  is  stabile  provision  of  water  by  conservation  of  forests  (ha).    

(2)  Who  are  the  buyers  and  sellers  (providers)?  Are  there  non-­‐buying  beneficiaries  ?  • Case  study  1:    • Buyer:  The  government  • Sellers:  Households  nearby  the  forest  area.  Households  in  the  buffer  zone  were  

prioritized.  In  total  4,200  ha  of  land  were  contracted  to  97  land  recipients.  In  one  of  the  areas,  The  Ba  Vi  commune,  a  total  of  270  ha  of  forestland  inside  the  park  was  contracted  to  6  out  of  94  households.  These  six  households  got  the  contracts  because  of  their  prior  knowledge  of  it  as  local  officials  (party  officials).  The  area  was  too  big  for  them  to  protect  so  they  in  turn  gave  annual  leases  to  the  other  village  households  in  exchange  for  labor  for  forest  protection  activities.  

• Non  buying  beneficiaries:  N/A  • Case  study  2:  • Buyers:  4  buyers  identified:  2  state  owned  hydropower  plants  companies,  1  water  

supply  organization  and  1  Tourism  Company.  • Sellers:  Nearly  all  of  the  forestlands  in  the  province  are  managed  by  state  entities.  The  

remaining  land  is  managed  by  564  households.  To  ensure  that  local  households  were  able  to  benefit  from  the  revenues,  local  authorities  maintained  old  contract  arrangement  from  the  1980s,  which  resulted  in  the  fact  that  only  10  %  of  the  village  households  gained  access  to  PES  benefits.    

• Non  buying  beneficiaries:  The  other  tourist  companies  benefiting  from  landscape  beauty  of  the  forest.  

• Case  study  3:  • Buyers:  3  buyers  identified:  2  state  owned  hydropower  plants  and  one  water  supply  

company.  • Sellers:  More  than  50  000  forest  owners,  mostly  households.  • Non  buying  beneficiaries:  N/A  

(3)  How  long  is  the  contract/program  designed  for?  Time  frame  for  payment?  • Case  study  1:  Land  was  allocated  to  participants  for  50  years  with  scope  for  extension  if  

they  complied  with  forest  protection  regulations.  Annual  payments  of  100  000  VND/ha  (US$5)  for  forest  protection  and  2.3  million  VND/ha  (US$153)  for  forest  planting.  

• Case  study  2:  No  info  about  length  of  contract.  Environmental  service  fee  for  hydropower  plants  of  20  VND  (0.125  cents)  per  kilowatt  hour;  for  water  supply  companies  the  fee  was  set  at  40VND  (0.25  cents)  per  m³  of  water  supplied.  Payments  

Page 53: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

53

are  290,000VND/ha  (US$16)  for  water  regulation,  270,000  VND/ha  (US$15)  for  soil  protection  and  10,000  VND/ha  (US$0,  5)  for  scenic  landscape  values.  All  payments  were  made  annually.  Totally  US$  2,  8  million  was  being  paid  to  3,400  local  households.  Each  household  will  have  gained  US$  600/year,  an  amount  3,  75  times  higher  than  their  income  prior  to  PES  implementation.  

• Case  study  3:  No  info  about  length  of  contract.  Total  revenue  of  63  billion  VND  (US  $3,5  million)  in  2009,  and  an  average  payment  per  hectare  of  forest  of  397,000  VND  (US$21).    

(4)  How  was  the  price  addressed  or  determined?  • Case  study  1:  No  info  about  how  the  price  was  determined.  • Case  study  2:  A  team  developed  a  “complicated  equation”  to  calculate  the  payment  

levels  but  failed  to  find  a  suitable  fee  to  apply  to  tourist  companies  benefiting  from  the  landscape  beauty  of  the  forest.  The  team  consulted  different  stakeholders  about  their  WTP  and  came  up  with  0.5-­‐2  %  of  the  tourism  companies´  gross  revenue.    A  K  coefficient  was  developed  to  reflect  different  conditions  of  the  forest  (status,  natural,  planted  etc.).  

