68
An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive Regime with a Focus on the Manufacturing Sector Paul Barbour Economic and Statistics Analysis Unit December 2005 ESAU Working Paper 14 Overseas Development Institute London

An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    2

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive Regime with a Focus on the Manufacturing Sector Paul Barbour Economic and Statistics Analysis Unit

December 2005

ESAU Working Paper 14

Overseas Development Institute London

Page 2: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

ii

The Economics and Statistics Analysis Unit has been established by DFID to undertake research, analysis and synthesis, mainly by seconded DFID economists, statisticians and other professionals, which advances understanding of the processes of poverty reduction and pro-poor growth in the contemporary global context, and of the design and implementation of policies that promote these objectives. ESAU’s mission is to make research conclusions available to DFID, and to diffuse them in the wider development community. ISBN 0 85003 781 6 Economics and Statistics Analysis Unit Overseas Development Institute 111 Westminster Bridge Road London SE1 7JD © Overseas Development Institute 2005 All rights reserved. Readers may quote from or reproduce this paper, but as copyright holder, ODI requests due acknowledgement.

Page 3: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

iii

Contents

Acknowledgements v

Acronyms v

Executive Summary vi

Incentives and their rationale vi Investment incentives in South Africa vi Conclusions and ways forward vii

Chapter 1: Introduction 1

PART I: TOWARDS AN ANALYTICAL CONSENSUS ON INVESTMENT INCENTIVES 2

Chapter 2: Incentives and their Rationale 2

2.1 Defining an incentive 2 2.2 Why offer investment incentives? 3

Chapter 3: Literature Review of Investment Incentives 6

3.1 The broad picture 6 3.2 Rationale for the continued use of investment incentives 7 3.3 Characteristics of effective investment incentives 9

PART II: ASSESSMENT OF SOUTH AFRICA’S INVESTMENT INCENTIVES 12

Chapter 4: Industrial Development Policy in South Africa 12

4.1 Policy objectives 12 4.2 The investment climate 13 4.3 Investment outcomes 15

Chapter 5: Assessing South Africa’s Incentive Regime 18

5.1 Incentive policy 18 5.2 Tax structure and incentives 19 5.3 Evaluation of South Africa’s incentives: international best practice 20 5.4 MIDP and SIP 22

Chapter 6: Marginal Effective Tax Rate Analysis 25

Chapter 7: Conclusions and ways forward 30

Bibliography 32

Annex 1: The Main Fiscal Incentives: Their Pros and Cons 36

Annex 2: South Africa: Investment Incentives Active in August 2004 39

Annex 3: Application to South Africa of the User’s Guide to the Dunn-Pellechio METR Model: 2004 53

Annex 4: Bell Equipment Ltd. 58

Page 4: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

iv

Figures

Fig. 4.1 Relative investment rates in South Africa 16

Fig. 4.2 Gross capital formation to GDP ratio 17

Tables Table 4.1 South Africa’s investment climate performance in comparison 14

Table 4.2 GEAR’s annual growth rate targets for investment 15

Table 4.3 Actual annual investment growth rates 15

Table 4.4 Average annual real growth rates of fixed capital stock by sector 16

Table 5.1 An analysis of South Africa’s two primary indirect investment incentives 24

Table 6.1 Base case: Asset structure of different business sectors 26

Table 6.2 How capital structure affects the METR in different sectors 26

Table 6.3 How incentive schemes affect the METR for manufacturing businesses 27

Table 6.4 How incentive schemes affect the METR for agricultural businesses 27

Table 6.5 How incentive schemes affect the METR for tourism/services businesses 27

Table A1 Bell Equipment financial statements: with and without MIDP and GEIS incentives 59

