Asian Journal of Political Science

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/9/2019 Asian Journal of Political Science

    1/26

    PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE

    This article was downloaded by: [Weede, Erich]

    On: 20 August 2010

    Access details: Access Details: [subscription number 926060054]

    Publisher Routledge

    Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office: Mortimer House, 37-

    41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK

    Asian Journal of Political SciencePublication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information:http://www.informaworld.com/smpp/title~content=t741771145

    The Rise of India: Overcoming Caste Society and Permit-License-QuotaRaj, Implementing Some Economic FreedomErich Weedeaa Institute of Political Science and Sociology, University of Bonn, Germany

    Online publication date: 20 August 2010

    To cite this Article Weede, Erich(2010) 'The Rise of India: Overcoming Caste Society and Permit-License-Quota Raj,Implementing Some Economic Freedom', Asian Journal of Political Science, 18: 2, 129 153

    To link to this Article: DOI: 10.1080/02185377.2010.492977URL: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/02185377.2010.492977

    Full terms and conditions of use: http://www.informaworld.com/terms-and-conditions-of-access.pdf

    This article may be used for research, teaching and private study purposes. Any substantial orsystematic reproduction, re-distribution, re-selling, loan or sub-licensing, systematic supply ordistribution in any form to anyone is expressly forbidden.

    The publisher does not give any warranty express or implied or make any representation that the contentswill be complete or accurate or up to date. The accuracy of any instructions, formulae and drug dosesshould be independently verified with primary sources. The publisher shall not be liable for any loss,actions, claims, proceedings, demand or costs or damages whatsoever or howsoever caused arising directlyor indirectly in connection with or arising out of the use of this material.

    http://www.informaworld.com/smpp/title~content=t741771145http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/02185377.2010.492977http://www.informaworld.com/terms-and-conditions-of-access.pdfhttp://www.informaworld.com/terms-and-conditions-of-access.pdfhttp://dx.doi.org/10.1080/02185377.2010.492977http://www.informaworld.com/smpp/title~content=t741771145
  • 8/9/2019 Asian Journal of Political Science

    2/26

    The Rise of India: Overcoming CasteSociety and Permit-License-Quota Raj,Implementing Some EconomicFreedom

    Erich Weede

    Two or three centuries ago most of mankind was still very poor. When the West outgrew

    mass poverty, India was a British colony and suffered from stagnation. When East Asian

    economies exploited the advantages of backwardness and benefited from export-led

    growth, India remained inward-looking and poor. The Hindu rate of growth preserved

    mass poverty. Since the reforms of the early 1990s India has exploited the advantages of

    backwardness and some global markets. In this article, the roots of Indias failure to grow

    rapidly before the end of the twentieth century are analyzed. Stagnation is blamed on

    restrictions of economic freedom, whereas growth is explained by the expansion of

    economic freedom. Before the mid-twentieth century, the caste system and the legacy of

    sultanism curtailed economic freedom and contributed to economic stagnation. There-

    after, democratic socialism distorted incentives and generated permit-license-quota raj

    or a rent-seeking society. When some obstacles to growth were dismantled, vigorous

    growth followed. Although expanding economic freedom remains limited. Indias growth

    potential is not yet fully exploited. Indian infrastructure and human capital formation

    remain inadequate, regulations intrusive, and the budget in deficit. The rule of law looks

    better on paper than from the ground. Compared to China Indian public policy still has

    a lot of room for improvements. Maoists or Naxalites threaten political stability andeconomic freedom. Geopolitics may explain Indias late, slow and incomplete reforms. The

    rise of Asia, in particular of China and India, generates geopolitical challenges of its own.

    Conceivably, the global expansion of economic freedom permits not only the rise of Asia,

    but the peaceful management of the coming power transition between Asia and the West.

    Keywords: Capitalism; Caste; Economic Freedom; Geopolitics; Growth; India; Regulation

    Erich Weede, PhD, was a Professor of Sociology at the University of Bonn, Germany. He is a member of the

    Mont Pelerin Society. Correspondence to: Erich Weede, Institute of Political Science and Sociology, University ofBonn, Germany. Email: [email protected]

    ISSN 0218-5377 (print)/ISSN 1750-7812 (online) # 2010 Asian Journal of Political Science

    DOI: 10.1080/02185377.2010.492977

    Asian Journal of Political Science

    Vol. 18, No. 2, August 2010, pp. 129153

  • 8/9/2019 Asian Journal of Political Science

    3/26

    Introduction

    The purpose of this article is the explanation of Indian economic performance in the

    long run. The tools of this effort are propositions tested elsewhere, some of them

    tested in my own work, most of them tested in econometric studies done by others.

    Although my explanatory effort is not fit for testing a theory, it illustrates the

    relevance of theorizing about economic freedom.

    Some centuries ago most of mankind was still desperately poor. There was not

    much per-capita-income disparity between countries. Only 400 years ago, the real

    wages of farm labourers in India might have been higher than those in Britain

    (Goldstone, 2008: 82). During the nineteenth and twentieth centuries, a peninsula

    and subcontinent attached to Asia, namely Europe and its North American and

    Australasian daughter societies, overcame mass poverty (Collins, 1986; Jones, 1981;

    Landes, 1998; Maddison, 2001; North, 1990; Weber, 1923/1981; Weede, 1996; 2000;

    2009). After modern economic growth began, the global population increased seven-fold, global production more than 60-fold, and manufacturing industry at least

    75-fold (Goklany, 2007: 19, 41).

    After the rise of the West, Japan joined it by making economic development its top

    priority. After World War II Singapore, Hong Kong, Taiwan and South Korea followed

    the same path. But most of mainland Asia, including India, remained mired in

    stagnation and poverty until the 1980s. Certainly until then, and possibly until the end

    of the second millennium, the gap between developed and less developed countries

    widened and the global distribution of income became less and less equal. China and

    India together account for almost 40 per cent of mankind. Once they joined thecapitalist market economies, capitalism became truly global. Mainland Asia is catching

    up. According to Maddison (2007: 378, 381), in 1950 the Asian share of world

    population was 54.7 per cent, but the Asian share of world gross domestic product

    (GDP) was only 18.6 per cent. By 2003 the Asian share of global population had

    increased to 59.4 per cent, but the Asian share of world GDP had more than doubled

    and increased to 40.5 per cent. In 2003 the West still commanded 43 per cent of world

    GDP, but contained only 12 per cent of global population (Maddison, 2007: 71).

    Global growth is good for the poor (Dollar and Kraay, 2002). Even global income

    distributions between households and persons finally mighthave become more equalagain (Collier and Dollar, 2002; Sala-i-Martin, 2007; Wolf, 2004: chapter 9; World

    Bank, 2005). Since all of the empirical studies have to build on less than perfect data

    and some questionable assumptions, one may accept the scepticism of Anand and

    Segal (2008) that we do not really know how the global distribution of income is

    changing. If one wants to arrive at some admittedly uncertain and preliminary

    conclusion, however, then one may start with Anand and Segals (2008: 6364)

    compilation of studies. Among those analyses which cover the last three decades of

    the twentieth century, six of them report a decrease, but only three report an increase,

    in inequality. Thus, there is more, albeit inconclusive evidence in favour of an

    equalizing trend than of a change for the worse.

    130 E. Weede

  • 8/9/2019 Asian Journal of Political Science

    4/26

    Developing countries benefit from the diffusion of technology from rich to poor

    countries in terms of life expectancy. Life expectancy in many poor countries is

    higher today than it was at the same stage of economic development in Western

    societies (Goklany, 2007: 39). According to Bhalla (2002: 187), the global middle class

    is no longer Western and white. Most members of the global middle class were Asiansalready by the turn of the millennium.1

    The rise of Asia might also be illustrated in a different way. According to the recent

    data published by the World Bank (2009: 378379), the rank order of gross national

    incomes in purchase power parity terms is: first, the United States; second, China;

    third, Japan; fourth, India; fifth, Germany; sixth, Britain; seventh, Russia; eighth,

    France. Three among the top five are Asian economies. The rise of China and,

    somewhat more slowly, of India will not only make global poverty rates fall, but also

    affect the global balance of power.2 According to Maddisons (2007: 343) estimates,

    China might control about 23 per cent, the USA 17 per cent, and India 10 per cent ofgross world product in 2030.

    As this sketch of global economic history illustrates, India missed the boat of

    economic development in the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries, when the West

    surged ahead. Although the ultimate cause of economic development seems to be

    institutional and determined by politics, India is a civilization where political

    institutions and their frequently negative impact on economic freedom and property

    rights, on incentives and opportunities to exploit knowledge do not suffice to explain

    its falling behind the West. In India*by contrast with China and the West (Weede,

    2009)*religion and the caste system also had some harmful effects. Since its

    independence, however, in the middle of the twentieth century, politics reasserted

    itself and led to permit-license-quota raj which retarded catch-up growth in India

    until the 1990s. Only in the last decades has India expanded economic freedom

    a bit and permitted creeping capitalism to make inroads in its persistent poverty.

    How the caste system, pervasive bureaucratic interference with the economy,3 and

    liberalizing reforms affected economic freedom4 and growth will be analyzed in the

    next section.

