51
An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the award of the Master of Law and Business (“MLB”) Degree Teresa Wittgenstein July 24, 2013 14.436 words Supervisor 1: Prof. Dr. Ralf Fendel Supervisor 2: Mr. Iraj Ispahani

An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    4

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

An Economic Perspective on the Race-to-

the-bottom in International Labour

Standards

A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in

partial fulfillment of the requirements for the award of the Master of Law and Business

(“MLB”) Degree

Teresa Wittgenstein July 24, 2013

14.436 words

Supervisor 1: Prof. Dr. Ralf Fendel

Supervisor 2: Mr. Iraj Ispahani

Page 2: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

i

TABLE OF CONTENTS

Table of Contents……………………………………………………………………………. i

List of Abbreviations………………………………………………………………………… ii

List of Figures ………………………………………………………………………………. iii

1. INTRODUCTION………………………………………………………………..…… 1

2. BACKGROUND………………………………………...…………………………….. 4

2.1 International labour standards: a historical overview……………………………..…. 4

2.2 International labour standards: definition and scope……………………………….... 6

2.3 Labour standards in the globalised economy………………………………………... 7

3. CORE LABOUR STANDARDS AND COMPETITIVENESS…………...………... 9

3.1 Regulatory competition: the prisoner’s dilemma……………………………….…… 9

3.2 Trade and resources: the Heckscher-Ohlin model………………………………….... 11

3.2.1 Reasons to choose the Heckscher-Ohlin model and relevant assumptions……... 11

3.2.2 Free trade equilibrium: respect of ILO core labour standards………………...… 12

3.2.3 Free trade equilibrium: decline in core labour standards in country H………..... 13

3.2.3.1 Child labour and forced labour……………………………………………... 13

3.2.3.2 Employment discrimination…………………………….………………….. 16

3.2.3.3 Freedom of association and collective bargaining…………………………. 19

4. RACING TO THE BOTTOM OR CLIMBING TO THE TOP? …………………... 21

4.1 Empirical evidence…………………………………………………………………... 21

4.2 Theoretical literature……………………………………………………………….... 22

4.3 Market-driven mechanisms………………………………….………………………. 24

4.3.1 Ethical consumerism……………………………………..……………………... 24

4.3.2 Trade and income convergence…………………………..……………………... 26

5. CASE STUDY: EVIDENCE FROM CHINA………………………………………... 27

5.1 China’s economic integration…………………………………..……………………. 27

5.2 Regress or progress? ………………………………………………………………… 29

5.3 Racing to the bottom…………………………………………………….…………... 29

5.4 Climbing to the top……………………………………………………….….………. 31

5.4.1 Trade and export diversification……………………………………..….………. 31

5.4.2 Ethical supply chain management……………………………………..………... 32

5.5 China and the ILO core labour standards………………………………….………… 34

6. CONCLUSION AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS…………..………………………. 36

Bibliography…………………………………………………………………………………. 39

Page 3: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

ii

List of Abbreviations

ACFT All China Federation of Trade Unions

CPC Communist Party of China

CSR Corporate social responsibility

FDI Foreign direct investment

GATT General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade

ILO International Labour Organisation

IOE International Organisation of Employers

ITO International Trade Organisation

ITUC International Trade Union Confederation

OECD Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development

PRC People’s Republic of China

SOE State-owned enterprises

UN United Nations

US United States

WTO World Trade Organisation

Page 4: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

iii

List of Figures

Figure 1: Systems competition illustrated in terms of the prisoner’s dilemma……………… 10

Figure 2: Trade and welfare effects of child/ prison labour – country H……………………. 14

Figure 3: Trade and welfare effects of child/ prison labour – country F……………………. 15

Figure 4: Trade and welfare effects of discrimination – country H…………………………. 18

Figure 5: Trade and welfare effects of discrimination – country F………………………….. 19

Page 5: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

1

1. INTRODUCTION

The integration of national economies through trade, capital flows and the international

movement of workers is a phenomenon frequently termed as economic globalisation (Bhagwati

2007). Rapid integration of the global economy began in the final decades of the 19th century,

facilitated by improvements in communication and transportation. Advances such as the

telephone, the steamship and the railroad greatly intensified the volume of trade, investment

and outward expansion (Feenstra and Taylor 2011).

During the interwar period, globalisation was interrupted by economic downturn and

rising trade barriers (Bhagwati 2007). Post-war liberalisation of commerce and investment led

to a resumption of the dynamics set in motion at the end of the 18th century. Especially the

second half of the 19th century witnessed the pace of globalisation accelerating, as hostility in

many of the developing countries turned to the progressive embrace of the market mechanism

(Steger and Roy 2010). While previous integration was primarily advanced by technological

innovations in transportation and communication, “today’s most dramatic change is the degree

to which governments have intervened to reduce obstacles to the flow of trade and investments

worldwide” (Bhagwati 2007, p.11)

Although the current phase of globalisation has been advanced first and foremost by

changes in political strategy, the pace of technological progress has continued unabated (Singh

and Zammit 2004). With resources such as capital becoming increasingly footloose, countries

are now more than ever exposed to both opportunities and threats emanating outside their

control (Eglin 2001). Following Mosley and Uno (2007), “the standardisation of manufactured

commodities, the liberalisation of trade in manufactures, and the decline in long-distance

transportation costs have facilitated the development of global production networks” (p.927).

Multinational corporations may retain ownership of facilities within the global production

network by foreign direct investment (FDI) or may generate subcontracting and outsourcing

relationships with firms in distant countries. As competitive pressures have exacerbated, a

country’s ability to manufacture products at low costs is central to determining the extent of its

participation in the world market.

Lawrence et al. (1996) provide “as international competition has intensified, firms,

workers, and citizens have become increasingly aware that different national policies have

international effects” (pp.4-5). Subsequently, in recent years there appears to be a public

backlash evolving against globalisation (Sanyal 2001). Discontent translates into the perception

that neoliberal globalisation is the cause of a race-to-the-bottom in a whole host of economic

and social policies in which governments seek to attract mobile resources and access to lucrative

Page 6: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

2

markets. As explained by Klevorick (1996), “at the heart of the race-to-the-bottom argument is

the view that the competitive process among firms is imperfect” (p.460). Concerns about unfair

competition and an associated erosion of standards have been expressed in the arenas of

taxation, environmental regulation, and more recently labour standards (Davies and

Vadlamannati 2013). Few debates have been as controversial as the nexus between international

commerce and labour rights. While it is unambiguous that standards respond to the opening of

trade, conceptually speaking, the relationship between labour conditions and trade remains

ambivalent.

Importantly, anti-globalisation sentiments are expanding among developed countries.

Governments, workers, unions, as well as parts of the business sector blame intensified

competition, stemming primarily from less developed trading partners, as the basis for

diminishing labour standards in their own countries (Sanyal 2001). In consequence, pressures

for fair trade as an alternative model to neoliberal globalisation have intensified, rooted in both

social and economic concerns. As Lawrence et al. (1996) stipulate, “once markets and

competition are global there is a strong case for the rules defining fair competition” (p.5). One

response to these misgivings has been the call for tying recognised basic labour standards to the

multilateral trading system. In terms of the analysis of Polanyi (1944), the introduction of a

social dimension to trade is necessary to ensure that prosperity is generated on socially

acceptable terms.

While globalisation critics fear the competitive erosion of labour standards, their fixing

in multilateral agreements is a similarly contentious issue (Singh and Zammit 2004). To trade

economists, used to the general idea that gains from commerce stem from differences between

countries rather than from uniformity, the demand for harmonisation sounds suspicious.

Globalisation enthusiasts are concerned that the promotion of rules tied to the international

trading system might become a pretext for protectionism, denying countries access to

international markets. Following Casella (1996), “as markets continue to integrate and tariff

barriers are progressively eliminated, the political debate has shifted to differences in standards

and regulations as possible instruments of markets protection and of trade distortion” (p.119).

Despite the fact that labour standards have taken on a high profile in contemporary

policy debates, to date, there have been few comprehensive studies analysing the impact trade

liberalisation exerts on labour practices. This paper is devoted to filling this void, contributing

to the discussion by systematically investigating the race-to-the-bottom hypothesis. The labour

standards discussed are those set out by the core conventions of the International Labour

Organisation (ILO), embodying consensus on a subset of practices that ought to be recognised

Page 7: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

3

globally, irrespective of a country’s stage of development (Hasnat 2002). Although there

appears to be agreement among the major protagonists that these standards need to be upheld

for social as well as economic reasons, heated debate about the appropriate mechanisms to

ensure protection continues unabated. This paper will thus analyse the arena in which

internationally applicable labour standards ought to be established, arguing that market access

will play a vital role in improving a country’s labour conditions.

This paper begins with a review of the social and historical background in which labour

standards were fashioned, locating the current debate in the broader perspectives on economic

globalisation. It must be emphasised that in sketching the historical context, developments that

are peripheral to the main theme are necessarily omitted. Chapter three goes on to examine the

analytical underpinnings of the race-to-the-bottom argumentation, setting the stage for the

theoretical critique. Extending the Heckscher-Ohlin model in its basic version to incorporate

labour standards, it will be demonstrated that while countries can improve their competitiveness

in producing and exporting labour-intensive goods through strategically repressing their

domestic labour standards, the resulting market allocation does not necessarily occur to the

detriment of the economic welfare of the country’s trading partners. However, enforceable

labour standards will be vital to ensure that the benefits of globalisation are spread evenly. As

explained by Elliott and Freeman (2003), “labour standard are a way to balance the interests of

workers and capital within countries and in the world economic system. This balance, in turn,

is an essential element in building public support for continued globalisation” (p.11).

Chapter four examines both the theoretical and empirical literature on the race-to-the-

bottom argumentation. It will be shown that globalisation has altered the incentive structures

for both governments and the business sector alike, fostering market-driven demand for labour

standards. The fifth chapter applies the preceding analysis to China’s recent market reforms.

Following the race-to-the-bottom hypothesis, trade liberalisation and progressive market

engagement since the late 1970s should have culminated in the competitive erosion of China’s

labour standards. The case study will demonstrate that the interaction between trade and labour

standards is complex and multifaceted, giving rise to countervailing forces.

A review of this length is necessarily selective. As such, the following analysis can

only provide a flavour of the main dynamics in the discussion. Pressures for improved labour

conditions are deeply rooted in social and humanitarian concerns and the notion that labour

standards need to be maintained cannot be disputed on moral premises. While fully recognising

the various dimensions to the discussion, this paper focuses first and foremost on the associated

economic argumentation.

Page 8: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

4

2. BACKGROUND

2.1 International labour standards: a historical overview

The modern evolution of labour standards begins in England in the late 19th century as an

attempt to mitigate the human and social costs accompanying the potent combination of rapid

industrialisation and laissez-faire liberalism (Engerman 2003). Before the deepening of market

forces, workers and families relied on the church, landowners, and local authorities to support

them in times of illness, unemployment, or other hazards. However, “these institutions proved

to be insufficient in the wake of the industrial revolution that brought with it new kinds of

exposures and risks” (Huberman 2012, p.4). Threats emanated primarily from the development

of the factory system and the agglomeration of industry in urban centres where workers found

themselves isolated from established social networks (Huberman 2012).

As observed by a contemporary, George Campbell, the Eighth Duke of Argyll, “during

the [nineteenth century] two great discoveries have been made in the science of government:

the one is the immense advantage of abolishing restrictions on trade; the other is the absolute

necessity of imposing restrictions on labour” (Campbell 1867, p.367). Much support of free

trade was contingent on the adoption of complementary labour regulations to provide assurance

against trade’s more brutal reality. Consequently, historically, labour standards are seen as a

precursor to greater and more direct state intervention (Huberman 2012).

Early initiatives for improved labour conditions stemmed primarily from philanthropic

and intellectual movements among bourgeoisie reforms and activists (Haworth and Hughes

1997). As Huberman (2012) stipulates, “because these reforms required cross-class support, the

argument had a political dimension” (p.2). From the early 19th century, a growing nexus of

countries introduced national labour standards, although most practices were only implemented

at the turn of the century. Development was internal and limited to the respective country, with

legislation formulated by the sovereign state (Engerman 2003).