• Case  study  3:  No  info  about  how  the  price  of  400,000  VND  (US$22)  was  addressed.  Only  that  the  site  had  very  high  opportunity  costs  and  that  the  payment  couldn´t  match  that.  

(5)  How  are  payments  structured?  Who  administers,  monitors  and  enforces  system?    • Case  study  1:  The  park  is  directly  managed  by  MARD  (The  Ministry  of  Agriculture  and  

Rural  Development).The  providers  were  given  direct  monetary  payments  annually  from  a  Park  Management  Board  who  also  offers  the  contracts  to  the  providers.  No  specific  info  about  monitoring  and  enforcing.  

• Case  study  2:  A  “relevant  state  organization”  administers  and  monitors  the  program.  Payment  was  made  based  on  participation  of  the  households  in  the  PES  schemes  rather  than  on  performance  of  the  services  provided  by  the  forest.  There  were  some  problems  with  the  land  use  certificates  because  it  sometimes  showed  different  allocations  than  the  actual  area  allocated  which  made  it  hard  to  see  the  improvements  of  the  ES.  Payments  were  therefore  calculated  according  to  the  land  area  shown  in  the  participants  land  use  certificate  and  based  on  the  forest  quality  at  the  time  of  land  allocation.  

• Case  study  3:  The  distribution  of  payments  faced  a  number  of  problems.  Only  14%  of  the  total  amount  was  transferred.  Only  10%  of  the  households  have  received  any  payment.  This  was  mainly  because  of  the  complexity  of  local  land  tenure  arrangements.  The  ways  the  payments  are  arranged  are  most  likely  to  change  in  the  province.  (No  info  about  administration  or  monitoring  on  this  site  but  probably  similar  to  case  study  2)    

R e s u l t s

Did  it  work?  • Case  study  1:  Only  a  part  of  the  interested  households  were  able  to  participate  due  to  

lack  of  information.  The  information  only  reached  former  local  officials.    • Various  actors  established  contrasting  and  overlapping  claims  and  rights  to  land  inside  

the  park.  This  led  to  conflicts  occurring  between  the  Park  officials  and  villagers  as  the  State  disregarded  villagers´  claims  on  the  land,  as  well  as  unofficial  and  illegal  deals  between  the  six  forestland  contract  holders  and  other  households  in  the  village.    

Page 54: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

54

• The  majority  of  local  households  failed  to  benefit  from  the  scheme.  • Case  study  2:  Each  household  have  earned  an  amount  3.75  times  higher  than  their  

annual  income  prior  to  PES  implementation.  In  many  areas,  the  implementation  of  PES  policy  is  unlikely  to  solve  the  problem  of  poor  forest  governance.    

• The  current  structure  of  payments  do  not  reach  the  poor,  particularly  the  poorest,  usually  newly-­‐established  households  and  migrants  lacking  access  to  land  bur  strongly  reliant  on  forestland  and  forest  resources.    

• Case  study  3:  The  result  of  case  study  3  is  not  very  good,  both  due  to  the  low  rate  of  payments  (only  10%  of  the  participants  have  received  payments  from  the  buyers)  and  due  to  the  complexity  of  the  local  land  tenure  agreements.    

• Results  in  general:    • It  is  too  early  to  conclude  that  a  PES  program  would  be  an  effective  mechanism  for  

forest  protection  more  broadly  in  Vietnam.  •  Owing  to  the  lack  of  technical  capacity  in  measuring  the  quality  of  service  provided  by  

the  forest,  it  is  not  clear  if  the  quality  of  service  provided  has  been  improved.      • The  share  of  payments  retained  by  the  government  from  PES  schemes  was  proving  

insufficient  to  cover  inventory  costs.  • In  addition  to  the  state,  the  PES  policy  in  Lam  Dong  has  mobilized  a  significant  funding  

pool  from  private  actors.  • PES  income  may  compete  with,  rather  than  supplement  other  livelihood  activities.  L e s s o n s l e a r n e d

• There  have  been  problems  implementing  the  programs  due  to  the  uncertainty  about  land  tenure  agreements.    To  conduct  an  inventory  of  all  forest  areas  in  Case  study  3  is  the  way  to  come  around  this  problem    but  would  take  at  least  five  years  at  a  cost  of  56  billion  VND.