    Caste Society and Stagnation

    The majority of Indians, whether under Mughal or British or democratic rule, have

    always been Hindus. Webers (1921/1978) treatment of Hinduism is the best part of

    his sociology of religion. Much of Hindu religion*for example, whether one prefers

    Shiva or Vishnu among the gods*is quite irrelevant for the economic order and

    growth. But the ideas of caste duties, retribution, and reincarnation are important.

    A simplified account suffices for the purposes of this article. For Hindus, there is

    a natural rank order of human beings. One is born into an estate, or more exactly,

    a caste. Castes differ in ritual purity with Brahmins, or priests, being the cleanest

    group, whereas the untouchables or dalits, being definitely unclean. In Webers

    analysis, the spirit of Hinduism and the caste system promoted a flight from this

    Asian Journal of Political Science 131

  • 8/9/2019 Asian Journal of Political Science

    5/26

    world rather than attempts to improve it. Most Hindus, especially lower caste

    Hindus, aspire to have a rebirth in a higher caste. The way to achieve it was to fulfil

    ones caste duties. Doing somebody elses duties, especially the duties of a cleaner

    task, would be worse than useless. It would not be rewarded by a better reincarnation

    next time, but punished by a worse one. Thus, the caste system restricted economicfreedom. It came close to preventing individual mobility, thereby making a rational

    or wealth-maximizing division of labour impossible.

    Moreover, the caste system deterred innovation because of some magical beliefs,

    according to which innovation might not only be incompatible with ones

    caste duties or dharma, and thus, damage ones prospects of upward mobility on

    the way to the next life, but according to which forgetting ones caste obligations

    also harms other members of the caste too. So, the conformity pressure within

    castes made technical innovation or change in working practice quite difficult in

    traditional India.In Hinduism, rule and military service were the right and duty of a specific caste,

    the Kshatriyas or Rajputs.5 Where the mass of the people is excluded from military

    service, there is little reason for rulers to grant rights, including property rights to

    them (Andreski, 1968). Not only Hinduism and the caste system contributed to the

    disarmament of most of the Indian population, but the heterodox teachings of Jains

    and Buddhists had a similar impact. They taught ahimsa, or radical pacifism. The

    assertion of rights by military means could only damage the prospects of non-

    members of the warrior caste in the next incarnation. Since the inhabitants of many

    Indian cities in the first millennium adhered to Jainism or Buddhism, and later to

    Hinduism, self-defending and self-ruling cities could not be established in traditionalIndia. Religious doctrine made military service inconceivable for too many Indians.

    Because of the fine gradations of cleanliness among Indians, they could not even eat

    together, much less fight together in order to assert their rights against ruling

    authorities.

    To sum up, Hinduism had two negative effects on the establishment of economic

    freedom, capitalism and growth.

    First, it diverted the upper castes to transcendent concerns and most of the middle

    and lower castes to a ritualistic instead of a rational division of labour which could be

    guided by the principles of comparative advantage and mobility or job hoppinginstead of descent and ascription. Whether one belonged to a clean or unclean caste,

    economic freedom was severely restricted.

    Second, the caste system made self-rule in cities, by merchants and artisans as in

    medieval Europe, rather than arbitrary rule less likely and thereby undermined the

    establishment of the institutional prerequisites of capitalism.

    An analysis of Indian history has to consider that huge parts of India have been

    ruled by Muslims for most of the second millennium. In Webers (1922/1964) terms,

    Muslim rule in India qualifies as sultanism. Sultanism is the most extreme subtype of

    patrimonialism which is defined by the dependence of the staff on the ruler who

    controls the means of administration as well as the livelihood of his staff. In sultanism

    132 E. Weede

  • 8/9/2019 Asian Journal of Political Science

    6/26

    rulers were assisted by foreigners and slaves who enjoyed no support in society. They

    absolutely depended on the ruler and his grace. The more dependent on his grace the

    staff of the ruler is, the more reliable an instrument of arbitrary rule it becomes. That

    is why sultanism provides the weakest protection of property rights for subjects. In

    addition to the caste system, centuries of sultanism also restricted economic freedomin India.

    Economic backwardness in India and elsewhere is sometimes explained by colonial

    exploitation. There is no doubt that exploitation happened, but exploitation does not

    usually lead to development in exploiting countries. Iberian rule over Latin America

    illustrates this point. It helped neither Spain nor Portugal to develop. Moreover,

    ruling classes other than Western colonialists have exploited their subjects, too.

    Maddison (2007: 123) provides a quantitative estimate of the exploitation of India by

    the Mughals and their British successors: The income which the Mughal elite, native

    princes and zamindars [officials] managed to squeeze from the rural population wasproportionately quite large. It amounted to about 15 per cent of national income . . .

    But, by the end of British rule, the successors of the old elite got only 3 per cent.

    Of course, the caste system has never been immutable. Current developments may

    be summarized under the headlines of westernization and sanskritization. According

    to Srinivas (1959: 159), westernization affects the upper and more privileged castes,

    whereas sanskritization is an attempt by lower caste groups to achieve collective

    mobility and respectability by purifying their lifestyles. Since westernization implies

    the acquisition of marketable skills, it promotes economic development and growth.

    The Brahmin might study information technology or engineering instead of religious

    texts, such as the Vedas. If the low-ranking shudra or dalit (untouchable), however,gives up dirty work, this does not guarantee that he finds better-paid work. So,

    sanskritization may imply deepening poverty rather than overcoming it (Sharma,

    1974). Whereas sanskritization dates back to British colonial rule, within independent

    India castes have become special interest groups which demand and frequently get

    special privileges, such as access to universities or government jobs*not because of

    merit but in order to remedy past sufferings by affirmative action. That is why it now

    even happens that castes demand to be reclassified downward in order to qualify for

    privileges (Nilekani, 2009: 285).

    The reassertion of Hindu identity is more frequently analyzed by writers interestedin political rather than economic development (Nussbaum, 2007; Devare, 2009).

    Although one has to deplore the destruction of mosques or the killing of thousands

    of Muslims by Hindu extremists, one simultaneously should note that leading Hindu

    revivalists, such as Savakar,6 are not pious traditionalists reaffirming caste rules, piety

    or service to the gods, but ardent nationalists interested in catch-up growth and

    making India a great power. By contrast, the secularist Brahmin Nehru expressed his

    contempt for capitalism and entrepreneurship in traditional caste terms by reference

    to bania civilization (Nilekani, 2009: 76).

    According to Greenfeld (2001: 218) the view of the economy as a battlefield in the

    struggle for national supremacy provides much of the motivation for economic

    Asian Journal of Political Science 133

  • 8/9/2019 Asian Journal of Political Science

    7/26

    growth. As in Japan more than hundred years ago, nationalism in contemporary

    China seems currently to be succeeding at legitimating entrepreneurship, private

    property rights, and capitalism and thereby overcoming the traditional contempt and

    lack of respect from which merchants suffered in the Confucian societies of East Asia.

    A similar development in India might be economically useful*

    in spite of the obviouspolitical dangers connected with nationalism. Increasing the status of banias

    (entrepreneurs,7 merchants, traders) at the expense of Brahmins, politicians and

    bureaucrats might be exactly what India needs for the sake of development and

    growth.

    Permit-License-Quota Raj

    From the 1950s to 1980 per capita incomes in India and China were fairly similar to

    each other. Per capita incomes in both countries grew more slowly than globally

    (Maddison, 1998: 4041). Both of them pursued leap-forward strategies which

    focused on heavy industries in spite of capital scarcity and labour abundance.

    Comparative advantage was neglected (Lin et al., 2003: chapter 2). It could not be

    exploited until the focus on heavy industry and import-substitution was mitigated

    or given up. Like China, India was afflicted with socialism and an emphasis on

    planning.8 Of course, a comparative advantage defying development strategy would

    have been impossible in a free and competitive market economy. A large involvement

    of government makes big and persistent mistakes possible. Whereas China suffered

    from the repressive and radical variety of socialism, India tried the democratic

    variety. Both countries, even democratic India, more or less disengaged from theglobal economy. In the late 1940s when India became independent, its share in

    global exports was 2.4 per cent. In the early 1990s, it was only 0.4 per cent (Bhagwati,

    1993: 58).

    The poor performance of the worlds most populous countries was not inevitable.

    In principle, both of them should have enjoyed the advantages of backwardness and

    should have benefited from conditional convergence (Barro and Sala-i-Martin, 1995;

    Helpman, 2004; Levine and Renelt, 1992; Levine and Zervos, 1993; Olson, 1996).

    Although not all backward economies do converge, although not all of them exploit

    the potential advantages of backwardness, in principle the followers of the globaldevelopment process enjoy some advantages over the pioneers. If they choose to do

    so, they can benefit from the greater degree of economic freedom and development of

    the more advanced countries (Weede, 2006). They may borrow technologies.9 They

    easily find opportunities for productive investment and are less likely to run into the

    problem of decreasing returns. They can reallocate labour from less productive

    employment in agriculture to more productive employment in industry and, later, in

    services.