Boxes Box 3.1 The success of tax incentives in driving FDI in Ireland 8

Box 3.2 Tax behaviour of MNCs: home and host country tax policy 11

Box 5.1 MIDP and SIP 23

Box 6.1 The Marginal Effective Tax Rate (METR) 25

Page 5: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

v

Acknowledgements

This paper is dedicated to the late John Roberts, Director of ESAU, who died tragically in late 2005. I would like to thank several colleagues whose support and guidance have made its production possible. John Roberts and Dirk Willem te Velde of the Overseas Development Institute provided invaluable support. Many thanks are also extended to Matthew Stern at the World Bank in Pretoria, who helped identify the project and scope its overall direction. The South African National Treasury generously provided office space and logistical support. Within the National Treasury, I would like to thank Martin Grote, Kevin Fletcher, and Peter Mogoane for their help and guidance. Professor Saul Estrin at the London Business School reviewed the paper, and his input is much appreciated. I would also like to thank ESAU’s Steering Committee and Director for approving the research proposal and the UK’s Department for International Development (DFID) for making available grant funds to complete the work. Finally, I would like to thank everyone at Bell Equipment Ltd. for taking the time to explain to me the realities of investing in South Africa.

Acronyms

CGIC Credit Guarantee Insurance Corporation of Africa CGT Capital Gains Tax CIT Corporate Income Tax DBSA Development Bank of South Africa DOL Department of Labor DTI Department of Trade and Industry ECRS Export Credit and Foreign Investment Reinsurance Scheme EMIA Export Marketing and Investment Assistance Scheme FDI Foreign Direct Investment GDP Gross Domestic Product GEAR Growth, Employment and Redistribution HDP Historically Disadvantaged Person ICA Investment Credit Allowance IDC Industrial Development Corporation IDZ Industrial Development Zone ITAC International Trade Administration Commission of South Africa MIDP Motor Industry Development Programme MNC Multi-National Company NPV Net Present Value PDB Previously Disadvantaged Business PIT Personal Income Tax R&D Research and Development RFIs Retail Financial Intermediaries SARS South African Revenue Service SIP Strategic Investment Programme (of South Africa) SMEDP Small and Medium Enterprise Development Programme SMME Small Medium and Micro Enterprises STC Secondary Tax on Companies TDI Trade Development Institute UNCTAD United Nations Conference on Trade and Development WTO World Trade Organisation

Page 6: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

vi

Executive Summary

This paper investigates whether South Africa’s tax incentives have been effective in generating additional manufacturing investment (both local and foreign direct investment). South Africa’s investment incentive regime compares favourably with international best practice. However, the qualitative and quantitative evidence reviewed supports the hypothesis that the impact on manufacturing investment has been negligible. The paper concludes with some recommendations for the way forward, notably to rationalise the number of incentives and to move away from the use of discretionary allocation systems.

Incentives and their rationale

Provision of investment incentives is in the form of either tax relief or cash grants. International experience shows that such incentives play only a minor role in investment decisions. Firms make investment decisions based on many factors including projections of future demand, certainty about future government policy, prevailing interest rates and moves by competitors. In general, they see incentives as ‘nice to have’ but not deal-breaking. Yet incentives remain a popular policy for both developed and developing countries. The economic rationale for incentives in specific sectors or locations is based on market failure, which incentives seek to correct. Examples of market failure include information asymmetries, the public-good nature of investment in research and development and infant industry protection. However, governments often introduce incentives in response to political lobbying or to compensate for other policies that deter investment. A careful review of international best practice provides a useful checklist for what characterises an effective and efficient investment incentive. Such an incentive stimulates additional investment for a minimum of revenue loss, and includes a cap on expenditure plus a sunset clause. Incentives should be transparent, easy to understand and with low administrative costs for both businesses and government. Incentives can be automatically available or provided on a discretionary basis, but discretionary allocation systems open up avenues for rent-seeking behaviour by public servants or politicians. The processes and procedures by which incentives are designed and implemented are therefore important in determining their effectiveness.