• The  unfair  distribution  of  contracts  among  households  has  triggered  conflicts  in  the  villages  resulting  in  resistance  from  the  villagers  by  surreptitiously  cutting  coffee  trees  belonging  to  households  with  contracts.

• In Lam Dong, local authorities decided to pay better-off households a lesser amount per hectare than poor households as a leveling strategy, although both groups provided the same kinds and quality of environmental services. This suggests that while the PES schemes in Vietnam partly embrace the ideals of market-oriented solutions, the socialist market context firmly embeds these programs within contrasting political and economic agendas.

• The state still plays a role in mediating market activities. • One of the state owned power plants didn´t pay PES fees of 218 billion VND (US$ 1.9 million)

in 2010, despite numerous payments requests from the MARD. The hydropower plant was only able to do this because it is owned and protected by the Vietnam Energy Group, which belongs to the Ministry of Industry and Trade. These types of companies may delay their payments indefinitely.

• More than 60 % of Vietnams forests are managed by state entities and the payments derived from these may provide a strong incentive for state entities to hold on to the land, capturing the benefit streams associated with PES while poor households are unable to access such benefits in the face of stronger restrictions on resource access.

Page 55: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

55

• The implementation of PES may exacerbate pre-existing inequalities as local elites monopolize direct income flows and state forest entities control the majority of national forestland.

 

P E S i n t e r n a t i o n a l C a s e S t u d y s u m m a r y # 1 3 : S o m m e r v i l l e e t a l ( 2 0 1 0 )

Sommerville  et  al.  2010.  The  role  of  fairness  and  benefit  distribution  in  community-­‐based  Payment  for  Environmental  Services  interventions:  A  case  study  from  Menabe,  Madagascar    

Location,  type  of  PES,  time  frame,  funding,  etc.  • Menabe,    Madagascar.  Program  started  2003  and  is  still  running.    • Community-­‐based  PES.  Communities  are  competing  with  each  other  about  an  award.  • Information  about  who  is  funding  is  not  available.    • Annually  US$  8500  is  distributed  as  an  award  to  communities.  What  are  the  ecosystem  services  (ES)  addressed  and    • ES  from  forests  with  a  focus  on  biodiversity  (the  forests  are  sole  habitat  for  4  

endangered  species  and  critical  habitat  for  numerous  other  endangered  species).  

What  management  activity  or  restoration  is  possible  to  improve  the  flow  of  these  ES?  • Preventing  citizens  of  the  communities  to  damage  and  exploit  the  area.  A  deal  is  signed  

which  clearly  define  the  rules  for  management/administration  of  the  forest.  Community  forest  associations  are  responsible  for  the  implementation  of  the  deal.  

What  is  the  current  or  future  threat  to  these  ES?  • Mainly  conversion  from  forests  to  agricultural  land  but  also  hunting,  timber  cutting  and  

creation  of  new  paths.    K e y p o i n t s t e s t e d

(1)  what  good/service  is  actually  bought  and  sold  and  how  is  it  measured  (what  metric)?  • The  service  sold  is  the  agreement  to  follow  the  rules  set  by  the  government  and  Durrell.    • The  service  bought  is  that  the  citizens  follow  the  rules.  • The  annual  assessment  is  made  by  Durrell  and  the  performance  is  measured  using  an  

indicator  scoring  system.  The  score  depends  on  each  community´s  specific  properties  relative  to  the  other  communities  in  the  region.    

(2)  Who  are  the  buyers  and  sellers  (providers)?  Are  there  non-­‐buying  beneficiaries  ?  • Buyers:  The  NGO  Durrell  • Sellers:  8  Communities  that  own  local  forest  management  rights.  • Non-­‐buying  beneficiaries:  N/A  (3)  How  long  is  the  contract/program  designed  for?  Time  frame  for  payment?  • No  information  about  the  length  of  the  contracts.  Annually  distribution  of  US$8500.  (4)  How  was  the  price  addressed  or  determined?  