The movement to coordinate labour standards internationally was set in motion at the

end of the 19th century. Engerman (2003) explains that “to have any chance of being effective,

international standards require bilateral or multilateral agreements or else acceptance of policies

set by some form of international agency” (p.31). The predecessor of the American Federation

of Labour, the Federation of Organised Trades and Labour Unions, urged the United States

(US) Congress in 1881 to adopt legislation providing “American industry full protection from

the cheap labour of foreign countries” (cited in Charnovitz 1987, p.568). In 1890 similar

concerns prompted the German Emperor William II to order a reluctant Bismarck to convene

Page 9: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

5

an international conference to build support for the establishment of international labour

standards (Manhaim 1934). International encompassed only Western Europe, nations that are

geographically proximate and with similar social traditions and economic development levels,

while distant colonial labour markets were outside the scope of applicable legislation

(Engerman 2003).

As examined by Brown (2001), “the international labour rights agenda broadened

dramatically at the end of World War I with the creation of the ILO” (p.90). The ILO was

established in 1919 as part of the implementation of the Treaty of Versailles and as a result of

the League of Nations. To date, it is the only international organisation that is not purely

intergovernmental in its governing structure, with unions and employers being represented in

its tripartite executive body (Sanyal 2001). The ILO’s primary activity is to negotiate and

promulgate conventions which, when ratified, bind the respective country to uphold these goals

(Bazillier 2008). During this process, the ILO provides guidance and technical advice, relying

on voluntary compliance and cooperation (Golub 1997).

The Great Depression of the 1930s, followed by the outbreak of World War II,

hindered further efforts to integrate international trade and labour standards. Following World

War II and the subsequent development of the present international trading system, cooperation

on the regulation of labour practices resumed new importance, with the ILO becoming an

agency of the United Nations (UN) (Engerman 2003). The 1944 Declaration of Philadelphia

had expanded the mandate of the ILO to include all nations, irrespective of development status.

The Declaration reaffirmed the legislative objectives of the Versailles mandate but gave formal

recognition to the role economic policies were to play in post-war social development and

labour welfare (Haworth and Hughes 1997). This readjustment aligned the ILO to the social

provisions of the 1941 Atlantic Charter, which called for “the fullest collaboration between all

nations in the economic field with the object of securing for all improved labour standards,

economic advancement and social security” (cited in Alcock 1971, p.165).

Agreement on the need for international labour legislation in any post-war peace treaty

was established by the 1947 UN Conference on Trade and Employment and was prompted by

three factors: first, increasing intra-European competition as European economies initiated

post-war reconstruction; second, enhanced international competition stemming from the new

industrial might of the US and rapid Japanese industrialism; thirdly, the persistent call for

linking economic policy and social justice (Haworth and Hughes 1997). The mandate of the

stillborn International Trade Organisation (ITO), as enunciated in 1947 by the Havana Charter,

was expansive on labour standards. Article VII stated that “unfair labour conditions,

Page 10: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

6

particularly in production for export, create difficulties in international trade, and, accordingly,

each member shall take whatever action may be appropriate and feasible to eliminate such

conditions within its territory” (cited in Lawrence et al. 1996, p.38). However, attempts to

formally include labour standards into the architecture of the post-war trading regime as

established by the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) were unsuccessful. The

GATT virtually ignored the issue of labour practices, except for Article XX(e), prohibiting trade

in goods produced from slave or prison labour (Charnovitz 1987).

As impediments to international trade became dismantled, particularly since the 1970s,

a group of advanced countries, supported by their respective trade unions and constituencies of

their business sector, resumed a vocal campaign at the GATT for adopting a formal role in

commanding adherence to labour practices in its member states (Eglin 2001). The sources of

concern are both social and economic, with demanded standards being based on key human

rights norms. Developed countries perceive themselves to be at a growing disadvantage, unable

to compete against countries whose production costs are depressed artificially through the

absence of enforceable labour standards. Attempts to formulate a so-called social clause

permitting trade sanctions to be levied against nations failing to comply with basic standards

have been unsuccessful in all eight rounds of trade negotiations under the auspices of GATT

(Srinivasan 2004). At the GATT ministerial meeting in Marrakech in 1994, the debate was

passed to its assessor, the World Trade Organisation (WTO) (Haworth and Hughes 1997).

2.2 International labour standards: definition and scope

This paper acknowledges that labour standards are multifaceted, “depending on the stage of

development, per capita income, political, social, and cultural conditions and institutions”

(Stern and Terrell 2003, p.3). Notwithstanding the fact that codified labour standards largely

depend on national circumstances, international consensus has been reached on a subset of

standards that ought to be recognised globally, irrespective of a country’s economic

fundamentals (Hasnat 2002).

Some of the voices calling a social floor to international trade were calmed by the ILO

Declaration on Fundamental Principles and Rights at Work. The Declaration, which was

adopted unanimously by the International Labour Conference in June 1998, is regarded as

indicating international agreement on a limited number of labour standards which should be

applied worldwide (Singh and Zammit 2000) . As stated by Palley (2004), such standards, “are

very much in the spirit of rights and stand independent of a country’s stage of economic

development” (p.23). Eight fundamental ILO conventions, general grouped into four categories

Page 11: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

7

referred to as the ILO core labour standards, form the basis of consensus among ILO

constituencies (Norton 2003):

i) Freedom of association and the effective recognition of the rights to collective

bargaining (Conventions 87 and 98);

ii) Elimination of all forms of forced or compulsory labour (Conventions 29 and 105);

iii) Effective abolition of child labour (Conventions 138 and 182); and

iv) Elimination of discrimination in respect of employment and occupation

(Conventions 100 and 111).

ILO involvement is generally limited to cases where countries have ratified the

respective convention. The labour standards addressed in the ILO Declaration, however, are

binding on all ILO member states by virtue of their membership in the ILO (Singh and Zammit

2004). However, this paper recognises that in the broader discussion on globalisation and labour

practice, the rights being referred to extend beyond the aforementioned standards. These relate

to acceptable working conditions and include considerations such as minimum wages, working

hours, occupational safety and health practices in the workplace (Stern 2000). Such labour

standards are set in statute law, since they are “labour market interventions that are clearly

contingent on the stage of development” (Palley 2004, p.23).

The International Organisation of Employers (IOE) (2006) finds that “the narrowing

of the issue to fundamental or core labour rights as contained in the ILO’s core conventions and

the Declaration has made the entire labour/ trade debate less divisive” (p.1). However, the ILO’s

institutional structure and supervisory mechanism are criticised for lacking both credibility and

enforcement power, implying that the adoption of the Declaration is not necessarily an

appropriate indicator for a country’s labour conditions (Elliott and Freeman 2003). With no

ability to offset national sovereignty through punitive trade measures, the ILO has a mixed

record of success in imposing its core labour standards.

2.3 Labour standards in the globalised economy

As the foregoing analysis has shown, the labour standards agenda has proliferated both in terms

of scope and breadth and labour standards continue to be among the more controversial issues

in contemporary global policy debates (Engerman 2003). The debate rests firmly in the wider

discussion on the implications of globalisation, and “the drive for harmonisation of labour

standards is part of a broader trend towards deeper integration” (Golub 1997, p.14).

Page 12: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

8

Demand for coordinating labour standards has been growing with the globalisation

process. Singh and Zammit (2000) explain “the pressure from groups militating in favour of a

link between labour standards and trade has become particularly intense as developing countries

have increased their capacity to produce and export manufactured goods and increased their

share of world trade in manufactures” (p.3). Subsequently, in recent years a coalition of trade

unions, labour representatives, employers, human rights activists and governments, primarily

from developed countries, has argued that exploitative labour practices conducted by their

major trading partners culminate in a race-to-the-bottom in labour conditions worldwide as

alternative production sites compete for mobile capital and global markets (Stern 2000).

According to Martin and Maskus (2001), the sources of concern are threefold: firstly,

there are altruistic concerns for workers in poor countries. Secondly, weak and inadequately

enforced standards are viewed as unfairly enhancing national competitiveness. Finally,

globalisation critics argue that the sustainability and legitimacy of commerce itself might be

eroded if human rights are not protected properly. While fully recognising the social and moral

dimensions, this paper focuses first and foremost on the associated economic argumentation.

Without a strict observation of certain universally applicable labour standards, “it is alleged that

exploitive practices in many low-wage exporting countries artificially depress labour costs,

leading to unfair competitive advantage in world markets and thereby to a downward pressure

on labour standards in rich countries” (Lawrence et al. 1996, p.36). The process arguably results

in inefficient resource allocations and reduced welfare, with distributional impacts being a

subset of these concerns.

A near-consensus has been reached by the major protagonists to focus international

efforts on the ILO core labour standards in order to place a floor under the treatment of workers

that is irrespective of a country’s development status (Leary 1996). While some progress has

been made, the extent of agreement is frequently overstated and there remains less than

universal adherence to the ILO’s core conventions. To date, there is little agreement on the

appropriate mechanisms to ensure protection and enforcement of these standards. While it is

unambiguous that standards respond to the opening of trade, conceptually speaking, the

relationship between labour practices and trade is ambiguous. Globalisation enthusiasts argue

that trade openness, rather than culminating in a race-to-the-bottom, will have positive effects

on labour rights, with public awareness, consumer demand and economic growth stimulating

economic and market-driven improvements in labour practices (Haworth and Hughes 1997).

Alternatively, debates about the inclusion of a social clause and with it the enforcement

of labour standards backed by trade sanctions into the mandate of the WTO have been resumed

Page 13: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

9

by developed countries and free-trade critics (Elliott and Freeman 2003). The analytical appeal

of selecting the WTO derives from the organisation’s powerful and authoritative position in

adjudicating disputes and imposing punitive trade measures on its members via its dispute-

settlement mechanism (Moran 2002).

The WTO has been hesitant to approach this issue in a comprehensive fashion and thus

far, attempts to place labour practices at the centre of multilateral trade agreements have been

resisted on both technical and political terms (IOE 2006). However, the issue is likely to be on

the agenda of any future set of multilateral trade talks. In some countries, simultaneous

pressures are building up for unilateral action. The US has, for example, recently negotiated

trade sanctions for violations of labour standards in several of its unilateral trade initiatives

(Golub 1997). The enforcement of international labour standards is perhaps one of the few

debates continuing to split constituencies along the North-South divide.

3. CORE LABOUR STANDARDS AND COMPETITIVENESS

3.1 Regulatory competition: the prisoner’s dilemma

As part of the broader phenomenon of globalisation, a heightened concern about the impact of

international trade on labour standards pursued by national governments has emerged. Much

opposition rests on the assumption that globalisation leads to a socially undesirable race-to-the-

bottom by which nations compete for scarce resources and lucrative markets through repressing

their labour standards for terms of trade purposes. Following Brown (2001), “trade with

countries in which labour is protected poorly may create an incentive to lower wages in

industrialised countries and weaken existing labour law in order to maintain competitiveness in

international trade” (p.89). Thus, globalisation arguably precludes fair competition, culminating

in an inefficient allocation of resources and welfare reductions. According to Palley (2004),

“the incentives to lower standards are likely to become exacerbated as international trade

becomes a larger proportion of economic activity, because the payoff from obtaining

competitive advantage is greater” (p.27).

The reference to a race-to-the-bottom resulting from competition among countries

suggests that the problematic outcomes are due to failures in the interactions among states,

failures external to any one country (Klevorick 1996). The argument is that the pattern of

incentives motivating the choice of labour standards has the structure of a prisoner’s dilemma

game, “in which each country has an individual incentive to adopt low labour standards, but all

nations could benefit from a coordinated choice of higher labour standards” (Brown 2001,

pp.100-101). Originally framed in 1950 by the scientists Merrill Flood and Melvin Dresher, the

Page 14: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

10

dilemma was later interpreted by A.W. Tucker and is now the most famous and analysed game

in game theory.