    Whether or not a backward economy develops and catches up depends on other

    factors. Without investment or human capital formation economic growth is

    unlikely. Insufficient amounts of investment cannot explain why neither India nor

    134 E. Weede

  • 8/9/2019 Asian Journal of Political Science

    8/26

    China succeeded in realizing the advantages of backwardness in the 1950s to

    1970s.10 Instead the productivity of investment left much to be desired (Bhagwati,

    1993: 40ff.). Human capital formation is another candidate to explain this. Here,

    China and India differ. Already in 1950, the Chinese had benefited from a little bit

    more schooling than the Indians (Maddison, 1998: 63). Now China scores muchbetter in adult literacy than India, namely, 93 against 66 per cent (World Bank,

    2009: 378). What holds Indian education back is teacher absenteeism (Panagariya,

    2008: 365, chapter 20).11 The difference in human capital formation between Asias

    giants may help us to understand why China outperformed India. In the early

    twenty-first century the Chinese advantage persists. According to the World Bank

    (2005) and The Economist (2005a: 10), at the beginning of the twenty-first century

    Chinese workers have been 50 per cent more productive than Indians, but cost

    only 25 per cent more.

    Compared to the global economy India and China did poorly in the 1950s to

    1970s. Advantages of backwardness were not realized in spite of sufficient investment

    and, at least in China, sufficient human capital formation. This poor economic

    performance was to be expected on the basis of an institutional explanation of the

    ultimate sources of growth, where economic freedom, property rights, incentives and

    opportunities to exploit knowledge matter most, as I have argued elsewhere (Weede,

    1996; 2000; 2009).12 Although India became and remained a democracy after its

    independence, although it never nationalized all the means of production, it

    nevertheless was inspired by the Soviet model for decades (Lal, 1998: 129). As

    pointed out by Maddison (2007: 130) Ghandian pressures in favor of self-sufficiency

    had a similar impact.Slow growth and persistent poverty were the results of this inspiration. Bureau-

    cratic controls and interventions weakened incentives, severely restricted entrepre-

    neurial decisions on hiring and firing and distorted prices. Import substitution and

    protectionism contributed to weak competition. Favoured enterprises, cartels, and

    even monopolies enjoyed an easy and profitable life at the expense of consumers. The

    political economy of India was characterized by license-permit raj (FICCI, 1999:

    165). Moreover, marginal income tax rates in India had been above 90 per cent some

    decades ago. At the beginning of the twenty-first century, they are down to about

    30 per cent (Panagariya, 2008: 336

    342).One of the reasons why India did rather poorly for the first decades after

    independence is the fragmented character of its markets. Already Adam Smith (1976/

    1976) taught in the late eighteenth century that productivity depends on the division

    of labour, and that the division of labour depends on the size of the market.

    An Indian entrepreneur (Nilekani, 2009: 242243) deplores the limited size of Indian

    markets in the following terms:

    India has been routinely described as a land deeply fragmented, with divisionswithin divisions, and I think this description especially suits our markets, which aresplintered all over the place*fragmented at the state level thanks to policydifferences, and locally because of regulation, weak infrastructure and information

    Asian Journal of Political Science 135

  • 8/9/2019 Asian Journal of Political Science

    9/26

    networks that cover only half the country. In fact, while India has managed tosustain a political unity that has defied all expectations, economic unity has beenfar more difficult for us to achieve.

    Although the improvement of infrastructure*from ports to rail or roads*

    necessarily takes time, the avoidable contribution of politicians and administrators

    to fragmented markets should not be forgotten. States impose taxes at state borders.

    Worse still, sometimes they force growers to sell their produce to local monopolists.

    Uttar Pradesh cane sugar-growers are an example for this type of misguided policy

    (Nilekani, 2009: 246). Whereas state borders are obstacles to trade for some, they

    constitute an opportunity to milk the public purse for others. Nilekani (2009: 250)

    points to a 50 per cent subsidy for pesticides in Uttar Pradesh which makes some

    trucks cross the state border multiple times with the same cargo in order to collect

    the subsidy each time. Of course, this abuse becomes easier where the border patrols

    are corrupt and take their cut. Different markets may be more or less affected byfragmentation. According to Nilekani (2009: 251), agriculture suffers most from

    constricted markets, manufacturing somewhat less, and services least. This rank order

    mirrors different sectoral growth rates.

    By contrast to the private sector the public sector expanded. Its share in gross

    domestic product increased from 8 to 26 per cent between 1960 and 1991 (Yergin and

    Stanislaw, 1998: 216). Even in the late 1980s, the Indian public sector took about

    70 per cent of all workers employed by big enterprises (Bhagwati, 1993: 64). It

    accounted for about 6 per cent of the economically active population and twice as

    many people as private employers of more than ten workers (The Economist, 1997:13). So, except for the impoverished informal sector and agriculture, public

    enterprises were dominant in India. Like elsewhere, public enterprises in India

    tended to be less efficient than private enterprises (Majumdar, 1998). Firing workers

    became close to impossible before the enterprise went bankrupt (Bhagwati, 1993: 65,

    86; Joshi and Little, 1998: 211ff.).

    Strong job protection in the formal sector, however, came at a price. Employment

    in the formal sector was reduced by about 30 per cent because of labour market

    regulations which made Indian enterprises install machines instead of hiring

    workers

    13

    (Nilekani, 2009: 308

    312). Although Indian socialism benefited a minorityof workers, the poorest strata of society were denied all access to formal employment.

    Certainly, Indian socialism neither expanded economic freedom, nor optimized

    incentives. Democratic socialism in India provided as little hope for the poor or their

    children as socialism in China did before Deng Xiaopings reforms.

    Although there has been a lively debate about the degree, kind and success of state

    intervention in East Asian economies, nobody doubts the strong interference of the

    Indian state with the economy. Even a strong supporter of state intervention, Kohli

    (2004: 14), however, admits that Indian intervention lacked effectiveness: Fragmen-

    ted-multiclass states were neither more nor less interventionist than cohesive

    capitalist states, but they were less effective. . .

    tax-collecting capabilities were limited,

    136 E. Weede

  • 8/9/2019 Asian Journal of Political Science

    10/26

    public spending priorities included numerous goals other than growth promotion,

    attempts to direct credit easily evolved into cronyism . . ..

    Elsewhere, Kohli (2004: 219, 258) deplores the softness of the Indian state and

    tries to shift the blame for Indias poor economic performance until the 1990s from

    state planning to limited state capacity: The Achilles heel of Indian political economyis not so much its statist model of development as the mismatch between that statist

    model and the limited capacity of the state to guide social and economic change.

    Thereby, Kohli comes close to an endorsement of Olsons (1987) earlier and more

    general insight. Whatever ones view of state guidance of economies is, the required

    effective bureaucracies are certainly not the comparative advantage of most

    developing societies, India emphatically included. In this context, one also has to

    remember Lin et al. (2003) insight, according to which only the state, but no private

    capitalist, can pursue a comparative advantage-denying development strategy for

    long, as India has done and, given its overregulated labour market, still does to asignificant degree.

    Although permit-license-quota raj was rationalized by egalitarian concerns and

    socialist ideals, the poor did not benefit. According to Nilekani (2009: 19), it

    perversely promoted privatization for the privileged classes: The low standards of

    our state-run schools and our weak infrastructure have especially hurt the poor in

    terms of access: those of us who can afford alternatives merely opt out, turning to

    private schools, private electricity, and gated communities*or we emigrate, leaving

    behind rickety, nonfunctioning systems for the less fortunate to endure.

    Social security in India illustrates the concern for the poor*as practised, rather

    than merely rhetorical*

    perfectly. For the masses in the informal sector, social

    security simply does not exist. In old age they have to depend on support by their

    children. But the implied debt on civil service pensions amounts to 55 per cent of

    Indias GDP, in spite of covering only 24 million (out of more than a billion) people

    (Nilekani, 2009: 394).

    Expanding Economic Freedom, or Towards Creeping Capitalism

    Whereas China reformed its economy ahead of the bankruptcy of the Soviet model,

    India took its time. As Panagariya (2008: 96) and Lal (2008: 15) point out, there is alink between earlier Chinese and later Indian reforms. It was much easier for Indians

    to deny the policy relevance of the still earlier South Korean or Taiwanese economic

    miracles than of the Chinese miracle. One reason for this tardiness might be that

    independent Indias economy grew much better under Nehru than in the colonial

    period before it (Cohen, 2001: 95; Panagariya, 2008: chapter 2). As in China

    economic growth rates and productivity picked up in India during the 1980s. Since

    1980, GDP per capita has more than doubled (Bosworth and Collins, 2006: 1).

    There is a debate why this has happened. Growth in the 1980s has been explained

    by growing aggregate demand driven by soaring government deficits and a build-up

    of external debt which led to the crisis of the early 1990s and thereafter to liberalizing

    Asian Journal of Political Science 137

  • 8/9/2019 Asian Journal of Political Science

    11/26

    reforms (Ahluwalia, 2002; Lal, 2008). Or, it has been explained by the suspension of

    the governments hostility to the private sector in the 1980s (Rodrik and

    Subramanian, 2004: 3), by a pro-business orientation of the government resulting

    in fewer restrictions on capacity expansion for established industries, fewer price

    controls, and lower corporate taxes. These reforms were not yet pro-market or infavour of competition. They favoured incumbents rather than entrants to the market

    or consumers. Or, one may reject the distinction between pro-business and pro-

    market policies as artificial and insist on the economic freedom and market

    promoting character of the reforms, even though it was liberalization by stealth

    (Panagariya, 2008: chapter 4).