Page 56: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

56

• No  information  about  how  the  total  sum  of  US$  8500  was  determined.  So  it  sounds  like  “value”  was  implicitly  determined  here  based  on  the  size  of  the  gov’t  budget  for  this  program  !  i.e.,  there  was  no  attempt  to  try  and  set  price  based  on  how  this  was  valued  by  society.    

(5)  How  are  payments  structured?  Who  administers,  monitors  and  enforces  system?    • US$  8500  is  annually  distributed  to  the  8  communities  that  are  part  of  the  program.  The  

distribution  depends  on  the  performance.  It  can  change  significantly  from  year  to  year.  •  The  award  is  not  distributed  in  cash  but  instead  used  to  purchase  in-­‐kind  incentives.  

Communities  have  purchased  generators,  building  materials,  bicycles  and  cows,  which  the  citizens  can  use.  Key  finding  from  other  articles  too  –  payment  can  be  non-­‐monetary.  Important  to  note.  

• Durrell  is  responsible  for  the  program.    R e s u l t s

Did  it  work?  • The  majority  of  individuals  reported  that  the  community  as  a  whole  benefited  positively  

from  the  intervention.  It  is  described  as  a  success.  • Individuals  perceived  the  community  to  have  benefitted  more  often  than  they  perceived  

their  family  to  have  benefitted.    • Only  a  few  reported  that  their  family  had  explicitly  lost  out  from  the  intervention.  • The  results  indicate  that  association  members  and  those  in  power  received  the  highest  

level  of  net  benefits.      • Individuals  with  high  opportunity  costs  (individuals  who  wanted  to  expand  their  

agricultural  land)  were  less  likely  to  perceive  their  family  as  benefitting  overall  and  also  perceived  unfairness  of  the  distribution.  

• 85%  of  the  respondents  perceived  the  distribution  of  the  incentive  (in-­‐kind  payment)  to  be  fair.    

 L e s s o n s l e a r n e d

• Community-­‐based  PES  doesn´t  necessarily  address  individual  opportunity  costs,  which  may  make  it  difficult  in  incentivizing  individual  behavior.  

• Community-­‐based  PES  can  be  used  as  poverty  reduction  if  the  payments  are  targeted  to  the  poorest  or  are  in-­‐kind,  non-­‐rival  and  non-­‐excludable.  This  may  decrease  the  effect  that  the  ones  with  power  and  wealth  benefit  the  most.  OK,  good  to  know,  answers  my  question  above

• Targeting  can  be  used  when  individual  opportunity  costs  are  important. • The  perception  of  fairness  and  good  governance  (the  performance  of  local  leaders)  is  

very  important  to  make  Community-­‐based  PES  work.  

P E S i n t e r n a t i o n a l C a s e S t u d y s u m m a r y # 1 4 : T u r p i e e t a l ( 2 0 0 8 )

Page 57: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

57

Turpie  et  al.  2008.  The  working  for  water  program:  Evolution  of  a  payments  for  ecosystem  services  mechanism  that  addresses  both  poverty  and  ecosystem  service  delivery  in  South  Africa  

Location,  type  of  PES,  time  frame,  funding,  etc.  • South  Africa,  The  Working  for  Water  (WfW)  program  started  1995.  • WfW  was  initially  initiated  as  a  poverty  relief  works  program.  The  bulk  of  the  funding  

has  been  generated  through  poverty  relief  programs  in  turn  funded  by  tax  revenue.    • Annual  budget  of  R400  million.  (R  6.50-­‐7.50:US$1)  • Both  mandatory  and  voluntary  PES.  Funded  by  tax  revenue  and  voluntary  payments  by  

water  users.  What  are  the  ecosystem  services  (ES)  addressed  and    • ES  from  grasslands  with  focus  on  water  quality,  provision  and  flows.  What  management  activity  or  restoration  is  possible  to  improve  the  flow  of  these  ES?  • Restoration  of  grasslands  by  clearing  them  from  invasive  alien  plants.  What  is  the  current  or  future  threat  to  these  ES?  • Bad  management  practices  such  as  overgrazing,  damming,  inappropriate  burning  

regimes,  and  reclamation  of  wetlands.  Other  threats  are  conversion  of  grasslands  by  afforestation  with  alien  Pinus  and  Eucalyptus  species.  Also  other  alien  vegetation.  