The prisoner’s dilemma serves as a catalyst for structuring research concerned with

strategic decision-making in situations where no single player has full control over the

outcomes (Kelly 2003). It is thus well suited to analyse collective actions issues associated with

the setting of national standards. The pathological incentive structure generating regulatory

competition is provided in Figure 1. Assuming the simplest possible example involving two

trading partners, home (H) and foreign (F) have the choice to either maintain (M) or lower (L)

labour standards. The best possible payoff for each country individually is to lower labour

standards, while the other country maintains its labour standards. The second best result is

mutual cooperation, followed by mutual defection, while the worst possible outcome is reached

when one country cooperates, with its trading partner defecting. Thus, in a prisoner’s dilemma,

the payoff structure for country H can be ranked as follows: LM > MM > LL > ML.

Lowering labour standards is a dominant strategy for both H and F, “a strategy that

yields the best outcome for an individual regardless of what anyone else does” (Kollock 1998,

p.185). The non-cooperative outcome where both H and F lower their labour standards is the

only Nash equilibrium of the standard setting interaction, with each country maximising its

payoffs given what the other country does (Ostrom et al. 1994). The dominant strategies

culminate in a deficient equilibrium with inefficient levels of standards, since the collective

payoff of H and F is maximised when both countries cooperate to maintain standards. While

both countries would benefit from mutual adherence, every individual country has an incentive

to disregard standards for reasons of strategic competitiveness. Subsequently, international

coordination is unstable, with both countries tempted to deviate from it to attain short-term

benefits. Kollock (1998) explains “social dilemmas are situations in which individual

Page 15: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

11

rationality leads to collective irrationality. That is, individually reasonable behaviour leads to a

situation in which everyone is worse off than they might have been otherwise” (p.183).

At the heart of the argument is the view that the competitive process among firms is

imperfect. In this context, the race-to-the-bottom hypothesis can be described as an externality

of weak labour practices in one country for labour in the country’s trading partners (Singh and

Zammit 2004). One response to this misgiving has been that coordination failure justifies

international intervention such as to enforce mutually beneficial cooperation. As noted by

Palley (2004) “owing to the pattern of private incentives, in the absence of binding labour

standards, the global economy will only support the equilibrium in which both countries lower

standards” (p.27).

3.2 Trade and resources: the Heckscher-Ohlin model

In the early 20th century, the Swedish economists Eli Heckscher and Bertil Ohlin put forward a

model intending to explain the large increase in international trade they had witnessed in their

own lifetimes. As noted by Booth (1995), “history informs the development of theoretical

models” (p.12). Heckscher and Ohlin believed that the new ability to transport machines

quickly and cheaply set in motion a convergence of technologies across countries (Feenstra and

Taylor 2011). The basis for explaining trade patterns is instead rooted in differences in national

factor endowments, the degree to which an economy is relatively endowed with resources such

as land, capital, and labour (Hill 2011). In essence, a country will have a comparative advantage

in producing goods that are intensive in its abundant factor, while importing goods that make

intensive use of factors that are locally scarce.

3.2.1 Reasons to choose the Heckscher-Ohlin model and relevant assumptions

The Heckscher–Ohlin framework has particular strengths in examining whether lax labour

standards provide countries with an unfair competitive advantage to increase production and

exports. As initially demonstrated by Busse (2002) and expanded on below, an association

between labour standards and relative factor endowments exists. Following Lawrence et al.

(1996), “analytically, most cases of low labour standards can be thought of as an enlargement

of the effective labour supply in the country concerned” (p.40). The Heckscher-Ohlin model is

based on the assumption that trade patterns emerge from differing factor endowments and it is

thus well suited to analysing polices affecting an economy’s relative supply of resources.

Nonetheless, this paper recognises that additional factors influence competitiveness, including

differences in institutional context and technology (Costinot 2009).

Page 16: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

12

Moreover, the Heckscher-Ohlin framework is convenient since it allows for a

differentiation between factors of production, including skilled and unskilled labour. Although

oversimplified, modelling developing countries as primarily trading in manufactures is

commonly used in the literature (Golub 1997). It is evident that such a view is simplistic, failing

to explain inter-industry as opposed to merely intra-industry trade. This paper acknowledges

that capital mobility and the increasing ease of technology and knowledge transfer have

culminated in more complex and sophisticated export structures, with countries shifting to more

knowledge-intensive products as they integrate further into the world economy. However, these

trends have been deliberately omitted and the following analysis is limited to a simple scenario

such as to focus on the interaction between labour standards, production, and trade, as

incorporated in the broader discussion surrounding globalisation’s welfare effects.

In designing the Heckscher-Ohlin framework in its basic version, this paper assumes

a world comprising of two countries, each of which produces two goods by using two factors

of production. As aforementioned, production technologies are identical across the countries.

Moreover, there are no market distortions such that both production factors can move without

friction between industries. Similarly, final outputs can be traded without any restrictions.

However, production factors are assumed to differ in their abundance between nations and are

not able to move across borders. Consumer tastes are homogenous, and preferences don’t vary

with a country’s income level. Finally, constant returns to scale exist in both nations.

While the assumptions on which the Heckscher-Ohlin model is based have been

criticised for being unrealistic, they allow the preceding analysis to focus on a single reason for

trade, namely the differences in resource endowments between countries. As noted Leamer

(1995) “the Heckscher-Ohlin model is empirically useful because it helps us to understand

important aspects of the patterns of international trade” (p.3).

3.2.2 Free trade equilibrium: respect of ILO core labour standards

Assume country H (home) is relatively more abundant in unskilled labour compared to country

F (foreign). Good A (e.g., shoes) is intensive in unskilled labour, while good B (e.g., computers)

is intensive in skilled labour. Both countries produce each good, but given the above

assumptions, H is capable of producing relatively more shoes than computers, while the

opposite holds for F. This translates into comparative advantages and a general trade pattern:

country H should specialise in manufacturing shoes and country F should specialise in

producing computers. Each country’s production possibility frontier (PPF), defined as the

maximum amount of goods that can be produced given the country’s production factors, will

Page 17: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

13

be convex. H’s PPF is skewed in the direction of A to reflect H’s greater capability of producing

good A, as shown in Figure 2. Similarly, F’s PPF, as outlined in Figure 3, is skewed in the

direction of good B. Consumer tastes are graphed using indifference curves (ICs), the selection

of productss that consumers view as being equally desirable. Since preferences are assumed to

be homogenous across nations, ICs have the same shape in country H and F.

Suppose country H and F trade with each other and fully comply with ILO core labour

standards. Due to international commerce, consumption lies outside each country’s PPF along

the free-trade world price line P with the slope PA/PB. As illustrated in Figure 2, H will

manufacture at point Q1 and consume at C1, where the highest utility IC1 is contained. Since

country H is abundant in unskilled labour, it will export good A and import good B. The

corresponding points at which F produces and consumes are Q3 and C3, respectively. Modelled

in Figure 3, country F will export skilled-labour-intensive good B, import good A, and reach

utility IC3. Since both countries are able to consume outside their individual PPF and reach a

higher IC, trade is mutually beneficial.

3.2.3 Free trade equilibrium: decline in core labour standards in country H

In assessing the perceived trade-off between higher labour standards and greater

competitiveness, this paper distinguishes between the four ILO core standards. As will be

demonstrated, from a theoretical point of view, the implications of repressing core labour

standards vary with the type of standard.

3.2.3.1 Child labour and forced labour

Consider an economy-wide decline in labour conditions in country H, caused for example by a

lowering of the minimum age of employment. This occurs either because H pursues national

policies that effectively reduce the working age, or because existing legislation is enforced

incomprehensively. Employing child labour will increase H’s total endowment of unskilled

labour. Similarly, employment of involuntary or prison labour will likely increase H’s unskilled

labour endowment, with most studies finding low levels of education and incarceration to be

correlated (Lochner and Moretti 2002). Subsequently, H improves its competitiveness in the

manufacture of unskilled-labour-intensive shoes.

As illustrated in Figure 2, H’s PPF pivots to PPF2, with a bias toward good A.

Assuming that H is large enough to affect world price, the enhanced endowment of A causes

PA and thus P to drop to P’, representing a decline in H’s terms of trade. Modelling the impact

of labour standards in this fashion is an extension of the techniques begun by Rybczynski

(1955). Following Rybczynski (1955), “an increase in the quantity of one factor will always

Page 18: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

14

lead to a worsening in the terms of trade, or the relative price, of the commodity using relatively

much of that factor” (p.340).

Country H attains a higher welfare level IC2, producing at point at Q2 and consuming

at point C2, with exports of A and imports of B increasing. Rybczynski (1955) explains,

“assuming that the maintenance of the same rates of substitution in production after the quantity

of one factor has increased must lead to an absolute expansion in production of the commodity

using relatively much of that factor, and to an absolute curtailment of production of the

commodity using relatively little of the same factor” (pp.337-338).

Note that the worsening in H’s terms of trade could potentially counteract the

economy’s enhanced welfare stemming from growth in its unskilled labour force. This

phenomenon is termed immiserising growth, as coined by Bhagwati in 1958. Bhagwati (1958)

postulates “economic expansion increases output which, however, might lead to a sufficient

deterioration in the terms of trade to offset the beneficial effect of expansion and reduce the real

income of the growing country” (p.201). According to Palley (2004) there is a vicious cycle

dimension to this process, with falling prices and declining terms of trade compelling

developing countries to export even more, thereby compounding the problem.

Page 19: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

15

Following the reduction in labour standards in H, country F experiences an alteration

in the relative price level from P to P’. Since F is a net importer of good A, a decline in PA

culminates in an improvement in its terms of trade. F will subsequently allocate its resources

further toward the manufacture of B as signified by its new production point Q4 and both exports

and imports increase, graphed in Figure 3. At the new consumption point C4, country F

consumes more of both goods and consequently reaches a higher welfare level at IC4.

As provided by Elliott and Freeman (2003) “forced labour and child labour increase

the supply of labour and could be used to increase low-wage exports” (p.17). Taking the

possibility of immersing growth into account, countries may improve their comparative

advantage in the production of unskilled-labour-intensive goods following the non-conformity

with internationally recognised basic labour standards. However, this does not necessarily occur

to the detriment of the overall economic welfare of the country’s trading partner, because what

will transpire are beneficial terms of trade for the developed country. In neoclassical economic

fashion, the Heckscher-Ohlin framework concludes that differing national systems of labour

protection are compatible with mutual gains from trade, with commerce compensating for the

uneven distribution of productive resources around the world (Leamer 1995). This stands in

Page 20: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

16

contrast to the allegations made by globalisation critics and pressure groups from developed

countries, arguing that exploitive practices in exporting countries culminate in reduced welfare.

However, gains from trade are likely to be distributed unevenly within each country,

unless a redistribution of income will occur. According to the Stolper-Samuelson theorem, an

increase in the relative price of a product will enhance the earnings of the production factor

used extensively in the manufacture of that product and reduce the earnings of the second factor

(Stolper and Samuelson 1941). Subsequently, the theorem predicts that child labour and forced

labour will lower real wages of unskilled workers in both countries.

Consequently, the Heckscher-Ohlin model is particularly successful in explaining the

political economy of anti-globalisation sentiments stemming from certain groups in developed

countries. As Brown et al. (1996) outline, “it will be in the interest of particular groups of

producers within these countries to press for higher standards” (p.236). Increased domestic

inequality fuels backlashes from policy makers, workers, and trade unions and calls for

protectionism are manifestations of these concerns. It is within the context of these

controversies that the debate about internationally enforceable labour standards is best

understood. Subsequently, suitable domestic transfers and redistribution programs are an

essential element in building public support for continued globalisation. The current situation

represents an ironic reversal of the dynamics of the 1960s and 1970s when most developing

countries were perusing import-substitution policies to redress the alleged economic unfairness

of the international trading system (Bhagwati 2007).

This paper recognises that in the foregoing analysis, child and prison labour merely

have the effect of increasing production possibilities, as labour standards are not modelled to

affect the utility function (Busse 2002). However, pressures for fair trade are also rooted in

social and humanitarian concerns and that labour standards need to be maintained is not

disputed on moral premises (de Wet 1995). Prison labour and child labour are emotive subjects

and the debate surrounding these issues is charged with moral content. Moreover, as noted by

Elliott and Freeman (2003), while leading to lower costs and increased exports of low-skilled

goods in the short run, forced and especially child labour are detrimental to a country’s long-

term development, muting human capital acquisition. These effects, however, are beyond the

scope of this paper.