    Despite a rather strong growth record in the 1980s, these reforms did not suffice to

    prevent the crisis in 1991. Neither public finances nor the current account were

    sustainable. Public sector deficits rose. Foreign currency was in short supply and

    became ever more so. After the dissolution of the Soviet Union, the main source offoreign aid had disappeared. The reforms consisted of the following measures. Most

    of the industrial licensing system was abolished. Reluctantly, foreign investment was

    welcomed. The Indian currency was devalued. The dream of autarchy was given up.

    Tariffs were cut dramatically. Whereas the average rate was 125 per cent in 19901991,

    it became 71 per cent three years later. The peak rate fell from 355 per cent to

    85 per cent in the same period (Joshi and Little, 1998: 70). Until 20052006 it has

    fallen to 12.5 per cent (Nilekani, 2009: 71).

    Although the Indian economy did not switch as vigorously from inward to

    outward orientation and export promotion as China did, there was a lot of

    movement in the right direction. Since growth rates improved in the early 1990s,especially in manufacturing, since the current account deficit fell and foreign

    exchange reserves strongly recovered while the primary deficit of the central

    government fell, too, the liberalizing reforms paid off (Joshi and Little, 1998: 17,

    35). Given the poor record of Indian administrations in large-scale policy

    implementation, liberalization made sense because it implies some economizing on

    limited state capability (Pritchett, 2009: 33).

    But the Indian development pattern does not offer sufficient job opportunities to

    its labour force which is dominated by low-skilled workers (Bosworth et al., 2006:

    34). Most of Indias labour force is not even employed in the formal economy or theso-called organized sector. Out of a labour force of about 470 million people, 21

    million work for the government or public enterprises and merely 14 million for

    organized private enterprises. In the private part of the formal economy labour

    productivity is about nine times as high as it is outside the organized sector. Whereas

    manufacturing employed more than hundred million Chinese workers, it employed

    seven million Indians only at the beginning of the twenty-first century (Luce, 2006:

    4849).

    Whereas Chinas economic development started with agricultural reforms, then

    moved to low-cost manufacturing before climbing the value-added chain, India

    grows from the other end with a strong emphasis on capital and human capital

    138 E. Weede

  • 8/9/2019 Asian Journal of Political Science

    12/26

    intensive products and services (Luce, 2006: 38). The Economist (2007a: 70) claimed

    that the main difference in the growth performance of China and India is not the

    strength of Indias service sector, but the weakness of its manufacturing. According to

    Panagariya (2008: 288), the key barrier to the emergence of large-scale, unskilled-

    labour-intensive firms is the complex set of labour laws they face in India. Neithermuch higher pay in the formal part of the economy, nor perfect job security helps

    those who cannot find a formal job in rigid labour markets.

    In contrast to China, India had never abolished private property in land and

    private farming.14 Nevertheless, agriculture suffered from serious distortions.

    According to Joshi and Little (1998: 89), the prices of all major agricultural products

    have been largely determined by the central governments total control of foreign

    trade in them. The prices of cereals*rice, wheat, and coarse grains*and cotton have

    been held below world prices in most years by controlling exports. Although this

    specific problem has been mitigated or even overcome, subsidies for food, fertilizer,electricity, or water are more likely to assist well-to-do farmers than the poor.

    According to Panagariyas (2008: 361) estimate, only in between 4 and 18 per cent of

    the food subsidies reach the poor. Since subsidies, like labour market rigidities,

    distort market signals and reduce growth rates, one should concur with Panagariyas

    (2008: 77) conclusion that a focus on equity instead of economic freedom has had

    harmful effects on poverty alleviation in India.

    Compared to China, India seemsto possess some advantages. Because of the British

    heritage, India seems much closer to the rule of law than China.15 But Indias laws

    might not be adequate for a poor country. According to an entrepreneur, the impactof laws is questionable: The consequence of too many rules has obviously been that

    eeveryone has agreed to ignore them (Nilekani, 2009: 207).

    Moreover, the application of the law in India leaves much to be desired. Cohen

    (2001: 115) observed: In some states, it is difficult to separate the politicians from the

    criminals; in others, the police are under the sway of high and middle castes and are

    used to hunt down and kill lower-caste or tribal leaders in what are euphemistically

    called police encounters. Even in big cities property conflicts may still be settled by

    gangs of bullies rather than by courts of law (Kakar, 1996). Land titles seem to be

    a mess. According to Nilekani (2009: 358), 90 per cent of all land titles are disputed,

    and 30 per cent of all pending court cases concern land disputes. In 2006, 27 million

    legal cases waited for a judgment, murder cases included. About US$75 billion was

    tied up in these legal disputes (Luce, 2006: 9495).

    Problems of law enforcement reduce the impact of this presumed Indian

    advantage. Since Indian states are on the way to become more assertive, enterprising,

    and powerful, it is conceivable that they become engaged in a race to the top where

    they compete with each other in providing a good business environment. Federalism,

    Indian style may provide some hope for the future. So far, however, India benefits

    little from its putative advantage in the rule of law, but it still suffers from

    overregulation or the legacy of license-permit raj (FICCI, 1999: 165).

    Asian Journal of Political Science 139

  • 8/9/2019 Asian Journal of Political Science

    13/26

    According to The Economist (2005a: 14), Indian bureaucracy continues to slow

    things down . . . it takes 89 days to receive all the permits needed to start a business in

    India, compared with 41 in China. Insolvency procedures take ten years, compared

    with 2.4 in China. Or, take other examples from the information technology (IT)

    business. One of the co-founders of Infosys had to hang around in the lobby outsidea bureaucrats office for 18 days in order to change the port of arrival for some

    hardware import from Madras to Bangalore (Nilekani, 2009: 70). In another instance,

    Infosys had to apply for the permission to import some hard disk drive. When they

    finally got the license, capacity had doubled and the price was cut. But the import

    license had to be changed (Nilekani, 2009: 98).

    Tardiness of administration may undermine the advantages of the rule of law. In

    spite of such handicaps Indian IT businesses led the country towards globalization.

    According to Infosys co-founder Nilekani (2009: 123): Information technology

    services served as the Trojan horse through which globalization entered the Indianeconomy and gained acceptance. Unconstrained by Indias capital and infrastructure

    bottlenecks, the knockout growth of the sector in the years since the reforms showed

    how well world markets could work to Indias advantage. The important

    characteristics of globalization and openness are the expansion of economic freedom

    and the weeding out of apathy and inefficiency.

    The rule of law is related to an even broader issue: good governance. Most social

    scientists seem to believe that better governance leads to better economic

    performance. Econometric evidence from developing Asia does not provide much

    support for this idea (Quibria, 2006). There are at least two different explanations for

    this irritating finding. Either the proposition is false or the measurement ofgovernance is biased and afflicted with measurement error. This author is inclined

    towards the second explanation.16 After all, standard operationalizations of govern-

    ance are derived from Western examples and implicitly tend to assume that Western

    ways are the most efficient or best ways to govern. Possibly, this is an exaggerated

    assumption.

    Good governance is incompatible with high levels of corruption. In India

    corruption is endemic at all levels of government (Quah, 2008). It seems to have

    become worse over time. The legacy of permit-license-quota raj provides ample

    opportunities because civil servants administer or control a lot of activities, includinglucrative ones. Low salaries must generate some appetite for speed money or other

    kinds of illegal income. Moreover, the risk of detection and punishment is low

    because the police itself is understaffed and corrupt and the judicial process is

    characterized by delays. Neither the per capita expenditure nor the staff levels of the

    corruption fighting agency indicate sufficient political will for fighting corruption.

    Whatever ones general view about the effectiveness of state intervention in the

    economy and planning is, corruption certainly undermines it (Olson, 1987).

    Another widely acknowledged Indian advantage is the fact that most educated

    Indians, and all natural scientists, engineers, and economists, speak English fluently*

    very much in contrast to the modest foreign language skills of most Chinese. So, India

    140 E. Weede

  • 8/9/2019 Asian Journal of Political Science

    14/26

    should be in a position to acquire technology from the West much faster than China.

    Although the Indian elite enjoys an advantage in speaking English, education policies

    frequently worked against its preservation. The entrepreneur and co-founder of

    Infosys Nilekani (2009: 87) deplores that English was quite decisively marginalized

    everywhere. On average. . .

    less than 10 per cent of state schools in India were English-medium schools, and many of the states passed policies that allowed the teaching of

    English only from the sixth standard. Since the promotion of provincial languages or

    Hindi hurt the lower castes and the poor worst, a dalit activist complained: We have

    an English language economy, but our education policy has denied people access to it.

    It is not an intelligent law, its a political one (Nilekani, 2009: 88). Since even the poor

    have recognized the value of English for getting a well-paid job, private English

    medium schools are mushrooming in Indias slums and countryside.

    Whereas India lags China in primary education, it is still ahead in tertiary

    education. But one should not exaggerate the achievements of Indian universities. Onthe one hand, Indias pool of highly qualified graduates was still about twice as large

    as Chinas until recently (The Economist, 2006a: 28). On the other hand, one study

    estimates that 75 per cent of all Indian graduates are unemployable in their field of

    study (Nilekani, 2009: 326).