K e y p o i n t s t e s t e d

(1)  what  good/service  is  actually  bought  and  sold  and  how  is  it  measured  (what  metric)?  • The  good  bought  is  manual  clearing  of  invasive  alien  plants  on  important  grassland.    • The  good  sold  is  the  service  to  clear  the  specific  area  that  the  workers  are  hired  to  clear.  • The  metric  is  ha.  (2)  Who  are  the  buyers  and  sellers  (providers)?  Are  there  non-­‐buying  beneficiaries  ?  • Buyers:  The  government  through  the  governmental  program  WfW.  They  in  turn  act  on  

behalf  of  water  users  who  pay  a  water  resource  fee  in  the  water  tariff.  This  part  is  mandatory.  Both  municipalities  and  even  some  companies  have  agreed  voluntary  payments  for  the  service  of  restoration  of  grassland.  The  voluntary  part  is  only  a  small  proportion  so  far.  

• Sellers:  Roving  service  providers  in  the  form  of  small-­‐scale  contractors  who  perform  restoration  work  on  land  under  any  type  of  ownership.  The  contractor  staff  must  have  been  previously  unemployed.  

• Non-­‐buying  beneficiaries:  Private  and  communal  landowners  benefit  from  having  their  land  cleared  through  increased  productivity.  

(3)  How  long  is  the  contract/program  designed  for?  Time  frame  for  payment?  • No  info  about  the  contract  lengths  for  the  mandatory  part.  The  voluntary  buyers’  signs  

contracts  with  the  WfW  and  the  length  of  the  contracts  can  vary.    • No  info  about  contracts  with  sellers.  • No  info  about  the  time  frame  for  payment  but  the  budget  is  annual  so  the  payments  may  

be  annual  as  well.  

Page 58: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

58

(4)  How  was  the  price  addressed  or  determined?  • Mandatory  part:  The  charges  levied  are  based  on  WfW’s  cost  estimates,  divided  by  the  

total  volume  of  registered  water  use  by  the  agricultural,  domestic  and  industrial  sectors,  weighted  according  to  affordability,  assurance  of  supply  and  equity.  

• Voluntary  part:  The  prices  are  negotiated  between  the  municipality/company  and  the  WfW  and  the  final  price  depends  on  the  site  specific  circumstances.  

(5)  How  are  payments  structured?  Who  administers,  monitors  and  enforces  system?    • The  mandatory  payment  is  structured  in  the  way  that  water  users  pay  a  water  resource  

fee  in  the  water  tariff  that  is  administered  by  WfW.  • The  voluntary  payment  can  be  a  lump  payment  for  a  specific  amount  of  year  or  an  

annual  payment.  • WfW  administers  the  program  but  there  are  no  specific  information  about  the  

monitoring  and  enforcing  other  than  that  they  have  to  improve  that  part  of  the  program.    R e s u l t s

Did  it  work?  • The  WfW  program  has  been  hailed  as  highly  successful  in  terms  of  its  objective  of  

restoring  water  supply  in  alien-­‐infested  catchments.  • It  has  been  called  “one  of  the  most  successful  integrated  land  managements  programs  in  

the  world”.  • The  program  has  cleared  more  than  one  million  ha  of  invasive  alien  plants.  • The  program  has  created  thousands  of  jobs  with  a  strong  emphasis  on  gender  equity,  

and  provides  considerable  benefits  such  as  skills  training  and  health  and  HIV/AIDS  awareness  programs.  

• Estimations  has  been  made  that  showed  that  24  000  previously  unemployed  people,  52%  of  whom  are  women,  were  employed  in  2000.  

L e s s o n s l e a r n e d

• A  unique  feature  of  the  program  is  that  the  cost  of  intervention  is  low.  This  is  mainly  because  of  low  opportunity  costs.

• As demand for water grows, there is the potential for moving from a system that is highly dependent on government funding to one based on voluntary transactions. This potential is demonstrated by the voluntary agreements that have been entered into to date, as well as by the expressed willingness of consumers to participate where they have been consulted.