3.2.3.2 Employment discrimination

Employment discrimination encompasses both unequal opportunities as well as unequal

treatment, based on gender, race, ethnicity, national origin, religion or political opinion (Palley

Page 21: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

17

2004). Common forms include restrictions on female labour in particular industries, as well as

lower compensation relative to male workers. Both forms of discrimination will culminate in a

reduction of the economy’s work force, as women are either coerced to or will voluntarily

redress from work (Busse 2002).

However, the effect such discrimination has on the relative abundance of unskilled

labour is ambiguous (Busse 2002). There is evidence that despite the improvement of

educational opportunities, women in developing countries continue to receive less education

than men. The 2012 World Development Report on Gender Equality and Development finds

that despite continuous progress, primary and secondary schooling for girls remains

significantly lower than for boys for disadvantaged populations (World Bank 2012). Women

therefore continue to be overrepresented in unskilled jobs and discrimination against females

in country H will then lead to a reduced relative endowment of unskilled labour.

As stipulated by Brown et al. (1996) , “how a standard affects output and trade depends

on the factor intensity of the standard itself – that is, the ratio of the factors withdrawn from

tradable production as a result of the standard – in comparison to the factor intensity of the

tradable goods” (p.248). Assuming that discrimination against females withdraws relatively

more unskilled labour, H’s PPF will shift inward to PPF2, with an increased biased toward good

B, and country H reduces its comparative advantage in the manufacture of good A. This process

causes P to rise to P’, as shown in Figure 4, representing an increase in H’s terms of trade.

However, owing to the reduced amount of production factors, the economy produces at Q2 and

consumes at C2, thus reaching a lower level of welfare at IC2.

Page 22: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

18

Following the reduction in labour standards in H, country F experiences a change in the

relative price level from P to P’. Since F is a net importer of good A, a rise in PA culminates in

a deterioration in its terms of trade. This dynamic will make the production of B less profitable

compared to that of good A, with F shifting its production toward good A. Following the decline

in labour standards, F will produce at Q4 and both exports and imports decrease, as indicated in

Figure 5. At the new consumption point C4 country F consumes less of both goods, reaching a

lower welfare level IC4.

Page 23: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

19

3.2.3.3 Freedom of association and collective bargaining

Over the past decades, there has been an expansive development of the economic analysis of

unionised labour markets, quantifying the impact trade unions have on a host of labour market

outcomes. Alison Booth (1995), a leading researcher in the field, gave some structure to this

burgeoning body of literature, finding that basic trade union rights have ambivalent effects on

labour endowment. Following Addison and Hirsch (1989), “controversy continues to surround

the nature and direction of union effects on economic performance” (p.72). The effects of

unionisation will depend on institutional labour market characteristics across countries.

Booth (1995) distinguishes between two faces of unionism – the monopoly role of

unions, and their possible efficiency-enhancing role. The monopoly face represents the

orthodox textbook approach to unionised environments, with unions arguably introducing

further distortions into the labour market, primarily by pressing wages for unionised workers

above market levels. According to her argument, “the standard view of trade unions is that they

are organisations whose purpose is to improve the material welfare of members, principally by

raising wages above the competitive wage level” (Booth 1995). Leonard (1992) finds that

Page 24: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

20

unionisation will lead to greater rigidities and union wage gains will generally come to the

detriment of employment levels.

However, under some circumstances unions can be productivity-enhancing. As

stipulated by Booth (1995), “although unions may cause wages to increase in the union sector,

neither employment nor firms’ higher labour costs may be offset by opposing union effects on

productivity” (p.9). Much impetus behind this debate stems from the analysis of Freeman and

Medoff (1984), who outline productivity and efficiency gains stemming from better social

relations at the workplace, more efficient governance structures and subsequently higher

motivation and lower turnover. According to this argument, a unionised labour market would

pivot the PPF outward, but not necessarily with a bias toward unskilled labour.

Subsequently, it is evident that unions play a direct role in employment dynamics.

Depending on the relative size of the opposing effects, wages and the abundance of unskilled

labour could either rise or fall following the repression of basic union rights. As noted by Elliott

and Freeman (2003), “the effects on trade of discrimination and repression of unions are

conditional and depend on the sectors and environment in which they occur” (p.17). The

literature remains highly fragmented on this critical issue, which ultimately requires an

empirical analysis. As will be demonstrated in chapter five, although the effects of unions are

indeterminate a priori, states and employers continue to keep workers from forming

independent unions (Elliott and Freeman 2003).

To sum up, as postulated by Martin and Maskus (2001), if the violation of labour

standards results from discrimination against certain groups in society, employment,

production, and competitiveness will deteriorate. However, if unionisation was intended to

enable labour to restrict output and increases wages, the absence of these standards increases a

country’s competitiveness. From an economic perspective, outlawing child and forced labour

leads to a reduction of the relative labour endowment and thereby to a reduced comparative

advantage in the production of unskilled-labour-intensive goods. As noted by Golub (1997),

differences in wages and labour practices are compatible with mutually beneficial trade and

capital mobility. Conceptually speaking, non-adherence to these standards by developing

countries does not threaten the economic welfare of their trading partners. Calls for international

harmonisation are thus generally focused on distributional concerns rather and spreading the

benefits of globalisation more broadly.

However, the results of this analysis ought to be interpreted cautiously. The augmented

model is simple and fairly mechanical. Under no circumstances does it suggest that labour

Page 25: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

21

standards should not be a concern for policy makers and that labour practices need to be upheld

on moral grounds is not disputed.

4. RACING TO THE BOTTOM OR CLIMBING TO THE TOP?

4.1 Empirical evidence

While the intuition behind the race-to-the-bottom argumentation has surface appeal, there exists

little empirical evidence in the international literature to support the proposition. Empirical

studies have focused on the link between regulatory standards and FDI and to date conclusive

assessment has not been agreed upon.

Evidence of FDI being deterred by stringently enforced labour standards is provided

by Dewit et al. (2009), Görg (2005), as well as by Javorcik and Spatareanu (2005). However,

Dewit et al. find that high domestic levels of labour rights simultaneously discourage outward

FDI. According to their argument, “strict employment protection in the firm’s home country

makes firms reluctant to relocate abroad and keeps them “anchored” at home” (Dewit et al.

2009, p.98). Mosley and Uno (2007) argue that the overall effect of foreign investment on

labour rights is generally positive. The two economists find three causal pathways through

which FDI may facilitate labour standards: firstly, multinational corporations may pressure

governments directly to enhance their labour code; secondly, FDI can transmit best practices to

the labour market of the host countries; thirdly, public scrutiny can promote the transmission

of corporate social responsibility (CSR) among multinationals.

Similarly, the linkage between core labour standards and competitiveness has been a

topic of active empirical research. Aggarwal (1995) investigated the correlation between import

penetration in the US and adherence to basic labour standards in 10 developing countries. She

found it common for labour practices to be higher in export-oriented industries than in non-

traded sectors. Similarly, the Organisation of Economic Co-operation and Development

(OECD) concludes that no significant relationship between core labour standards and a

country’s export performance exists (OECD 2000).

By contrast, the work of Rodrik (1996) and Mah (1997) indicates that labour

conditions can reduce the competitiveness of countries in labour-intensive products,

culminating in diminishing manufactured exports. A further study by Hasnat (2002) concludes

that solely the ability organise and collective bargaining has a significant negative effects on

exports in non-OECD countries. According to his argument “there is no economic rationale for

introducing trade barriers in countries with high labour standards against goods imported from

countries with low labour standards” (Hasnat 2002, p.573).

Page 26: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

22

Comprehensive tests on whether countries competitively undercut one another’s

labour standards are rare. However, the use of spatial econometrics to look for a race-to-the-

bottom in taxes and environmental policies, which in essence partakes a similar dynamic,

already finds some instance (Palley 2004). Research on the economic impacts of labour

standards is complicated by the absence of comparable cross-country information on

compliance. The existence of legislation may not be a good proxy for the enforcement of

standards, and thus studies that investigate the number of ILO conventions ratified do not allow

for differences in adherence. Elliott and Freeman (2003, p.17) find that “the application of core

labour standards differs widely among advanced countries, and the ILO conventions defining

the core standards allow for broad flexibility in implementation.” The US, for instance, has

ratified only two core Conventions, but implements these rigorously. Rwanda, on the other

hand, as ratified all eight Conventions, but struggles with exploitative labour practices.

Empirical detection of a global race-to-the-bottom in labour standards is at an early

stage, with only a handful of studies having systematically addressed the issue. In 2007, Mosley

and Uno highlighted globalisation’s mixed impact on labour rights, testing the relationship

between labour rights violations and globalisation in 90 developing nations from 1986 to 2002.

According to their argument, “the impact of globalisation depends on the precise ways in which

a country participates in the global production networks” (Mosley and Uno 2007, p.924).

However, the study concludes that trade generally gives rise to enhanced competitive pressures,

with behaviour among peer economies being related to national labour rights outcomes.

A further study was conducted by Olney in 2010, providing evidence of a race-to-the-

bottom in labour standards, both within OECD and non-OECD countries. Olney (2010)

concludes that developed countries tend to compete in laws, while developing countries do in

practice. Building on Olney’s work and using spatial estimation on panel data for 135 countries

from 1985 to 2012, Davies and Vadlamannati (2013) find regulatory competition in both

developed and developing countries. This interdependence is more evident in enforcement than

in labour law, “suggesting that competition is driven less by a failure to institute regulations

than by an unwillingness to enforce them” (Davies and Vadlamannati 2013, p.1).

4.2 Theoretical literature

One way of thinking about globalisation is that it is creating a “leaky economic environment”,

distinguished by three types of leakiness (Palley 2004, p.24). Macroeconomic leakiness refers

to the propensity for demand to leak out of economies toward imported goods and services.

Similarly, microeconomic leakiness alludes to the tendency for jobs to leak to other countries

Page 27: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

23

if labour markets are sufficiently flexible. Financial leakiness comprises the exacerbated scale

of capital flows between economies. In this, Palley (2004) represents the theoretical case for

core labour standards, providing that standards generate both static and dynamic efficiency

gains that will improve a country’s competitiveness. Static arguments have been explored in

detail by Maskus (1997), arguing that core labour standards reduce domestic labour market

distortions by redistributing income away from capital. Dynamic efficiency gains stem from

advances altering the path of economic growth as countries adhere to more stringent labour

practices. Exploited workers are expected to invest sub-optimally in human capital, to lack

motivation, and to perform below their potential. Thus, as noted by Martin and Maskus (2001),

“paradoxically, then, the adoption and enforcement by developing countries of core labour

standards would increase the competitive pressures on workers in rich nations” (p.318).

According to Elliott and Freeman (2003), promoting global standards would not be so

costly as to put domestic competitiveness in manufacturing exports at risk. Freeman (1994)

concludes that countries desiring higher labour standards can purchase these without offsetting

their competitiveness in three possible ways: firstly, a currency devaluation could reduce costs

in foreign currency terms; secondly, wages could be adapted directly; thirdly, higher labour

standards may be financed by the state by raising taxes. Sanyal (2001) argues that the race-to-

the-bottom argumentation overemphasises the role of labour costs in corporate relocation

decisions, especially if lower costs simply reflect lower productivity of workers.

As postulated by Golub (197), while “it is in principle possible that a prisoner’s

dilemma situation could emerge, it is far less plausible than the popular fear suggests” (p.22).

Brown (2001) finds that if trading partners are small relative to the world market and are thus

unable to affect market prices and terms of trade, their individual standards do not affect each

other. According to Singh and Zammit (2004) labour standards are important indicators of a

country’s stage economic development and their promulgation is best advanced in a non-

coercive and supportive domain.

Klevorick (1996) provides that the existence of a race-to-the-bottom among national

governments depends much on the character of competition among them. Singh and Zammit

(2004, p.93) postulate “standards can, in principle, have both negative and positive

consequences, depending on the country’s history and the nature of its labour legislation.”

However, mobile resources and global production networks may render it more tedious for

labour to make other members of society, specifically employers, share in the costs associated

with enhanced labour standards (Lawrence et al. 1996).