    India should raise its investment rate. Since household savings have strongly

    increased, the savings rate could support more investment (Bosworth et al., 2006:

    figure 2a). Actually, India seems to be well on the way towards raising investment. By

    contrast to China, there is little financial repression in India. But in infrastructure

    development India might lag a full decade behind China (Lal, 2008: 28

    29). Chinaspends about three times as much for it as India (Nilekani, 2009: 234). Since the

    Indian public sector already is deeply in deficit, this will be difficult. Some time ago,

    already 44 per cent of recurrent expenses in India serviced the public debt (The

    Economist, 2005a: 14). So, the legacy of past profligacy undermines Indias capability

    to improve its infrastructure. Whereas public debt was about a quarter of Chinese

    GDP, it amounted to 80 per cent of Indian GDP in 2005 (The Economist, 2007b: 66).

    Whereas Chinas government might have been in surplus in 2007, Indias total

    government deficits was close to 7 per cent of GDP (The Economist, 2008a: 72). In

    2008 the Indian deficit approached 10 per cent of GDP, in 2009 it is likely to be about

    12 per cent (The Economist, 2008b: 52; 2009e: 50). Estimates of Indian public debt go

    as high as 85 per cent of GDP, that is, much higher than those for China, Russia, or

    Brazil to whom India is frequently compared (The Economist, 2009e: 51).

    Although Indian public spending is frequently rationalized by the need to serve the

    poor, they benefit little. Subsidies on fuel or fertilizer are most useful for those who

    own vehicles or farm large plots of land. In Luces (2006: 89) evaluation, two-thirds of

    the nominally pro-poor subsidies in India benefit better-off groups. Moreover, until

    the first decade of the twenty-first century Indias government depended to a

    significant degree on customs duties, on barriers to trade and globalization.17 The

    state still makes money by restricting economic freedom.

    Asian Journal of Political Science 141

  • 8/9/2019 Asian Journal of Political Science

    15/26

    Whereas China has been one of the four most important trade partners of the US

    for a long time, India had to be satisfied with the 25th rank at the turn of the

    millennium (Cohen, 2001: 288; Sivasubramonian, 2002: 116). When China already

    was the third most important exporter of the world, behind Germany and the US, but

    ahead of Japan, India did not yet equal in importance even the Republic of China onTaiwan (The Economist, 2005c: 101). Of course, trade in manufactured goods is

    Chinas comparative advantage. India might have a comparative advantage in

    services, in particular in software exports.18 Moreover, the 2.5 million strong and

    affluent Indian-American community (Dhume, 2008: 27) of doctors, engineers,

    businessmen, and software experts may link India at least as closely to the United

    States as Sino-American trade does for China. Conceivably, Indian expatriates might

    contribute to Indias future globalization as much as Chinese expatriates have already

    done for China by direct foreign investment in the past.

    Certainly, there is little reason to doubt that more trade openness and globalizationshould help India. As Panagariya (2005: 14) has pointed out, before liberalizing its

    economy Indias per capita growth rate in the 1960s and 1970s was only 1.1 per cent.

    After modest liberalization in the 1980s and deeper liberalization in the 1990s, the

    record for these two decades improved to 3.8 per cent. It was 5.7 per cent in 2007

    2008 (World Bank, 2009: 378). Since 2000, Indian gross domestic product grew

    7.9 per cent per year (World Bank, 2009: 384).

    Although poor infrastructure, poor productivity, and bigger barriers to trade

    explain why India cannot repeat Chinas success in attracting foreign direct

    investment in order to compensate for the weakness of its domestic investment,India is remarkably successful in attracting foreign institutional investment (Nilekani,

    2009: 126). India seems to need foreign capital rather than foreign entrepreneurship.

    In spite of this mushrooming of entrepreneurship, economic freedom has not yet

    found a comfortable home in India. For 2007, Gwartney and Lawson (2009: 10, 109)

    rank the country 86 out of 141, that is, below the median.19 Regulation and

    deteriorating property rights are the components which do most to depress Indias

    freedom rating. But attitudinal obstacles against capitalism, free markets and

    globalization have been vanishing in India. According to a Pew Survey (The

    Economist, 2009a: 26), in no major country did faith in free markets exceed the

    Indian level or increase as much between 2002 and 2007. Whether politicians shall

    translate this permissive opinion climate into pro-growth policies or continue

    servicing rent-seekers remains to be seen.20

    In contrast to the West and most small poor countries, Indias and Chinas

    economies are rebounding even before a recovery in the West (The Economist,

    2009d: 60). Moreover, India benefits from the fact that trade in services is more

    resilient in the current crisis than trade in goods (The Economist, 2009f: 64). While

    India looked hopeless in the first three decades after its independence, now it seems

    to be rising. Moreover, the country benefits from a pervasive spirit of optimism.

    Previously, Indians worried about the difficulty of feeding their people. Currently

    142 E. Weede

  • 8/9/2019 Asian Journal of Political Science

    16/26

    they are proud of being a young nation in an aging world. The young population

    becomes an asset, a reservoir of skilled labour (Nilekani, 2009: 49).

    Interstate Rivalry and Domestic Instability

    So far, Indian advantages remain largely unexploited. Why did China reform its

    economy so much earlier and more forcefully than India did? Although an autocratic

    government may enjoy some advantages in this respect over a democracy, I tend to

    credit geopolitical factors with more influence than domestic politics. Here, I follow

    the guidance of Jones (1981; 1988: 177) who explained the European miracle by

    interstate rivalry: Competition for subjects and power among states and kings and

    nobles seems in the end to be the answer. It abridged the worst behaviour*not

    much, and only on average, but more than in other great societies of the world.

    Focusing on nationalism rather than on geopolitical considerations, Greenfeld (2001:

    218) makes a related point where she argues that nationalism and the view of the

    economy as a battlefield in the struggle for national supremacy provides much of the

    motivation for economic growth. As in Japan more than hundred years ago,

    nationalism in China might succeed in legitimating entrepreneurship, private

    property rights, and capitalism and thereby overcome the traditional contempt and

    lack of respect from which merchants suffered in the Confucian societies of East Asia.

    Rivalry between the Peoples Republic of China on the Mainland and the Republic of

    China on Taiwan, growing hostility between the Chinese and their fellow Commu-

    nists in the Soviet Union in the 1960s to 1980s, as well as the historical rivalry

    between China and Japan, and the geographical closeness of US troop deployments toChina forced the PRC leadership to consider the consequences of falling further and

    further behind the West, Japan, and Taiwan.

    The more privileged geopolitical location of India compared with China

    contributes to the explanation of the lateness and of the half-hearted character of

    Indian economic reforms. Although Indians had learned in the early 1960s*after

    suffering defeats in battles during the Himalaya War*that China might become a

    threat to their national security, the effect of this lesson was mitigated by the fact that

    both superpowers of the 1960s, the United States and the Soviet Union, favoured

    India over China. The dominant national security preoccupation of India remainedPakistan. Competing with Pakistan, or even fighting a successful war against it, as

    India had learned in the early 1970s when it dismembered Pakistan*or, if one prefers

    to put it that way: when it liberated Bangladesh*did not require a transformation of

    the Indian economy.

    China began its economic reforms at a time when it enjoyed little friendship abroad,

    but was surrounded by hostile neighbours, even the Soviet Union and Vietnam

    included among them. Foreign threats were the midwife of the European evolution

    towards economic freedom and capitalism centuries ago (Jones, 1981; 1988; Weede,

    1996; 2000; 2009). In the late 1970s, foreign threats were the midwife of Chinas

    expansion of economic freedom (from an extremely low base) and creeping capitalism,

    Asian Journal of Political Science 143

  • 8/9/2019 Asian Journal of Political Science

    17/26

    too. Conceivably, the already visible rise of China helped to persuade Indians of the

    usefulness and necessity of reforming and liberalizing their economy in the early 1990s.

    India has been affected by turmoil and insurgencies (Mitra, 2006). In the late

    1940s, India incorporated the principality of Hyderabad and most of Kashmir. Since

    the mid-1950s there have been insurgencies in the north-east by Nagas, Mizos, andAssamese. Scattered through time and place there have been Communist uprisings

    and terrorist incidents. In the 1980s, there was a major ethnic-religious uprising in

    Punjab. Since the 1990s there is renewed fighting in Kashmir. None of the domestic

    uprisings ever came close to success. But a Maoist or Naxalite insurgency continues

    in many states of the union. If they should ever capture political power, economic

    freedom would be tightly restricted and growth would deteriorate or stop. During the

    first six months of 2009, it claimed about 450 lives (The Economist, 2009d: 65).

    In 2002, there was a mass murder of Muslims in Gujarat which some observers

    even call genocide (Nussbaum, 2007). Although it is not widely known in the West,Indian Islam has not gone untouched by the jihadist trends in neighbouring Pakistan

    and Bangladesh. Indeed in recent years more civilians have been killed in India as a

    result of Islamic terror than in any other country aside from war-torn Afghanistan

    and Iraq (Dhume, 2008: 29). The multiple terrorist attacks at ten different locations

    in Mumbai, the financial capital of India, in late November 2008 resulting in nearly

    two hundred deaths are only the most recent and worst terrorist incidents in India

    (Prasannarajan, 2009: 34). Being poor and a fractionalized society, by ethnicity as well

    as by religion, or caste, India is predisposed to suffer from insurgencies and civil wars.

    Its readiness to give a voice to minorities, even to empower them, fits a democracy

    well, but such a humane approach to diversity may exact a price. According to arecent cross-national study of civil war (Jacobsen and de Soysa, 2009: 137), state

    policies that dis-empower people under conditions of high fractionalization actually

    reduce the chance of civil war. India seems to be too democratic to stabilize itself by

    recourse to repressive means.