• Thanks to the low costs of the program, it has the luxury of being able to priorities areas for actions using ecological and social rationales.

• Given the scale of the invasive alien species problem facing the country the WfW-model is likely to be sustainable and productive over the long term.

• The program has potential to be expanded to other deal with other ecosystem serviced as well. • The fact that the program is labor intensive and provides opportunity for poverty relief makes

it even more attractive.

Page 59: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

59

P E S i n t e r n a t i o n a l C a s e S t u d y s u m m a r y # 1 5 : W u n d e r a n d A l b a n ( 2 0 0 8 )

Wunder,  Sven  and  Montserrat  Alban.  2008.Decentralized  payment  for  environmental  services:  cases  of  Pimampiro  and  PROFAFOR  in  Ecuador.  Ecological  Economics  65:  685-­‐698  

Location, type of PES, time frame, funding, etc. PES #1: Pimampiro: (2000-2005) watershed scheme in Pimampiro municipal watershed-protection scheme. Funding: (1) users of water (~80% of operation costs) and (2) local municipality. But also (3) start up capital costs came from int’l NGOs. Not sustainable or advised that local gov’t continue to incur costs of program over time (political concerns).

PES#2: PROFAFOR, (1993-2005) Forests Absorbing Carbon-dioxide Emissions Forestation Program carbon-sequestration program whereby Dutch electricity companies pay local landowners to re-forestation and afforestation to meet carbon reduction goals. Funding: Everything paid by Dutch electricity firms apparently – (1) start up costs (2) landowner payments and technical assistance (75% of operation costs) (3) administration such as enforcement, etc. (25% of operation costs).

What are the ecosystem services (ES) addressed ? What management activity or restoration is possible to improve the flow of these ES? • Pimampiro addresses water quality/quantity through forest management and promoting

natural vegetation cover • PROFAFOR provides carbon sequestration services by paying landowners to plant trees What is the current or future threat to these ES? • Pimampiro – agriculture displacing forests, leading to local water quality/quantity impacts • PROFAFOR – agriculture displaces forests, leading to CO2 emissions globally. Key points tested

(1) what good/service is actually bought and sold and how is it measured (what metric)? Pimampiro: the service is water quality delivered through proper forest management. There are 19 households contracts covering ~600 hectares. Contracts are measured by % vegetative cover, but as with most PES there is some scientific agreement on measuring the quantity of ES being delivered, i.e.,. how does existence of tress actually reduce evaporation, reduce run-off, improve water quantity/quality? Research on-going. PROFAFOR. Carbon sequestration. But, as is typical, controversy about how to attribute the actual amount of carbon sequestered by native vegetation (preferred) versus other vegetation.

(2) Who are the buyers and sellers (providers)? Are there non-buying beneficiaries ? Pimampiro

• Buyers: 1350 households in town that have water meters and pay 20% surcharge on water consumption. There are lots of free-riders in town that do NOT have water meters. But surveys indicate that 80+% are willing to pay for this ES of water provision.

• Sellers: 27 households in upper region that get paid to manage forests. Most of these are extremely poor, with payments making up 30% of annual income.

PROFAFOR

Page 60: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

60

• Buyers: Dutch electricity firms wanting to reduce CO2. Obviously lots of free-riders since the global community benefits from CO2 reduction.

• Sellers: mostly private landowners (~130) but also communities as a whole. Note that some sellers also benefit from forest training over and beyond financial payment

(3) How long is the contract/program designed for? Time frame for payment? Pimampiro: Initially 5 years, but then extended indefinitely into the future. Note that it took one year to set this up and 4 additional months to negotiate and write contracts. Long lead time. PROFAFOR Up to 99 years. Payment made over time. First to cover planting costs (80% of cost) then other 20% if trees survive, which gives incentive for proper management re-forested (30% of payment). Finally, 70% of revenues from harvest at end of cycle PLUS final 30% of revenues if they fully re-forest afterwards (if they do not re-forest, they must pay). In addition, they receive “in-kind” payments in terms of products from thinning etc. (4) How was the price addressed or determined? Pimampiro: 6-12 $/yr/hectare depending on quality of forest type and how it improves water quality/quantity PROFAFOR. Based on opportunity costs of re-forestation, plus the market priced of timber. Pretty straight forward calculations.