Page 28: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

24

4.3 Market-driven mechanisms

Globalisation has altered the incentive structures for both governments and the business sector

alike. Subsequently, free-trade proponents argue that trade openness, rather than culminating in

a race-to-the-bottom, will have positive effects on labour rights, with public awareness,

consumer demand and economic growth stimulating economic and market-driven regulation of

labour practices (Haworth and Hughes 1997).

4.3.1 Ethical consumerism

According to an expanding body of literature, irrespective of whether states enforce their

respective labour codes, companies in some respect are already encouraging more effective

implementation of labour standards in response to growing consumer pressures. The emergence

of an ethical consumer base has been studied at length by Freeman (1994), identifying that

consumers not only care about the physical attributes, but also about the production conditions

and social quality associated with the goods they purchase.

The spread in information technology has created a heightened sense of awareness

about business practices and production conditions in different parts of the world. Following

Elliott and Freeman (2003), “globalisation means that consumers and workers in rich countries

will scrutinise the labour standards producing consumer goods” (p.25). Companies are

increasingly alive to pressures emanating from a variety of stakeholders, with consumers

sanctioning firms engaged in exploitative and repressive labour practices. Nike, for example,

was confronted with consumer boycott after the New York Times unveiled abusive labour

conditions at the company’s Indonesian suppliers two decades ago (Porter and Kramer 2006).

In 2004, ethical consumerism accounted for almost $44 billion in the United Kingdom

alone (Gugler and Shi 2009). Foreign suppliers can tap this lucrative market and attract

multinationals that want to add value to their brand by emphasising the ethical credentials in

their business operations. As noted by the IOE (2006), “companies now find themselves much

more open to public scrutiny on how they operate, where they operate and who their partners

are. In such an environment enterprises are very aware of the need to project a positive image

of their company, its values and ethics” (p.7). With firms being awake to the damage labour

rights problems in their supply chain have on the reputation and image of their brands, supplier

compliance with basic labour standards becomes a precondition for access to international

business and investment.

Today, labour-related CSR initiatives are an inescapable priority and de factor

mandatory for multinational firms’ in every country. While the concept of CSR can be traced

Page 29: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

25

back to Sheldon (1924), pioneer work analysing the linkage between CSR and competitiveness

is the research by Michael Porter. Porter describes how firms can enhance their long-term

business sustainability by reshaping their corporate agenda to align financial and social goals.

According to his argument, “companies achieve competitive advantage through acts of

innovation. They approach innovation in its broadest sense, including both new technologies

and new ways of doing things” (Porter 1990, p.74). While having traditionally revolved around

multinationals from industrial countries and their behaviour in developing countries, “CSR

issues are likely to become more important as firms in developing and transition economies

expand abroad” (Gugler and Shi 2009, p.17).

As a response to public pressures from consumers, investors, trade unions, and activist

groups, many reputable corporations have committed to corporate codes of conduct to regulate

labour conditions of their foreign suppliers and distant production facilities. In general, these

are written statements of norms and rules serving as the manifestation of a commitment to

uphold particular labour standards at the workplace (Yu 2008). Although their content and

format vary considerably, most codes reflect international legal norms and are based on the ILO

core conventions. As noted by Porter (1990) private corporate codes emerged as a response to

the lacking of a globally agreed upon labour regime. Since their credibility depends on how

they are monitored and implemented, consultancies have emerged with a vast network of tools

to assist firms with their ethical supply chain management.

It is convenient to think of goods conforming to certain basic labour standards as being

essentially equivalent to higher quality products, even though this attribute is based on the

manufacturing process rather than on tangible characteristics of the final good (Beaulieu and

Gaisford 2002). If such quality can be easily observed by consumers, labour standards will be

enforced at the efficient level to meet consumer demand. However, as Singh (2003) points out,

it is prohibitively costly for individuals to observe labour practices directly. Since conforming

products are generally indistinguishable from lower quality products when reaching the end

consumer, a disguised quality issue comparable to the lemons problem in the used car market

analysed by Akerlof (1970) exists. As in Akerlof’s studies, non-conforming goods will replace

high-quality products if they exchange at similar prices (Beaulieu and Gaisford 2002).

Social labelling schemes, involving assigning a label to products certifying that they

were produced under acceptable labour conditions, are implemented as one solution to getting

information about the production process to the end consumer. Especially third-party

certification, with an independent party monitoring labour practices and enforcing accurate

product labelling, is employed for credibility purposes. As noted by Lawrence et al. (1996,

Page 30: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

26

pp.59-60), “if imported goods can be appropriately labelled, consumers who are willing to pay

a premium for higher standards in a foreign country will be able to do so.”

Subsequently, Freeman (1994) has emphasised the possibility that demand for labour

standards is similar to the demand for any other economic commodity – something that

consumers desire and are thus willing to pay for. Beaulieu and Gaisford (2002) provide that

“when households would prefer to directly consume products made according to recognised

standards, they would be willing to pay a price premium to consume conforming goods” (p.60).

In a similar vein, supply for standards is equivalent to the supply of any product, with producers

providing improved labour conditions when they can profit from it. High standards reflect

rational business decision-making when consumers, activists, or governments make it more

profitable to produce under good working conditions (Freeman 1994).

As explained by Elliott and Freeman (2003,), “this willingness to pay more creates a

financial margin for improving conditions or increasing wages in less developed countries”

(p.28). Thus, if consumers look askance at goods produced under poor working conditions,

increased trade will create pressures to improve them, thereby initiating a race-to-the-top in

labour standards. This allows the market-mechanism to dictate the extent of labour practice,

ruling out uneconomic upgrading of standards.

4.3.2 Trade and income convergence

The free trade view traces its intellectual basis to classical economics and the trade theories of

Adam Smith and David Ricardo in the 18th and early 19th century. The classical economists saw

the market as an efficient, self-regulating mechanism tending toward equilibrium, thereby

assuring an optimal allocation of resources. Unrestricted trade and a laissez-fair stance are

beneficial, while barriers to trade are self-defeating and inefficient, culminating in wasted

resources. As summarised by the Nobel Prize-winning neoclassical economists Milton

Friedman (2000) in an interview, “the most important single central fact about a free market is

that no exchange takes place unless both parties benefit”.

Building on this argument, free market advocates trust in the endogeneity of labour

practices, arguing that demand for standards will naturally be modified by changes in economic

fundamentals and the well-being of society. Rather than leading to a race-to-the-bottom, trade

will promote economic growth and welfare, thereby facilitating improvement in labour

standards. As summarised by Casella (1996), “the main mechanism responsible for the

tendency toward harmonisation is the convergence in national incomes brought by trade.

Failing this convergence, the convergence in standards will also fail” (p.120).

Page 31: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

27

The intellectual rationale is rooted in the neoliberal economic doctrine, which sees

labour standards as counterproductive and interfering with the efficient market process. The

best protection for workers will emerge in a highly competitive labour market, unrestrained by

artificially imposed standards (de Wet 1994). The IOE (2006) provides, “marked-based

economic policies, including openness to international trade and investment, offer a superior

policy setting for lifting the pace and breadth of economic development in developing countries

and are the best means of enhancing labour practices in those countries” (p.2). Free market

advocates fear that prematurely enforced labour standards will threaten the competitive

advantage and trade prospects of less developed countries in the global market place, muting

the potential for economic growth (Roessler 1996).

According to trade economists, “open markets will bring about fast economic growth

in developing countries and this will ultimately lead to improvement of labour conditions”

(Denkers 2008, p.3). The argument is that trade results in both static and dynamic efficiency

gains. Economic openness will not only lower prices for consumers and increase domestic

employment opportunities, but liberalisation is thought to be an important source of long-term

economic growth. Through international trade countries may enhance their availability and

allocation of resources, benefit from specialisation in production, realise scale economies, and

access new production technologies and knowledge. However, globalisation enthusiasts

acknowledge short-term adjustment costs associated with trade openness, with the distribution

of benefits not necessarily shared broadly (Hill 2011).

Detailed statistical analyses show that open economies typically have faster growth

rates and more rapid declines in poverty (Dollar and Kraay 2002). However, existing studies

have been subject to intense scrutiny and empirical evidence that trade openness and economic

welfare are causally linked is hotly debated. Thus, conceptually speaking, the relationship

between trade and labour standards is ambivalent and the debate is ripe with grey areas.

5. CASE STUDY: EVIDENCE FROM CHINA

5.1 China’s economic integration

The economic system of the People’s Republic of China (PRC) has altered twice since its

foundation in 1949 (Rumbaugh and Blancher 2004). In the 1950s, a system similar to that of

the Soviet Union socialist economic model was established. The country’s industrial and

agricultural sector became nationalised and markets and prices were replaced by a planned

economy. As China pursued the economic strategy of self-sufficiency, four in five Chinese

Page 32: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

28

worked in agriculture and economic activity was characterised by a preponderant role of state-

owned enterprises (SOE) and government intervention (Hu and Khan 1997).

Following Mao Zedong’s deceasing in 1976, the Communist Party of China (CPC)

implemented a series of export-oriented economic reforms, gradually shifting toward a market

economy and decentralisation of economic decision-making (Rumbaugh and Blancher 2004).

The subsequent years were characterised by the coexistence of planned and market economic

elements. The party state encouraged the formation of a private business sector, liberalised

commerce and investment, relaxed price planning, and invested in industrial production and the

education of its workforce.

Especially after the end of the Cold War, the Chinese government embraced closer

integration into the global capitalist economy (Clarke et al. 2004). A decade of modernising the

country’s authoritarian state had produced a workforce combining high-productivity

manufacturing with cheap labour and little independent political power (Diamond 2003). FDI

inflows surged throughout the 1990s as multinational corporations stretched their commodity

chains to exploit China’s newfound cost advantage (Huang 2003). In addition to building

production facilities in China, international firms engaged in subcontracting and outsourcing

relationships with local Chinese suppliers. Standardisation of manufactured commodities and

declining long-distance transportation and communication costs facilitated the development of

global production networks. With China’s accession to the WTO in 2001, trade barriers yielded

to the full embrace of economic liberalisation (Elliott and Freeman 2003).

Decisive commitment to accept a larger role for markets in domestic resource

allocation brought far-reaching changes, not only to the Chinese economy, but fundamentally

to its industrial relations (Garnaut 1996). The first labour law in the country’s history was

enacted in 1994, providing the foundation for a range of labour market concerns, ranging from

hours of working, rests and leaves, to occupational safety and rights of female workers to labour

dispute resolution. As noted by the International Trade Union Confederation (ITUC), the

revised Labour Contract Law entered into force in 2008, advancing collective contracts and

tripartite institutions to mediate labour disputes (ITUC 2001)

China’s economic growth and subsequent poverty reduction has been outstanding. As

summarised by Borensztein and Ostry (1996), “China’s experience is unique in that its economy

grew rapidly in the context of reforms that transformed it from a rigid central planning system

to an increasing open and market-based economy” (p.224). By the turn of the millennium the

Chinese economy had grown more than fivefold, average income per capita had quadrupled

and 270 million Chinese had been lifted out of poverty (Chen and Wang 2001). However, the

Page 33: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

29

benefits of Chinese economic growth have been unevenly distributed and inequalities have been

deteriorating, particularly in recent years.

5.2 Regress or progress?

China’s entry into the global economy represents the integration of about a billion workers into

the labour market at wages below those found in advanced countries (Diamond 2003). Thus,

Elliott and Freeman (2003) note “what happens in China is important for labour standards

around the world. Because a large proportion of the global workforce is Chinese, changes in

China’s standards affect more people than changes in dozens of smaller countries” (p.119).

There remains heated debate about the effect China’s global economic engagement

has had on the country’s labour conditions. China has been at the forefront of growing concerns,

with a coalition of foreign trade unions, labour representatives, employers, activists and

governments arguing that brutal competition for mobile capital and global markets has

culminated in the strategic repression of labour standards (ITUC 2001). The global race-to-the-

bottom is allegedly an unhealthy feedback of this dynamic into the country’s major trading

partners, as alternative production sites compete for lucrative business. Diamond (2003)

explains “the structural changes underway in the Chinese economy are creating both domestic

and international imbalances that exacerbate inequalities among Chinese workers and create

new inequalities in the global labour market” (p.47).