    Like China, India suffered from a recent history of violence and war (Small and

    Singer, 1982; Gleditsch et al., 2002). India has fought four wars against Pakistan, one

    against China, and it captured the former Portuguese colony of Goa by force. In

    addition, it unsuccessfully intervened in the Sri Lanka Civil War in the late 1980s.

    Although Indias most persistent foreign conflict, the protracted hostility with Pakistan,has not been solved, India had established its supremacy by dismembering Pakistan and

    making Bangladesh into an independent state in 1971. Therefore, one may argue that

    the worst foreign challenges to India are historical rather than current concerns.

    About 30 years after the Chinese precedent, India became a nuclear weapon power

    in the late 1990s. The Himalayan border issue which led to the 1962 war has not

    yet been solved. In the west, China controls Aksai Chin, but India still claims it. In

    the east, India controls Arunchal Pradesh but China still claims it. Although both

    sides seem to have little interest in reviving the border conflict, a settlement is not in

    sight either. By contrast, China has settled almost all other land border conflicts,

    frequently by making substantial concessions to weaker neighbouring states (Fravel,

    144 E. Weede

  • 8/9/2019 Asian Journal of Political Science

    18/26

    2005; 20072008). Moreover, China has been a persistent supporter of Pakistan, even

    delivering nuclear and missile technology (Cohen, 2001: 259).

    It is likely that the future big three in the global economy will be the United States,

    China, and India (Kugler, 2006).21 All of them already are nuclear weapon powers.

    Sooner or later, international politics is likely to become dominated by relations withinthis triangle of powers. Following Collins (1986) geopolitical theory, one should expect

    that the most centrally located power is likely to be isolated. Since the United States

    alone is not located in Eurasia, it enjoys the most peripheral location. It can choose

    whether it wants to favour China or India. Since China is stronger than India and likely

    to remain so for decades to come,22 geopolitical realism makes one predict that the

    United States favours India over China. In Mearsheimers (2001: 4) words: China and

    the United States are destined to be adversaries as Chinas power grows.

    The American preference for India over China has been well expressed (and

    promoted) by a former American ambassador to India who has advocatedsubordinating nuclear non-proliferation concerns to cooperation between America

    and India as well as reinforcing Indian military power. Blackwill (2005: 10) wrote: In

    my view, the United States should try to integrate India into the evolving global non-

    proliferation regime as a friendly nuclear weapons state. And he asked the rhetorical

    question: Why should the United States want to check Indias missile capability in

    ways that could lead to Chinas permanent nuclear dominance over democratic India?

    During the second half of the twentieth century, the United States usually enjoyed

    more cordial relations with Pakistan than with India. Following the ascent of India

    American perceptions of both countries changed. Tellis (2008: 23) advocatesclassifying India as the larger and more strategically important country and

    Pakistan as a troubled country teetering repeatedly on the brink of failure. Tellis

    (2008: 36) prescription for Pakistan in its historic rivalry with India comes close to

    pre-emptive surrender: Pakistan would have to make its peace with India on what are

    essentially the only sustainable terms over the long run, namely, those that reflect the

    differential in relative power. If global US interests would best be served not simply

    by respecting the natural evolution of the balance of power in South Asia but rather

    by accelerating it through a committed buildup of Indias national capabilities (Tellis,

    2008: 31), then one should consider the repercussions of such a policy not only

    on Pakistan, but on China as well.23 At best, the Chinese must regard such

    considerations and subsequent policies as containment by stealth.

    One may raises the question whether it is wise for the United States and India to

    contain China, to encircle it. According to Lind (2007: 14), an anti-Chinese alliance

    of the US, Japan, and India would be to launch a cold war of choice. How many

    more cold wars between nuclear-armed powers can mankind survive? Fortunately,

    Indians do not seem to be inclined to join the Americans in an effort to contain

    China. Moreover, China has become Indias most important trade partner (The

    Economist, 2009b: 54). In the past, the expansion of economic freedom, economic

    interdependence and trade ties significantly reduced the risk of war between nations

    Asian Journal of Political Science 145

  • 8/9/2019 Asian Journal of Political Science

    19/26

    (Gartzke, 2005; 2007; 2009; McDonald, 2007; Russett and Oneal, 2001; Weede, 2005a,

    2010).24

    Admittedly, there is also something like the democratic peace. The risk of war

    between democracies is extremely small. But one should conceptualize the

    democratic peace as a component of the capitalist peace, because democraciesprosper best in wealthy countries,25 because capitalism or economic freedom and

    thereby globalization contribute to prosperity (Weede, 2005a; 2006). Moreover, the

    democratic peace is simply not applicable throughout Asia, because it merely pacifies

    relations between democracies. It neither pacifies Sino-Western, nor Sino-Indian

    relations. By contrast, economic freedom, and the capitalist peace built on it,

    promises a much better foundation for Asian security.

    Conclusion: Economic Freedom, Growth and Peace

    Historically, growth has depended on the establishment and expansion of economic

    freedom. Economic freedom implies limited government and respect for private

    property rights. As Austrian economists (Hayek, 1945; 1960; Mises, 1920) have

    argued, private property rights and economic freedom are essential in order to

    achieve an efficient allocation of resources and to exploit widely dispersed knowledge.

    By contrast, centralized political decision-making permits a comparative advantage

    denying development strategy (Lin et al., 2003). In traditional India, the Hindu caste

    system restricted economic freedom by linking legitimate work to a status which was

    inherited from ones parents. Muslim rule brought sultanism and arbitrary

    government which was incompatible with safe property rights for producers andmerchants. Whereas the fragmentation of political power in Europe forced competing

    kings and princes in Europe to concede property rights and economic freedom to

    subjects, political fragmentation in southern India did not exert such a beneficial

    impact because many political units were much less persistent than European ones.

    Economic freedom and private property explain why the West could ever overtake

    Asia,26 why small Britain could ever conquer and rule much bigger India. The

    determinant of limited government, economic freedom and safe private property

    rights in the West is interstate competition or European disunity.

    Once the West had become developed and much richer than Asia, potentialadvantages of backwardness were established. Poor countries could borrow

    technologies and institutions from richer ones, thereby benefiting from the earlier

    and greater degree of economic freedom elsewhere. Of course, limited government,

    economic freedom and secure private property rights at home remained useful. The

    socialist inclinations of the long dominant Congress Party lead to permit-license-

    quota raj and the corresponding Hindu rate of growth until the early 1990s. Since

    then economic freedom within India and Indian participation in international trade

    has expanded. Growth has picked up. India could delay the liberalization and

    opening up of its economy longer than China because it was not threatened by major

    powers, like the United States or the Soviet Union. Only when neighbouring China

    146 E. Weede

  • 8/9/2019 Asian Journal of Political Science

    20/26

    began its miraculous rise, Indians began to recognize the benefits of expanding

    economic freedom.

    As hiring and firing regulations in labour markets demonstrate (Gwartney and

    Lawson, 2009: 109), India still has a long way to go. Indias growth potential remains

    insufficiently exploited. Since rising powers tend to challenge the political status quo,it is good luck that the two demographic giants rising Asia seem to prosper under

    global capitalism. Therefore, the strong economic ties between the United States,

    China and India hold some promise for the future and survival of mankind.

    Economic freedom is simultaneously compatible with the rise of Asia and its peaceful

    management.

    Notes

    [1] Of course, such statements depend on definitions. In Bhallas view, a daily income between

    10 and 40 US-dollars makes one a member of the global middle class.

    [2] Although the rise and decline of nations has historically been associated with threats to

    peace, I am optimistic about our chances of accommodating the rise of China and India

    (Weede, 2005a).

    [3] Of course, bureaucratic guidance looked attractive to Indians, because of the British heritage.

    As Huntington (1968) and Kohli (2004) point out, the British built a much more effective

    administrative service in India than they did in some of their African colonies, like Nigeria.

    Unfortunately, however, affirmative action for the benefit of backward tribe, low-caste and

    untouchable (or dalit) Indians must have undermined the quality and effectiveness of the

    bureaucracy. In 1990, 49 per cent of central government positions were set aside for these

    groups (van Praagh, 2003: 201).

    [4] According to Gwartney and Lawson (2009: 3), the key ingredients of economic freedom are

    personal choice, voluntary exchange coordinated by markets, freedom to enter and compete

    in markets, protection of persons and their property from aggression by others. Since 1980,

    economic freedom data is available for a large and increasing number of countries.

    Operationally, economic freedom assesses size of government (preferably small), security of

    property rights, sound money, freedom to trade internationally, and regulation (preferably

    limited).

    [5] My description of the caste system is admittedly extremely superficial. I do not elaborate the

    distinction between varna, i.e., the classical four castes, and jati. There might be about two or

    three thousand of the latter. Caste duties refer to jati. Whether a jati is a part of one or

    another varna may be contested, if a jati becomes richer or more powerful, or if it tries to

    become cleaner. The latter process is called sanskritization. Details like these and sources are

    provided in Chapter 6 of my book on Asia (Weede, 2000).

    [6] Savakar himself even has been an atheist (Devare, 2009). Whereas atheism is obviously

    incompatible with being a Jew, Christian, or Muslim, being an atheist, however, is

    compatible with being a Hindu. Most Hindus are neither monotheists nor atheists, but

    polytheists.