(5) How are payments structured? Who administers, monitors and enforces system? Pimampiro. In practice, picks 3 random contracts (of 19) to visit each year and check whether they are doing as they say, but in practice little money available for this monitoring to happen. But it has led to penalties and some were kicked out. It seems to have ‘conditionality” in delivering ES. PROFAFOR. Visits every contracted area at least once every year, some times more. This is costly, but still only 25% of total costs. Penalties have been enforced against individual landowners, but bigger problem enforcing against communities themselves. Results

Did it work? In general: We find that both schemes have been relatively effective in reaching their environmental objectives, in terms of having probably high additionality levels and low leakage effects. A strong focus on the targeted environmental service and a strong degree of conditionality seem to be two key factors explaining these achievements. Although neither scheme has targeted poverty alleviation or other side objectives, both are likely to have improved PES recipients' welfare, mostly through higher incomes. We highlight several observations with more generalized relevance and lessons for the design of PES schemes.

Pampiro. The Pampiro has inspired other similar programs. In total, three other watershed protection PES schemes in Ecuador are now up and running, while another seven are in design stages (as of 2008).

PROFAFOR is successful, but of course communities with higher quality forest resources do better. Successful communities also invest revenues in schools, family orchards, machinery (including trace- tors), infrastructure and creation of micro-credit schemes. ‘Less successful’ cases typically are more land-scarce and have low plantation management capacity, resulting in sub-opti- mal tree growth. They often exhibit organizational weak- nesses — at the extreme,

Page 61: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

61

communal leaders have run away with the PES funds.

Beyond the pure income accounts, there are wider livelihood effects from PES. For instance, forestry training has expanded human capital, although this has mostly been restricted to community leaders.

Lessons learned

Monitoring costs need to be internalized into user payments to make the system fully financially sustainable, instead of relying on local gov’t budgets to incur part of adm cost of running program.

Both schemes' natural focus on environmentally strategic but economically marginal lands was clearly in favor of the poor because they tend to live in these areas.

the hydrological service is much more spatially specific than carbon sequestration

No side objectives were targeted in either scheme, in terms of either welfare goals (e.g. poverty alleviation) or of other environmental services (e.g. biodiversity protection). However, both schemes are likely to contribute to some extent to such goals through unintentional side effects. However, the authors also note that diluting environmental objectives with other objectives may reduce program efficiency. A possible trade-off here. The Pimampiro PES scheme is a conservation set-aside, ‘activity- reducing’ scheme, basically designed to downscale agriculture in an environmentally sensitive area. In contrast, PROFAFOR is an ‘asset-building’ scheme that at least temporarily increases economic activity and local employment (Wunder, 2005). PROFAFOR While measures can mitigate farmers' liquidity shortages, they cannot eliminate the underlying basic problem: that it takes significant time for trees to grow before they can be harvested and yield significant economic returns.

Calculating land opportunity costs more explicitly could raise the environmental efficiency of the PES schemes – “greater bang for the buck” through differentiated payments. One could discriminate and pay different landowners differently (more for high threat areas and elevated opportunity costs) , but this raises inevitable issues of fairness.

In addition to buyers and sellers themselves, there can be some winners/losers in terms of the institutions that carry out the PES. Sometimes they are pioneers (winners), other times they loser b/c they incur too great a portion of administrative costs.

Start up costs can be very high for small area PES schemes.

P E S i n t e r n a t i o n a l C a s e S t u d y s u m m a r y # 1 5 : Z a b e l a n d B o s t e d t ( 2 0 1 0 )