Such concerns have provided much opposition to China’s entry into the WTO.

Opponents fear that China’s accession to the multilateral trading system has eroded the ability

of its trading partners to put economic pressures on Chinese politics and human rights

situations. As China exerts great influence over the world economy, pressures for labour rights

improvements may become negated as a pretext for protectionism. On the other hand, free-trade

enthusiasts postulate that China’s integration into the global structure has facilitated the

promotion of economic and structural development, indivertibly contributing to a stronger

emphasis on rule-based reform.

5.3 Racing to the bottom

In China’s pre-reform planned economy, SOEs provided wide-ranging protections and

certainties to its workers, including health care, housing, pensions, schooling and lifetime job

security (ITUC 2001). However, following China’s emphasis on export-led growth and the

expansion of its private sector, large parts of the country’s state-owned industries were

dismantled, laying off 30 million workers in the 1990s (Elliott and Freeman 2003).

Page 34: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

30

As China’s SOEs are progressively alleviated from government control, responsibility

for management and social security has been handed to the enterprise level (Clarke et al. 2004).

Subsequently, the spread of market mechanisms to product and labour markets has eroded

traditional guarantees of employment, wages, and welfare for once privileged SOE employees.

As noted by the Norton (2003), “the process of liberalisation has reduced the statutory

protection that workers used to enjoy” (p.10).

The development of Chinese legislation has closely followed the country’s market

reforms, with the first labour code enacted in 1994. Today, Chinese labour laws approach those

in developed countries and are more advanced than existing rules in most developing countries,

save for the country’s treatment of freedom of association and collective bargaining (ITUC

2001). The critical issue is the extent to which enforcement of Chinese labour law lags behind

its legislation. As noted by Elliott and Freeman (2003), “with the exception of union rights, the

problem in China is not one of deficient labour laws but of deficient enforcement” (p.121).

Rampant sweatshop labour abuses, especially in labour-intensive export-oriented industries,

continue to be commented on in the media and academic studies. Such exploitative practices

are a manifestation of the conflict between capital and labour, emanating from the embrace of

neoliberal globalisation. Trade liberalisation has fuelled brutal competition as the ability to

create a positive investment climate for foreign capital determines the extent of participation in

the world market (Chen 2003).

According to Elliott and Freeman (2003) there are three main causes for China’s

incapability to enforce its labour code: firstly, China’s state-controlled trade union monopoly,

the All China Federation of Trade Unions (ACFTU), is virtually impotent when it comes to

representing and mobilising workers. According to official figures, the ACFTU has 137

members, more than the rest of the world’s trade union members put together (Metcalf and Li

2007). However, the ACFTU remains a pliable instrument of the state apparatus. As noted in

its constitution, “trade unions are a bridge and a bond linking the party and the masses of the

workers and staff members, an important social pillar of the state power of the country” (cited

in Clark and Lee 2003, p.64).

Second, widespread corruption in the CPC, fostered by economic decentralisation of

power in favour of regional control, implies that the repression of labour standards goes

unnoticed and unpunished (Elliott and Freeman 2003). The final and politically sensitive reason

China fails to enforce its labour code is that the country’s paternalist labour regime obviates

independent union representation. As noted by Clarke and Lee (2003), “the subordination of

Page 35: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

31

trade unions and employers’ organisations to the party-state is clearly in gross violation of what

the ILO regards as the most fundamental precondition for real social dialogue” (p.77).

The repression of labour in favour of capital following China’s economic liberalisation

has provoked wide-ranging industrial conflict and social unrest. Discontent about growing

inequality and continued labour rights violations is exacerbated by the lack of appropriate

institutions assuring collective representation, resulting in a radicalisation of incidents (ITUC

2001). Although the right to strike was removed from the Chinese Constitution in 1982, each

year between 1992 and 1997, roughly 2 million Chinese workers were involved in protest

individually and another 1.26 million collectively (Chen 2003).

5.4 Climbing to the top

Elliott and Freeman (2003) argue that China’s embrace of globalisation, rather than culminating

in a race-to-the-bottom, has resulted in increased public awareness and market-driven

improvements in domestic labour practices. Consumer scrutiny and economic growth produce

opposing forces to existing competitive pressures, stimulating improvements in labour

standards until the highest, rather than the lowest prevailing levels among competitor nations

are reached (Haworth and Hughes 1997).

5.4.1 Trade and export diversification

The Chinese economy has responded dramatically to progressive economic reforms and

structural adjustment, enhancing its capacity to produce manufactured goods with high-

productivity at relatively low cost. China’s real exports have increased by more than 500

percent since the mid-1990s as the country yielded steadily to the progressive embrace of

globalisation (Amiti and Freund 2010).

Early phases of Chinese export-oriented economic growth were concentrated on

labour-intensive goods, following China’s abundant endowment of labour and land. By the

1990s, textiles, apparel, leather and footwear accounted for more than 44 percent of China’s

manufacturing exports to the world market (Xu 2010). However, as reforms took root, labour

and industrial land became relatively less abundant and increasingly costly, particularly in the

country’s coastal regions. By the turn of the millennium China’s inland had taken over coastal

provinces’ shares in the production of manufactured goods, competing with newly export-

oriented low-cost locations (Garnaut 1996).

Chinese real wages have tripled over the past two decades, reflecting both rapid growth

in productivity and more stringent labour legislation (Metcalf and Li 2006). With China’s

historical cost advantage diminishing, the economy has experienced dramatic changes in its

Page 36: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

32

export composition. Rapid growth has been associated with a diversification out of agriculture

and soft manufactures into hard manufactures, including machinery, consumer electronics,

appliances, computers, and to a lesser extent, metals (Amiti and Freund 2010). By 2005,

sophisticated manufactures represented more than 42 percent of China’s exports (Xu 2010).

China’s distinctive demographic features have accelerated the country’s evolution of

comparative advantage out of labour-intensive goods. Prompted by the country’s one-child

policy, China’s relative abundance of labour is diminishing more quickly than if it were

experiencing a more naturally paced demographic transition (Garnaut 1996).

The sophistication of China’s export structure has been more progressive than what

would be expected from the country’s development stage, resembling the export composition

of high-income countries (Rodrik 2006). With capital-intensive products generally requiring

technological sophistication, integration into the global economy has acted as a transmission

mechanism, increasing the overall skill content of the Chinese workforce (Yao 2006). As noted

by Brown and Lauder (1996), upgrading a country’s educational standards is instrumentally

important for the delivery and expansion of social justice. Economic integration has intensified

global demand for skilled labour within China, with the necessary capabilities to enforce

existing labour laws against employers. Between 200 and 300 rural Chinese workers have not

been integrated into the modern manufacturing sector, implying that the repercussions are yet

to be felt (Yao 2006).

5.4.2 Ethical supply chain management

While the term CSR originates from the Western world and its implementation has a relatively

short history in China, Chinese responsible business practices can be traced back to the

Confucian traders more than 2000 years ago (Wang and Juslin 2009).

The CSR movement was initiated in China in the mid-1990s, as the country yielded to

the progressive embrace of export-oriented growth. As China increased its capacity to produce

and export manufactured commodities at comparably low costs, foreign-owned production

facilities surged and Chinese enterprises became increasingly integrated into global supply

chains (Kotabe and Zhao 2002). Standardisation of manufactured commodities, declining

transportation costs and improvements in information and communication technologies

facilitated the development of transnational production networks to exploit newfound cost

advantages (Sum and Ngai 2005).

However, advances in communication and information processing have also created a

heightened sense of awareness about business practices and production conditions around the

Page 37: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

33

world. As aforementioned, firms now find themselves vulnerable to public scrutiny and are

awake to the damage repressive labour rights conditions in their global supply chains have on

the reputation of their brands (Elliott and Freeman 2003). Compliance with basic labour

standards has thus become a precondition for access to international business and investment.

As concluded by Ngai (2005), “global capital penetrates the sphere of labour rights in

China” (p.112). Public allegations of labour rights violations in Chinese factories have

triggered, especially from the 1990s onwards, transnational civic activism with a focus on

China. Multinational firms, concerned about their corporate image, have imposed strict rules

and standards for CSR in the form of codes of conduct to their Chinese production facilities and

overseas suppliers (Wang and Juslin 2009). Some companies have formulated codes of conduct

specifically for Chinese companies, epitomised by the China Business Principles of the

International Labour Rights Fund (Wang and Juslin 2009).

While CSR takes hold in China rapily, particularly among export-oriented firms,

Chinese CSR engagement is still in its infancy and continues to present a geographical disparity.

Gugler and Shi (2009) explain, “China’s CSR engagement has not yielded any systematic

approach so far, and the notion of sustainable development is still a new concept to many

business managers” (p.14). The most progressive region with respect to CSR engagement

continues to be the South China Guangdong province, accounting for one-third of the country’s

exports and most foreign-owned factories (Zheng 2006).

China’s extraordinary export performance in the past decades has been closely

associated with the production of labour-intensive goods for export. Subsequently, local

enterprises have only hesitantly accepted the labour-focus of many codes of conduct carried out

by foreign companies, concerned these might diminish their historical cost-advantage.

However, China’s export sector, accounting for 65 percent of national GDP in 2004, can no

longer afford to overlook the increasing profile of CSR on investment choices made by

multinational firms (Gugler and Shi 2009).

In fact, today “many large-sized enterprises recognise that an increasingly active CSR

engagement will offer them a chance to become globally competitive” (Gugler and Shi 2009,

p.13). Chinese suppliers now compete to introduce CSR initiatives as part of their strategic

policies on the global market. Losing cost-competitiveness to newly industrialising countries,

Chinese suppliers respond to the social responsibility movement, strengthening their

marketability and long-term competitiveness by emphasising their ethical credentials.

Page 38: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

34

5.5 China and the ILO core labour standards

The PRC has ratified ILO Conventions 138 and 182, outlawing child labour. However, lack of

proper enforcement implies that child labour under the age of 16 continues to be widespread.

The penalties prescribed are not stringent, criminal law provisions apply only to child

trafficking, hiring minors for particularly hazardous tasks, compulsory child labour and offering

children for prostitution (ITUC 2001). However, as noted by the ILO (2006) in a follow-up

report to its 1998 Declaration, there is evidence that child labour is declining rapidly. According

to their findings, since the early 1990s, China has educated more children than any other nation.

In similar vein, Basu (1999) illustrates that the percentage of children aged 10 to 14 who work

has dropped from 48 percent in 1950 to 12 percent in 1995, following progressive embraces of

market reforms since the early 1980s.

Similarly, the Chinese government has ratified ILO Conventions 100 and 111,

prohibiting employment and occupational discrimination. However, rural migrants, comprising

35 percent of China’s urban employment, continue to experience discrimination based on their

socioeconomic status, language or ethnicity (Zhang et al. 2009). As analysed by Feng et al.

(2002), such discrimination has contributed to the development of a dual society and associated

segregation in urban China.

For more than half a century, the Chinese system of household registration (hukou)

has divided the country’s rural and urban populations, not only geographically, but more

fundamentally along social, economic, political and legal lines. As noted by Chan (2010), the

system “is the foundation of China’s divisive dualistic socioeconomic structure and the

country’s two classes of citizenship” (p.357). Under the socialist planned economy, labour

allocation and mobility came under tight codification, with every Chinese citizen registered by

either agricultural or non-agricultural status. Some 800 million Chinese continue to be in effect

inferior citizens, without the chance to settle legally in cities and without access to basic

government-sponsored benefits enjoyed by urban Chinese.

While it is frequently argued that such injustice is central to China’s historical cost-

advantage, the hukou system has provoked much opposition within the international

community. According to Chan and Buckingham (2008), the main argument for hukou reform

is economic, with China being increasing pressured by major trading partners and civic activism

to soften its approach. While it is unrealistic that the dualistic structure will be dismantled

completely in the near future, China can no longer delay substantive reforms.

However, China has not ratified ILO Conventions 29 and 105 concerning forced and

compulsory labour. Forced labour continues to be systematically promoted in China’s penal

Page 39: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

35

institutions, in connection with prisoners sentenced to “reform through labour” (ITUC 2001).