    [7] Of course, not all entrepreneurs have a bania caste background. Since many Brahmins have

    earned degrees in the natural sciences or engineering, many high-tech entrepreneurs are

    Brahmins.

    [8] The choice of planning and import substitution by many poor countries, including China

    and India, has two important roots. One was the spirit of the time (1950s and 1960s) and the

    tendency of development economists to exaggerate market failure and to overlook state

    Asian Journal of Political Science 147

  • 8/9/2019 Asian Journal of Political Science

    21/26

    failure. The second is the desire to achieve national security by heavy industrialization,

    autarchy, and, at least in the Chinese case, building a strong army.

    [9] Actually, one might even refer to a double advantage of backwardness. The first of these

    advantages refers to the well-known potential for much higher growth rates in poor or less

    developed than in rich countries. The second one of these advantages refers to the fact that

    the same real income today buys much lower infant mortalities, better nutrition or cleanerwater, and higher life expectancies than it did for the West at an earlier stage of economic

    development (Goklany, 2007: chapters 2 and 3, 409).

    [10] Although this is an article on Indian economic development rather than a comparison

    between Chinese and Indian economic performance, some comparisons between India and

    China are useful in order to highlight what was possible in the global context of the time.

    Here, China provides a much better yardstick than, say, Russia or South Korea. By contrast

    to resource-rich and sparsely populated Russia, India is comparatively resource-poor and

    densely populated. By contrast with South Korea, India (like China) is a demographic giant.

    South Korean economic achievements merely suggested that the global economy was open

    enough for small countries to benefit from an export-oriented growth strategy. China

    demonstrated that a huge and populous nation can repeat the success story.[11] Unfortunately, teachers are a politically influential group in India. Because of poor

    public schooling, an increasing number of students get a private education. Whether private

    schools are officially recognized or not, their students usually outperform state-educated

    students. But some poor families may have to pay one quarter of their income in school fees

    (Nilekani, 2009: 183, 188, 194). Absenteeism is even worse in Indian public health services

    than in Indian schools (Panagariya, 2008: chapter 19). It has been estimated that more than

    85 per cent of all patients choose private health care, including even a large proportion of

    very poor people (Nilekani, 2009: 375).

    [12] My work builds on Weber (1923/1981) and Jones (1981; 1988), on Smith (1776/1976), Mises

    (1920), and Hayek (1945, 1960).

    [13] An earlier attempt by the World Bank (1995: 90) to assess this effect estimated at least 18 percent. Workers in big enterprises earned a multiple of agricultural wages, in steel production

    eight times as much (World Bank, 1995: 76, 83).

    [14] Legal titles to land are poorly documented in India. Records are incomplete and fragile

    (Panagariya, 2008: 323).

    [15] As Kohli (2004) points out, the British built a much more effective administrative service in

    India than they did in some of their African colonies, like Nigeria. Unfortunately, however,

    affirmative action for the benefit of backward tribe, low-caste and untouchable (or, dalit)

    Indians must have undermined the quality and effectiveness of the bureaucracy. In 1990, 49

    per cent of central government positions were set aside for these groups (van Praagh, 2003:

    201). According to Peerenboom (2007: 166), violations of physical integrity rights in India

    appear to be more severe than in China

    quite in contrast to what one might expectconcerning the different human rights performance of democracies and autocracies.

    [16] Seldadyo et al. (2007) report a positive relationship between good governance and growth

    after reducing the impact of measurement error by confirmatory factor analysis.

    [17] The Economist (2005a: 15) once estimated that tariffs accounted for about one sixth of the

    tax revenue.

    [18] Information technology (IT) and IT-enabled services employed less than a million people in

    2004 and accounted for about 4 per cent of the Indian GDP. By 2007, these numbers might

    grow to 4 million people and 7 per cent of GDP. The value of IT-related exports might triple

    in three years (The Economist, 2005b: 69).

    [19] According to Gwartney and Lawson (2008: 18), however, what seems most important is not

    so much moving from an intermediate degree of freedom to very much more, but to avoid

    extreme restrictions of freedom.

    148 E. Weede

  • 8/9/2019 Asian Journal of Political Science

    22/26

    [20] Possibly, one should question these survey results. Survey responses frequently depend on

    framing the questions. Nilekani (2009: 272280) complains that reforms or privatization are

    still less popular than inclusive growth or swadeshi which is close to autarchy.

    [21] This expectation depends on pessimism about Europe. Elsewhere (Weede, 2005b) I have

    explained why Europe should be discounted as a major power.

    [22] Since China is greying significantly faster and much earlier than India, India has anopportunity to outperform China after the 2020s.

    [23] Not only Americans, but also neutral observers (Mohan, 2008) perceive the link between US

    support for India and balancing the rise of China. Whether the similarities between the

    worlds greatest democracies facilitate their cooperation, remains to be seen.

    [24] Trade depends not only on political barriers, but also on distance and transportation costs,

    on the size and complementarity of economies. Therefore, measures of trade and measures of

    the avoidance of protectionism need not have the same impact on peace. See McDonald and

    Sweeney (2007).

    [25] Of course, India is a well-known exception to this generalization. On the general proposition

    linking prosperity or the level of economic development and democracy, see Burkhart and

    Lewis-Beck (1994), Lipset (1994), and Przeworski et al. (2000). For criticism of this untilrecently widely accepted link, see Acemoglu et al. (2008). In Acemoglus view, (capitalist)

    institutions made prosperity as well as democracy possible. For a warning against premature

    democratization, see Heller (2009).

    [26] The link between the expansion of economic freedom and growth has been supported by

    econometric studies (de Haan and Sturm, 2009; Doucouliagos and Ulubasoglu, 2008;

    Gwartneyet al., 2006; Liu, 2007; Weede, 2006). What remains disputed is whether economic

    freedom as such or its improvement exerts the stronger impact on growth, whether the

    relationship between economic freedom and growth is linear or merely monotonic

    (Gwartney and Lawson, 2008: 18). Establishing some economic freedom seems to be more

    important than approaching perfection.

    References

    Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., Robinson, J. A. and Yared, P. (2008). Income and democracy, American

    Economic Review, 98(3): 808842.

    Ahluwalia, M. S. (2002). Economic reforms in India since 1991: has gradualism worked? , Journal of

    Economic Perspectives, 16(7): 6788.

    Anand, S. and Segal, P. (2008). What do we know about global income inequality? Journal of

    Economic Literature, 46(1): 5794.

    Andreski, S. (1968). Military Organization and Society. 2nd edn. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

    Barro, R. J. and Sala-i-Martin, X. (1995). Economic Growth. New York: McGraw-Hill.

    Bhagwati, J. N. (1993). India in Transition. Oxford: Clarendon.Bhalla, S. S. (2002). Imagine Theres No Country: Poverty, Inequality and Growth in the Era of

    Globalization. Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics.

    Blackwill, R. D. (2005). The India imperative, The National Interest, 80: 917.

    Bosworth, B. and Collins, S. M. (2006). Accounting for Growth: Comparing China and India.

    Washington, DC: Brookings.

    Bosworth, B., Collins, S. M. and Virmani, A. (2006). Sources of Growth in the Indian Economy.

    Washington, DC: Brookings.

    Burkhart, R. E. and Lewis-Beck, M. S. (1994). Comparative democracy: the economic development

    thesis, American Political Science Review, 88(4): 903910.

    Cohen, S. P. (2001). India. Emerging Power. Washington, DC: Brookings.

    Collier, P. and Dollar, D. (2002). Globalization, Growth and Poverty. New York: Oxford University

    Press (for the World Bank).

    Asian Journal of Political Science 149

  • 8/9/2019 Asian Journal of Political Science

    23/26

    Collins, R. (1986). Weberian Sociological Theory. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    De Haan, J. and Sturm, J.-E. (2009). Is the IMF right? How robust is the relationship between

    market-oriented institutions and policies and economic growth? in P. Graeff and G.

    Mehlkop (eds), Capitalism, Democracy and the Prevention of War and Poverty. Abingdon, UK:

    Routledge, pp. 108134.

    Devare, A. (2009). Secularizing religion: Hindu extremism as a modernist discourse, InternationalPolitical Sociology, 3(2): 156175.

    Dhume, S. (2008). Is India an ally?, Commentary, 125(1): 2530.

    Dollar, D. and Kraay, A. (2002). Spreading the wealth, Foreign Affairs, 81(1): 120133.

    Doucouliagos, C. and Ulubasoglu, M. A. (2006). Economic freedom and economic growth,

    European Journal of Political Economy, 22(1): 6081.

    Dreze, J. and Sen, A. (1998). Economic Development and Social Opportunity. Delhi: Oxford

    University Press.

    Economist, The (1997). Survey: Indias economy. The Economist 342, No. 8005, 22 February.

    Economist, The (2005a). Survey: the tiger in front, The Economist 374, No. 8416, 5 March.

    Economist, The (2005b). The Bangalore paradox, The Economist375, No. 8423, 23 April, pp. 6769.

    Economist, The (2005c). Top exporters, The Economist 375, No. 8423, 23 April, p. 101.Economist, The (2006). The great Indian hope trick, The Economist 378, No. 8466, 25 February,

    pp. 2628.