Zabel  and  Bostedt    2010.  Outcomes  and  Determinants  of  Success  of  a  

Page 62: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

62

Performance  Payment  Scheme  for  Carnivore  Conservation  

Location,  type  of  PES,  time  frame,  funding,  etc.  • Northern  part  of  Sweden.  • Government  funded  performance  payment  scheme,  started  1996.  • Empirical  investigation  conducted  during  2008  and  2009.  • No  info  about  total  funding  but  SEK  200  000  per  offspring.  What  are  the  ecosystem  services  (ES)  addressed  and    • Biodiversity,  preservation  of  lynx  and  wolverine.  What  management  activity  or  restoration  is  possible  to  improve  the  flow  of  these  ES?  • Protect  the  endangered  species  lynx  and  wolverine  by  preventing  illegal  poaching.  What  is  the  current  or  future  threat  to  these  ES?  • Illegal  poaching,  mainly  by  reindeer  herders.  K e y p o i n t s t e s t e d

(1)  what  good/service  is  actually  bought  and  sold  and  how  is  it  measured  (what  metric)?  • Service  bought  is  that  the  reindeer  herders  will  refrain  from  illegal  hunting  of  lynx  and  

wolverine  and  to  let  their  reindeer  roam  free  as  potential  food  for  carnivores.  • Service  sold  is  essentially  the  same  as  above.  • Both  services  are  measured  in  the  total  numbers  of  offspring  that  are  certified  on  the  

Samis  reindeer  grazing  grounds.  (2)  Who  are  the  buyers  and  sellers  (providers)?  Are  there  non-­‐buying  beneficiaries  ?  • Buyer:  The  government.  • Sellers:  Indigenous  Swedish  Sami  villages  (reindeer  herders).  • Non-­‐buying  beneficiaries:  N/A.  (3)  How  long  is  the  contract/program  designed  for?  Time  frame  for  payment?  • No  info  about  length  of  the  program.  No  info  about  time  frame  for  payment  but  

inventories  of  the  populations  is  made  annually  and  that  probably  implies  annual  payments  per  offspring.  

(4)  How  was  the  price  addressed  or  determined?  • The  payments  are  SEK  200  000  per  offspring,  (SEK  1≈0,14  US$).  It  is  computed  to,  on  

average,  compensate  slightly  more  than  the  damage  a  carnivore  is  expected  to  cause  during  its  lifetime.  

(5)  How  are  payments  structured?  Who  administers,  monitors  and  enforces  system?    • The  carnivores  are  inventoried  every  winter.  The  Sami  villages  receive  payments  (SEK  

200  000)  for  every  offspring  certified  on  their  grazing  grounds.  The  inventory  is  performed  by  herders  and  rangers  and  is  conducted  according  to  very  detailed  regulations.    

R e s u l t s

Page 63: Background 2.2 int cases - Fores – Den gröna liberala ...fores.se/.../uploads/2012/11/Background-2.2-int-cases.pdfDeveloping*a*piloting*model*on*payments*for*coastal*wetland*ecosystem*services*in*MuiCa*

63

Did  it  work?  • The  econometric  analysis  provides  evidence  that  the  combined  “carrot  and  stick  

approach”,  i.e.  performance  payments  and  penalties  on  illicit  poaching,  provide  sufficient  incentives  for  herders  to  abstain  from  illegal  poaching.  

• The  most  important  sole  factor  impacting  the  number  of  wolverine  offspring  is  the  abundance  of  mountainous  areas,  which  is  wolverines  preferred  habitat.    

• There  is  a  negative  relationship  between  the  size  of  the  Sami  villages  (number  of  herders)  and  the  conservation  success.  

• There  is  a  positive  relationship  between  the  allocation  of  performance  payments  directly  to  individuals  and  increased  conservation  success.  

•    L e s s o n s l e a r n e d

• If  strict  conservation  is  required  due  to  the  status  of  a  carnivore  species,  providing  pro-­‐conservation  incentives,  such  as  performance  payments,  additional  to  regulations  can  generate  favorable  results.

• The  conservation  success  depends  on  a  groups´  potential  to  engage  in  collective  action. • Group  size  was  found  to  be  a  particularly  important  factor  but  other  factors  such  as  

economic  or  cultural  homogeneity,  social  capital,  and  exit  options  are  also  likely  to  be  important.

• The  general  advice  is  to  allocate  as  much  as  possible  directly  to  individual  group  members.

• Because  of  its  relative  uniqueness,  an  interesting  question  would  thus  be  to  test  the  transferability  of  the  performance  payments  approach  to  a  developing  country  setting.