Officially established in 1957, labour reform camps have become de facto enterprises, with

prison made goods generating $100 million in export value annually. However, in recent years,

the system has been widely condemned, both within and outside China, with prison labour

emerging as a central issue of contention between the US and China (Yang 2006). In February

2001, at her visit in Beijing, the UN High Commissioner for Human Rights called for the

Chinese regime to abolish is re-education through labour system (Keyuan 2001). Seymour and

Anderson (1999) argue that as international scrutiny is increasing, the system is becoming

inefficient and unprofitable, with the CPC having no option but to reform it.

Finally, China has not ratified ILO Conventions 87 and 98 on freedom of association

and the right of collective bargaining. As explained by Metcalf and Li (2007), “the party-state

does not recognise any conflict between capital and labour” (p.25). Trade unions have to be

affiliated to the ACFTU, which exercises a trade union monopoly. The ACFTU is a constituent

element of the state and the majority of its constituencies is elected directly by the CPC.

Activists of independent unions resisting ACFTU assimilation are arrested, detained or

imprisoned (ITUC 2001). Art.11 of the Trade Union Law stipulates “the establishment of any

trade union organisation, whether local, national or industrial, shall be submitted to the trade

union organisation at the next higher level for approval” (cited in ITUC 2001, p.2). Moreover,

there exists no comprehensive legislation on collective bargaining procedures, but instead a

nexus of laws regulating collective contracts (Fleisher and Yang 2003).

The CPC’s approach to labour conditions continues to be rigidly authoritarian, causing

dramatic confrontations, despite the government’s commitment to socialism. However, as noted

by Metcalf and Li (2007) “the whole notion of a labour market is only a decade or so old,

reflecting the previous Marxist aversion to exchanging labour for money” (p.3). Integration

into the global economy has accelerate the recognition that transition toward a pluralistic form

of corporate regulation constitutes an inescapable element to assuring long-term social stability.

As noted by Diamond (2003), “the trade union is a central force for democratisation,

transparency and social responsibility in a modern industrial economy” (p.46). It is becoming

politically increasingly difficult for the regime to react to industrial conflict with solely

authoritarian measures and trade liberalisation has pressured the ACFTU to stress its

representational role (Chen 2003).

In summary, deepening of the market mechanism in the PRC since the late 1970s has

brought momentous change to existing industrial relations. Failure or unwillingness to enforce

existing legislation has been used by globalisation critics as an argument supporting the race-

Page 40: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

36

to-the-bottom hypothesis. China has come a long way in opening up its economy, but some of

its more challenging transitions have yet to be faced. Authoritarian measures continue to be

constituent elements of modern Chinese politics, creating industrial conflict and social unrest.

Unionsation will constitute a critical step in the country’s broader processes towards a

pluralistic system of labour relations, as found in advanced industrial nations. As noted by

Diamond (2003), “without an effective labour movement there is no counterweight to the power

of business interests or volatile market forces in society or to the state itself” (p.46). Independent

trade unions will be fundamental in enabling Chinese workers to defend their own rights,

pressuring for more stringent observance of existing labour laws (Elliott and Freeman 2003).

With labour standards pervading virtually every aspect of trade and investment

relations, China has no choice but to address its reform-through labour programs, household

registration system and widespread corruption of local officials and businessmen. China now

has to encourage its institution-building, dismantle remaining central planning institutions,

strengthen its social safety net, and narrow social and economic disparities between rural and

urban regions.

6. CONCLUSION AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS

As the foregoing analysis has shown, the labour standards agenda has proliferated both in terms

of scope and breadth and labour standards continue to be among the more controversial issues

in contemporary global policy debates. Contrary to prevailing assumptions, this paper argues

that, rather than culminating in a race-to-the-bottom, trade liberalisation can be expected to

stimulate improvements in labour conditions. While increased competition over the

international allocation of capital exerts downward pressure on labour conditions, the

interaction between trade and labour standards is multifaceted, giving rise to countervailing and

opposing forces.

A nation’s ability to attract mobile resources is not merely contingent on its cost-

competitiveness, since “game theory represents an abstract model of decision making, not the

social reality of decision making itself” (Kelly 2003, p.3). Globalisation has changed the pattern

of incentives for both policy-makers and the business sector alike, stimulating market-driven

improvements in labour practices. Martin and Maskus (2001) explain “there are complex links

between core labour standards and competitiveness, and the countries with the highest labour

standards (today’s industrial countries) dominate world trade” (p.318).

While blaming international trade for less than universal adherence to core labour

standards is politically convenient and has surface appeal, “trade did not create low labour

Page 41: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

37

standards in developing countries; low labour standards are deeply rooted in poverty and social

customs” (Hasnat 2002, p.574). Demand for standards will be altered by changes in economic

fundamentals and long-term economic growth stemming from trade liberalisation will thus

facilitate adherence to internationally recognised labour practices. As explained by Casella

(1996) “because free trade modifies the national income of an economy, its production pattern,

and the distribution of its resources, we should expect standards to react positively to the

opening of markets” (p.124).

A key premise of this analysis is that the issue of labour standards stands at the

intersection of public and private spheres of law and policy. While the role of regulatory

regimes is an important part of any analysis, effective enforcement mechanisms have stemmed

from the business community itself. The spread in information technology has created a

heightened sense of public awareness about business practices in increasingly global production

networks, thereby integrating social concerns into private sector decision-making. With the

emergence of an ethical consumer base, multinational companies today encourage more

effective implementation of labour standards in their global supply chains. Growing consumer

pressures mean that labour standards are being leveraged to enhance competitiveness and

marketability (Haworth and Hughes 1997).

While the embrace of neoliberal globalisation has exposed the Chinese market to brutal

competition, prioritising economic development over workers’ rights, the twin pressures of

export sophistication and international scrutiny play a proactive role in advancing more

effective compliance with labour standards. As noted by (Wachman (2001)) “China is a more

human place today than it was during the years when Mao Zedong dominated it and ideological

extremism served as a justification for the wholesale deprivation of human rights” (p.257-258).

The foregoing analysis does not imply that labour standards may not be abused to

distort trade. As stipulated by Brown et al. (1996), “both import-competing and export firms

and workers may use issues of lower foreign labour standards to further their own narrow

interest” (p.231). As theoretically demonstrated by modifying the Heckscher-Ohlin framework

to incorporate labour standards, countries may improve their competitiveness in the production

and export of unskilled-labour-intensive goods following the non-conformity with

internationally recognised labour standards. However, this does not necessarily occur to the

detriment of the overall economic welfare of the country’s trading partners. Nonetheless, this

paper acknowledges that globalisation has increased national inequality, with labour standards

emerging as an essential element in building public support for continued globalisation.

Page 42: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

38

The promotion of rules tied to the international trading system might become a pretext

for protectionism, denying developing countries access to international markets. Bhagwati

(2007) explains “governments that can accelerate globalisation can also reverse it” (p.11).

However, a group of advanced countries, as well as their respective trade unions and parts of

their business sector resume a vocal campaign at the WTO for coercing adherence to

compulsory minimum labour practices in its member states (Eglin 2001). The WTO has thus

far been hesitant to approach this issue in a systematic way, but the issue is likely to be on the

agenda of any future set of multilateral trade talks. While this paper does not address the general

issue whether trade sanctions are an appropriate tool for enforcing international labour

standards, Hasnat (2002) explains “restricting market access in the developed countries for

goods made in the developing countries with poor labour standards may be ineffective, and

even hurt the very labourers the restriction is presumed to help” (p.574).

Subsequently, this paper rejects the dichotomy that labour standards and trade are polar

opposites, arguing that they can be successfully combined. In the words of Elliott and Freeman

(2003), “the appropriate metaphor is that of Siamese twins who share vital organs and cannot

be separated. One may be stronger than the other, but neither can advance without the other;

and the effort to separate them endangers both” (p.9). The authority to regulate labour standards

internationally ought to remain with the ILO, promulgated through dialogue and technical

advice. Experience has shown that the real issue of labour standards is lack of application of

existing law. As noted by the IOE (2006) “in many cases, excessively complex labour codes is

a key reason forcing many workers into the informal economy” (pp.2-3). Thus, this paper

argues that the approach to be take is a practical one and not a narrow legislative route. Enabling

greater market access will play a vital role in improving labour conditions, allowing the market-

mechanism to dictate the extent of labour standards, thus ruling out uneconomic upgrading of

standards.

Page 43: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

39

Bibliography

Addison, J. T. and Hirsch, B. T. (1989) 'Union effects on productivity, profits, and growth: Has

the long run arrived?', Journal of Labour Economics, 7(1), 72-105.

Aggarwal, M. (1995) International trade, labour standards, and labour market conditions: An

evaluation of the linkages, US International Trade Commision, Office of Economics,

Working Paper No. 95-06-C.

Akerlof, G. A. (1970) 'The market for lemons: Quality uncertainty and the market mechanism',

The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 84(3), 488-500.

Alcock, A. E. (1971) History of the International Labour Organisation, Octagon Books.

Amiti, M. and Freund, C. (2010) 'The anatomy of China's export growth' in Feenstra, R. C. and

Wei, S.-J., eds., China's growing role in world trade, University of Chicago Press, 35-

56.

Basu, K. (1999) 'Child labour: cause, consequence, and cure, with remarks on international

labor standards', Journal of Economic Literature, 37(3), 1083-1119.

Bazillier, R. (2008) 'Core labour standards and development: Impact on long-term income',

World Development, 36(1), 17-38.

Beaulieu, E. and Gaisford, J. (2002) 'Labour and environmental standards: The lemons problem

in international trade policy', The World Economy, 25(1), 59-78.

Bhagwati, J. (1958) 'Immiserising growth: a geometrical note', The Review of Economic

Studies, 25(3), 201-205.

Bhagwati, J. (2007) In defense of globalisation: With a new afterword, Oxford University Press.

Booth, A. L. (1995) The economics of the trade union, Cambridge University Press.

Borensztein, E. and Ostry, J. D. (1996) 'Accounting for China's growth performance', The

American Economic Review, 86(2), 224-228.

Brown, D. K. (2001) 'Labour standards: Where do they belong on the international trade

agenda?', The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 15(3), 89-112.

Page 44: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

40

Brown, D. K., Deardorff, A. V. and Stern, R. M. (1996) 'International labour standards and

trade: A theoretical analysis' in Bhagwati, J. and Hudec, R. E., eds., Fair trade and

harmonisation: Prerequisites for free trade?, 227-280.

Brown, P. and Lauder, H. (1996) 'Education, globalisation and economic development', Journal

of Education Policy, 11(1), 1-25.

Busse, M. (2002) 'Do labour standards affect comparative advantage in developing countries?',

World Development, 30(11), 1921-1932.

Campbell, G. D. (1867) Reign of law, Yale University Press.

Casella, A. (1996) 'Free trade and evolving standards' in Bhagwati, J. and Hudec, R. E., eds.,

Fair trade and harmonisation: Prerequsites for free trade?, The MIT Press, 119-157.

Chan, K. W. (2010) 'The household registration system and migrant labor in China: Notes on a

debate', Population and Development Review, 36(2), 357-364.

Chan, K. W. and Buckingham, W. (2008) 'Is China abolishing the hukou system?', The China

Quarterly, 195(1), 582-605.

Charnovitz, S. (1987) 'Influence of international labour standards on the world trading regime:

A historical overview', International Labour Review, 126(5), 565-584.

Chen, F. (2003) 'Between the state and labour: The conflict of Chinese trade unions' double

identity in market reform', The China Quarterly, 176, 1006-1028.

Chen, S. and Wang, Y. (2001) China's growth and poverty reduction: Recent trends between

1990 and 1999, The World Bank, Paper presented at the WBI-PIDS Seminar on

“Strengthening Poverty Data Collection and Analysis”.

Clarke, S. and Lee, C. H. (2003) 'The significance of tripartite consultation in China' in Warner,

M., ed., The future of Chinese management, Frank Cass & Co. Ltd., 61-81.

Clarke, S., Lee, C. H. and Li, Q. (2004) 'Collective consultation and industrial relations in

China', British Journal of Industrial Relations, 42(2), 235-254.