    Economist, The (2007a). Economic focus: reading the tea leaves, The Economist 382, No. 8513, 27

    January, p. 70.

    Economist, The (2007b). India on fire, The Economist 382, No. 8514, 3 February, pp. 6567.

    Economist, The (2008a). Asian budget finances: poles apart, The Economist 386, No. 8567, 16

    February, p. 72.

    Economist, The (2008b). Indias economy. Turning sour. The Economist 38, No. 8591, 2 August,

    pp. 5253.

    Economist, The (2009a). Government versus market in America: the visible hand. The Economist

    391, No. 8633, 30 May, pp. 25

    27.Economist, The (2009b). Does the elephant dance? The Economist 391, 8634, 6 June, p. 54.

    Economist, The (2009c). BRICs, emerging markets and the world economy: not just straw men,

    The Economist 391, No. 8636, 20 June, pp. 6062.

    Economist, The (2009d). Indias Naxalites. A ragtag rebellion. The Economist 391, No. 8637, 27

    June, pp. 6566.

    Economist, The (2009e). Indias budget. Hopes suspended, The Economist 392, No. 8639, 11 July,

    pp. 5051.

    Economist, The (2009f). Unpredictable tides, The Economist 392, No. 8641, 25 July, pp. 6364.

    FICCI (1999). Indian Business through the Ages. Delhi: Oxford University Press.

    Firebaugh, G. (1999). Empirics of world income inequality, American Journal of Sociology, 194(6):

    1597

    1630.Fravel, M. T. (2005). Regime insecurity and international cooperation: explaining Chinas

    compromises in territorial disputes, International Security, 30(2): 4683.

    Fravel, M. T. (20072008). Power shifts and escalation: explaining Chinas use of force in territorial

    disputes, International Security, 32(3): 4483.

    Gartzke, E. (2005). Freedom and peace, in J. D. Gwartney and R. A. Lawson (eds), Economic

    Freedom in the World. Vancouver, BC: Fraser Institute, and Potsdam: Liberales Institut der

    Friedrich-Naumann-Stiftung, pp. 2944.

    Gartzke, E. (2007). The capitalist peace, American Journal of Political Science, 51(1): 166191.

    Gartzke, E. (2009). Production, prosperity, preferences, and peace, in P. Graeff and G. Mehlkop

    (eds), Capitalism, Democracy and the Prevention of War and Poverty. Abingdon, UK:

    Routledge, chapter 4.

    150 E. Weede

  • 8/9/2019 Asian Journal of Political Science

    24/26

    Gleditsch, N. P., Wallensteen, P., Eriksson, M., Sollenberg, M. and Strand, H. (2002). Armed

    conflict 19462001: A new data set, Journal of Peace Research, 39(5): 61537.

    Goklany, I. M. (2007). The Improving State of the World. Why We Are Living Longer, Healthier, More

    Comfortable Lives on a Cleaner Planet. Washington, DC: CATO Institute.

    Goldstone, J. (2008). Why Europe? The Rise of the West in World History, 15001850. New York:

    McGraw-Hill.Greenfeld, L. (2001). The Spirit of Capitalism. Nationalism and Economic Growth. Cambridge, MA:

    Harvard University Press.

    Gwartney, J. D., Holcombe, R. D. and Lawson, R. A. (2006). Institutions and the impact of

    investment on growth. Kyklos, 59: 255273.

    Gwartney, J. D. and Lawson, R. (2008). Economic Freedom of the World: 2008 Annual Report.

    Vancouver, BC: Fraser Institute, and Potsdam: Liberales Institut.

    Gwartney, J. D. and Lawson, R. (2009). Economic Freedom of the World: 2009 Annual Report.

    Vancouver, BC: Fraser Institute, and Potsdam: Liberales Institut.

    Hayek, F. A. von (1945). The use of knowledge in society, American Economic Review, 35(4): 519

    530.

    Hayek, F. A. von (1960). The Constitution of Liberty. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.Heller, M. G. (2009). Capitalism, Institutions, and Economic Development. Abingdon, UK:

    Routledge.

    Helpman, E. (2004). The Mystery of Economic Growth. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press

    (Belknap).

    Huntington, S. (1968). Political Order in Changing Societies. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Jakobsen, T. G. and de Soysa, I. (2009). Give me liberty, or give me death! State repression, ethnic

    grievance and civil war, 19812004. Civil Wars, 11(2): 137157.

    Jones, E. L. (1981). The European Miracle. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Jones, E. L. (1988). Growth Recurring. Oxford: Clarendon.

    Joshi, V. and Little, I. M. D. (1998). Indias Economic Reforms 19912001. Delhi: Oxford University

    Press.Kakar, S. (1996). The Colors of Violence: Cultural Identities, Religion, and Conflict. Chicago: The

    University of Chicago Press.

    Kohli, A. (2004). State-Directed Development: Political Power and Industrialization in the Global

    Periphery. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Kugler, J. (2006). The Asian ascent: opportunity for peace or precondition for war?, International

    Studies Perspective, 7(1): 3642.

    Lal, D. (1998). Unintended Consequences: The Impact of Factor Endowments, Culture, and Politics on

    Long-Run Economic Performance. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Lal, D. (2004). India, in P. Bernholz and R. Vaubel (eds), Political Competition, Innovation and

    Growth in the History of Asian Civilizations. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar, pp. 128141.

    Lal, D. (2008). An Indian economic miracle?, CATO Journal, 28(1): 11

    34.Landes, D. S. (1998). The Wealth and Poverty of Nations. New York: W.W. Norton.

    Levine, R. and Renelt, D. (1992). A sensitivity analysis of cross-country growth regressions,

    American Economic Review, 82: 942963.

    Levine, R. and Zervos, S. J. (1993). What have we learned about policy and growth from cross-

    country growth regressions?, American Economic Review, 83: 426430.

    Lin, J. Y., Cai, F. and Li, Z. (2003). The China Miracle: Development Strategy and Economic Reform.

    Hong Kong: The Chinese University Press.

    Lind, M. (2007). Beyond American hegemony, The National Interest, 89: 915.

    Lipset, S. M. (1994). The social requisites of democracy revisited, American Sociological Review,

    59(1): 122.

    Liu, L. (2007). Wirtschaftliche Freiheit und Wachstum. Munster: Lit-Verlag.

    Luce, E. (2006). In Spite of the Gods: The Strange Rise of Modern India. London: Little, Brown.

    Asian Journal of Political Science 151

  • 8/9/2019 Asian Journal of Political Science

    25/26

    McDonald, P. J. (2007). The purse strings of peace, American Journal of Political Science, 51(3):

    569582.

    McDonald, P. J. and Sweeney, K. (2007). The Achilles heel of liberal IR theory? Globalization and

    conflict in the pre-World War One era. World Politics, 59(3): 370403.

    Maddison, A. (1998). Chinese Economic Performance in the Long Run. Paris: OECD.

    Maddison, A. (2001). The World Economy: A Millennial Perspective. Paris: OECD.Maddison, A. (2007). Contours of the World Economy, 12030 AD. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Majumdar, S. K. (1998). Assessing comparative efficiency of the state-owned, mixed and private

    sectors in Indian industry, Public Choice, 96(12): 124.

    Mearsheimer, J. J. (2001). The Tragedy of Great Power Politics. New York: Norton.

    Mises, L. von (1920). Die Wirtschaftsrechnung im sozialistischen Gemeinwesen, Archiv fur

    Sozialwissenschaft und Sozialpolitik, 47(1): 86121.

    Mitra, S. K. (2006). Engaging the world: the ambiguity of Indias power, in S. K. Mitra and B. Rill

    (eds), Indias New Dynamics in Foreign Policy. Munich: Hanns Seidel Foundation, pp. 734.

    Mohan, C. R. (2008). Indias quest for continuity in the face of change, Washington Quarterly,

    31(4): 143153.

    Nilekani, N. (2009). Imagining India: Ideas for the New Century. London: Penguin (Allen Lane).North, D. C. (1990). Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. New York:

    Cambridge University Press.

    Nussbaum, M. C. (2007). The Clash Within: Democracy, Religious Violence, and Indias Future.

    Cambridge, MA: Belknap (Harvard University Press).

    Olson, M. (1987). Diseconomies of scale and development, CATO Journal, 7(1): 7797.

    Olson, M. (1996). Big bills left on the sidewalk: why some nations are rich, and others poor,

    Journal of Economic Perspectives, 10(2): 324.

    Panagariya, A. (2005). Miracles and debacles: do free-trade skeptics have a case? Federal Reserve

    Bank of Dallas. Available at: http://www.dallasfed.org/news/research/2004/04global_panagar

    iya.pdf

    Panagariya, A. (2008). India: The Emerging Giant. New York: Oxford University Press.Peerenboom, R. (2007). China Modernizes: Threat to the West or Model for the Rest? New York:

    Oxford University Press.

    Prasannarajan, S. (2009). The terrorist: pronoun of evil, India Today, 5 January, pp. 2635.

    Pritchett, L. (2009). Is India a failing state? Detours on the four lane highway to modernization,

    Harvard Kennedy School RWP09-013.

    Przeworski, A., Alvarez, M. E., Cheibub, J. A. and Limongi, F. (2000). Democracy and Development.

    Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Quah, J. S. T. (2008). Curbing corruption in India: an impossible dream?, Asian Journ