Costinot, A. (2009) 'On the origins of comparative advantage', Journal of International

Economics, 77(2), 255-264.

Page 45: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

41

Davies, R. B. and Vadlamannati, K. C. (2013) 'A race to the bottom in labour standards? An

empirical investigation', Journal of Development Economics, 103, 1-14.

de Wet, E. (1995) 'Labour standards in the globalised economy: The inclusion of a social clause

in the general agreement on tariff and trade/world trade organisation', Human Rights

Quarterly, 17(3), 443-462.

Denkers, J. (2008) The World Trade Organisation and import bans in response to violations of

fundamental labour rights, intersentia.

Dewit, G., Görg, H. and Montagna, C. (2009) 'Should I stay or should I go? Foreign direct

investment, employment protection and domestic anchorage', Review of World

Economics, 145(1), 93-110.

Diamond, S. F. (2003) The race to the bottom returns: China's challenge to the international

labour movement, Cornell Law Faculty, Working Paper 10.

Dollar, D. and Kraay, A. (2002) 'Growth is good for the poor', Journal of Economic Growth,

7(3), 195-225.

Eglin, R. (2001) 'Keeping the “T” in the WTO: Where to next on environment and labor

standards?', The North American Journal of Economics and Finance, 12(2), 173-191.

Elliott, K. A. and Freeman, R. B. (2003) Can labour standards improve under globalisation?,

Peterson Institute Press: All Books.

Engerman, S. L. (2003) 'The history and political economy of international labour standards' in

Basu, K., Horn, H., Román, L. and Shapiro, J., eds., International labour standards,

Blackwell Publishing, 9-84.

Feenstra, R. C. and Taylor, A. M. (2011) International macroeconomics, Macmillan.

Feng, W., Zuo, X. and Ruan, D. (2002) 'Rural Migrants in Shanghai: Living Under the Shadow

of Socialism1', International Migration Review, 36(2), 520-545.

Fleisher, B. M. and Yang, D. T. (2003) 'Labour laws and regulations in China', China Economic

Review, 14(4), 426-433.

Freeman, R. (1994) 'A hard-headed look at labour standards' in Sengenberger, W. and

Campbell, D., eds., International labour standards and economic interdependence, 79-

92.

Page 46: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

42

Freeman, R. B. and Medoff, J. L. (1984) What do unions do?, Basic Books.

Friedman, M. (2000) 'PBS Documentary: The Commanding Heights', Public Broadcasting

Service.

Garnaut, R. (1996) Export-oriented growth in India and China: Is the world big enough?, The

Australian National University, Paper presented at the International Conference on

India's New Economic Policy.

Golub, S. S. (1997) International labour standards and international trade, IMF Working

Paper, WP/97/37.

Görg, H. (2005) 'Fancy a stay at the ‘Hotel California’? The role of easy entry and exit for FDI',

Kyklos, 58(4), 519-535.

Gugler, P. and Shi, J. Y. (2009) 'Corporate social responsibility for developing country

multinational corporations: Lost war in pertaining global competitiveness?', Journal of

Business Ethics, 87(1), 3-24.

Hasnat, B. (2002) 'The impact of core labour standards on exports', International Business

Review, 11(5), 563-575.

Haworth, N. and Hughes, S. (1997) 'Trade and international labour standards: Issues and

debates over a social clause', Journal of Industrial Relations, 39(2), 179-195.

Hill, C. H. (2011) International business: Competing in the global marketplace, 8th ed.,

McGraw.

Hu, Z. F. and Khan, M. S. (1997) Why is China growing so fast?, IMF Working Paper 96/75.

Huang, Y. (2003) Selling China: Foreign direct investment during the reform era, Cambridge

University Press.

Huberman, M. (2012) Odd couple: International trade and labour standards in history, Yale

University Press.

International Labour Organisation (2006) The end of child labour: Within reach, Global Report

under the follow-up to the ILO Declaration on Fundamental Principles and Rights at

Work, International Labour Conference, Report I (B).

Page 47: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

43

International Organisation of Employers (2006) The evolving debate on trade & labour

standards, IOE Information Paper.

International Trade Union Confederation (2001) Internationally recognised core labour

standards in the People's Republic of China, Report for the WTO General Council

Review of the Trade Policies of the People's Republic of China.

Javorcik, B. S. and Spatareanu, M. (2005) 'Do foreign investors care about labour market

regulations?', Review of world economics, 141(3), 375-403.

Kelly, A. (2003) Decision making using game theory: An introduction for managers,

Cambridge University Press.

Keyuan, Z. (2001) 'The re-education through labour system in China's legal reform', Criminal

Law Forum, 12(4), 459-485.

Klevorick, A. K. (1996) 'Reflections on the race to the bottom' in Bhagwati, J. and Hudec, R.

E., eds., Fair trade and harmonisation: Prerequisites for free trade?, MIT Press, 459-

469.

Kollock, P. (1998) 'Social dilemmas: The anatomy of cooperation', Annual Review of Sociology,

24, 183-214.

Kotabe, M. and Zhao, H. (2002) 'A taxonomy of sourcing strategic types for MNCs operating

in China', Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 19(1), 11-27.

Lawrence, R. Z., Rodrik, D. and Whalley, J. (1996) Emerging agenda for global trade: High

stakes for developing countries, Overseas Development Council.

Leamer, E. E. (1995) The Heckscher-Ohlin model in theory and practice, International Finance

Section, Department of Economics, Princeton University.

Leary, V. K. (1996) 'Workers rights and international trade: the social clause' in Bhagwati, J.

and Hudec, R. E., eds., Fair trade and harmonisation: Prerequisites for free trade?,

177-231.

Leonard, J. S. (1992) 'Unions and employment growth', Industrial Relations: A Journal of

Economy and Society, 31(1), 80-94.

Lochner, L. and Moretti, E. (2002) The effects of education on crime: Evidence from prison

inmates, arrests, and self-reports, California Centre for Population Research, Working

Paper CCPR-010-03.

Page 48: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

44

Mah, J. S. (1997) 'Core labour standards and export performance in developing countries', The

World Economy, 20(6), 773-785.

Manhaim, E. (1934) 'The historical and social importance of international labour legislation' in

Shotwell, J. T., ed., The origins of the International Labour Organisation, Columbia

University Press, 3-19.

Martin, W. and Maskus, K. E. (2001) 'Core labour standards and competitiveness: implications

for global trade policy', Review of International Economics, 9(2), 317-328.

Maskus, K. E. (1997) Should core labour standards be imposed through international trade

policy?, World Bank, International Trade Division, Working Paper No. 1817.

Metcalf, D. and Li, J. (2007) 'Chinese unions: An Alice in wonderland', Advances in Industrial

& Labour Relations, 15, 213-268.

Moran, T. H. (2002) Beyond sweatshops: Foreign direct investment and globalisation in

developing countries, Brookings Institution Press.

Mosley, L. and Uno, S. (2007) 'Racing to the bottom or climbing to the top? Economic

globalisation and collective labor rights', Comparative Political Studies, 40(8), 923-948.

Ngai, P. (2005) 'Global production, company codes of conduct, and labour conditions in China:

A case study of two factories', The China Journal, 54, 101-113.

Norton, A. (2003) Labour standards and poverty reduction, Department for International

Development, Consultation Paper.

Olney, W. W. (2010) A race to the bottom? Employment protection and foreign direct

investment, Williams College, Department of Economics, Working Paper.

Organisation of Co-operation and Economic Development (2000) International trade and core

labour standards, OECD.

Ostrom, E., Gardner, R. and Walker, J. (1994) Rules, games, and common-pool resources,

University of Michigan Press.

Palley, T. I. (2004) 'The economic case for international labour standards', Cambridge Journal

of Economics, 28(1), 21-36.

Page 49: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

45

Polanyi, K. (1944) The great transformation: Economic and political origins of our time,

Beacon Press.

Porter, M. E. (1990) 'The competitive advantage of nations', Harvard Business Review, 68(2),

73-95.

Porter, M. E. and Kramer, M. R. (2006) 'Strategy & society: The link between competitive

advantage and corporate social responsibility', Harvard Business Review, 1-13.

Rodrik, D. (1996) 'Labour standards in international trade: Do they matter and what do we know

about them?' in Lawrence, R. Z., Rodrik, D. and Whalley, J., eds., Emerging agenda for

global trade: High stakes for developing countries, John Hopkins University Press, 35-

79.

Rodrik, D. (2006) 'What's so special about China's exports?', China & World Economy, 14(5),

1-19.

Roessler, F. (1996) 'Diverging domestic policies and multilateral trade integration' in Bhagwati,

J. and Hudec, R. E., eds., Free trade and harmonisation: Prerequisites for free trade?,

21-57.

Rumbaugh, T. and Blancher, N. (2004) China: International trade and WTO accession, IMF

Working Paper, WP/04/36.

Rybczynski, T. M. (1955) 'Factor endowment and relative commodity prices', Economica,

22(88), 336-341.

Sanyal, R. N. (2001) 'The social clause in trade treaties: Implications for international firms',

Journal of Business Ethics, 29(4), 379-389.

Seymour, J. D. and Anderson, R. (1999) New ghosts, old ghosts: Prison and labour reform

camps in China, ME Sharpe.

Sheldon, O. (1924) The philosophy of management, Sir Isaac Pitman and Sons Ltd.

Singh, A. and Zammit, A. (2000) The global labour standards controversy: Critical issues for

developing countries, South Centre.

Singh, A. and Zammit, A. (2004) 'Labour standards and the race to the bottom: Rethinking

globalisation and workers' rights from developmental and solidaristic perspectives',

Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 20(1), 85-104.

Page 50: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

46

Singh, N. (2003) 'The impact of international labour standards: A survey of economic theory'

in Basu, K., Horn, H., Román, L. and Shapiro, J., eds., International labour standards,

107-182.

Srinivasan, T. N. (2004) 'Labour standards and international trade', Labour History, 45(4), 509-

516.

Steger, M. B. and Roy, R. K. (2010) Neoliberalism: A very short introduction, Oxford

University Press.

Stern, R. M. (2000) Labour standards and trade, Research Seminar in International Economics,

Gerald R. Ford School of Public Policy, Discussion Paper No. 457

Stern, R. M. and Terrell, K. (2003) Labour standards and the World Trade Organisation,

Research Seminar in International Economics, Gerald R. Ford School of Public Policy,

Discussion Paper No. 499.

Stolper, W. F. and Samuelson, P. A. (1941) 'Protection and real wages', The Review of

Economic Studies, 9(1), 58-73.

Sum, N.-L. and Ngai, P. (2005) 'Globalisation and paradoxes of ethical transnational

production: Code of conduct in a Chinese workplace', Competition & Change, 9(2),

181-200.

Wachman, A. M. (2001) 'Does the diplomacy of shame promote human rights in China?', Third

World Quarterly, 22(2), 257-281.

Wang, L. and Juslin, H. (2009) 'The impact of Chinese culture on corporate social

responsibility: The harmony approach', Journal of Business Ethics, 88(3), 433-451.

World Bank (2012) World development report 2012: Gender equality and development, World

Bank Publications.

Xu, B. (2010) 'The sophistication of exports: Is China special?', China Economic Review, 21(3),

482-493.

Yang, Q. (2006) 'ILO fundamental conventions and Chinese labour law: From a comparative

perspective', Chinese Labour Law & Policy Review, 2(1), 18-43.

Yao, S. (2006) 'On economic growth, FDI and exports in China', Applied Economics, 38(3),

339-351.

Page 51: An Economic Perspective on the Race-to- the-bottom in ...the-bottom in International Labour Standards A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial

47

Yu, X. (2008) 'Impacts of corporate code of conduct on labour standards: A case study of

Reebok’s athletic footwear supplier factory in China', Journal of Business Ethics, 81(3),

513-529.

Zhang, J., Li, X., Fang, X. and Xiong, Q. (2009) 'Discrimination experience and quality of life

among rural-to-urban migrants in China: The mediation effect of expectation–reality

discrepancy', Quality of Life Research, 18(3), 291-300.

Zheng, L. (2006) 'A study on relation of corporate social responsibility and corporate value:

Empirical evidence from Shanghai Securities Exchange [J]', China Industrial Economy,

2, 77-83.