Investment incentives in South Africa

The Government of South Africa outlined its macroeconomic policy in the Growth Employment and Redistribution (GEAR) document published in 1996. GEAR proposed a wide range of policy reforms, the most important of which were gradual trade liberalisation, deregulation of capital control, deficit reduction and stabilisation of the exchange rate. Within this broad orthodox approach, GEAR also included specific reference to the need for incentives to stimulate ‘labour-intensive manufacturing investment’. There is a good case for subsidising this sector in South Africa. The chronically high levels of unemployment and underemployment have significant negative externalities including links with poverty, crime and the spread of HIV and AIDS. Following GEAR, the government has adopted a cautious and well-informed approach on incentives, offering both up-front grant and tax relief incentives. There are also a number of parastatal lending institutions offering loans at sub-commercial rates. The balance of spend is heavily skewed towards off-budget tax incentives and subsidised finance rather than on-budget grants.

Page 7: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

vii

Since 1994, two ineffectual schemes - the General Export Incentive Scheme and the Tax Holiday Scheme – have been phased out and two significant new incentives targeted at the manufacturing sector – the Motor Industry Development Programme (MIDP) and the Strategic Investment Programme (SIP) – introduced in their place. The processes and procedures surrounding the implementation and execution of these two schemes have many of the characteristics of ‘best practice’ found through international experience. The results of a decade of reform, however, have been disappointing. The ratio of investment to Gross Domestic Product remains low at 16%. Investment in the manufacturing sector, while out-pacing investment in other sectors, has been too low to increase, or even maintain, the number of people employed in the sector. The paper presents a quantitative evaluation of South Africa’s tax incentives using Marginal Effective Tax rate (METR) analysis, based on a model developed by Bolnick (2004). The results show that the manufacturing sector faces a higher METR than any other because of tariffs on imported capital. By far the biggest determinant of a manufacturing firm’s METR is its financial structure because interest payments on debt are tax-deductible whereas returns on equity are not. The METR exercise shows that incentives available to the manufacturing sector are largely negligible and therefore unlikely to affect the decision to invest. Incentives are also unlikely to be effective in the face of more significant factors such as a volatile currency, weak demand, crime or a shortage of skilled labour. A case study of a South African exporter of manufactured goods, Bell Equipment, corroborates this. Bell Equipment values the benefit it receives under the MIDP, but regards the incentive as a form of ‘compensation’ for the other major challenges of investing in South Africa: namely, a volatile exchange rate, a remote location and an ever-increasing regulatory burden. These factors recently caused Bell Equipment to open a new factory in Germany, despite the MIDP benefits on offer in South Africa.

Conclusions and ways forward

The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First, the government could do more to rationalise the number of incentives and of institutions offering them. Second, too many incentives remain opaque in their application and approval process. The fact that a major accountancy firm in South Africa has a practice dedicated to helping firms navigate the complex application and approval processes highlights the current administrative costs to both government and firms. Too many incentives are still available on a discretionary basis. Third, South Africa’s motivation for subsidising the ‘labour-intensive manufacturing sector’ makes sense a priori. However, both the MIDP and the SIP have resulted in capital-intensive, not labour-intensive, manufacturing investment. The government should instead investigate ways of providing incentives directly on the hiring of low skilled labour rather than indirectly through ‘labour-intensive firms’. Fourth, the government needs to devote more time and attention to the evaluation of incentives, both ex ante and ex post, including the calculation of tax expenditures. This will help improve the chances that any future incentive will be both effective and efficient. Finally, the paper lends support to a common observation that governments should pay more attention to removing the disincentives to invest, rather than focusing on incentives to attract investment. In South Africa, the key issues to address include HIV/AIDS, crime, a shortage of skilled labour and an increasing regulatory burden.

Page 8: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,
Page 9: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

1

Chapter 1: Introduction

In 1996, the Government of South Africa outlined its macroeconomic programme in the Growth Employment and Redistribution (GEAR) document. The strategy comprised a set of orthodox policy reforms aimed at boosting investment and labour-intensive growth (Gelb, 2003; Gelb and Black, 2004a). It also proposed ‘tax incentives to stimulate new investment in competitive and labour-absorbing projects’. South Africa offers a range of incentives for investment in specific sectors. This paper investigates the extent to which these incentives have been effective and efficient in generating additional investment in the manufacturing sector. There are two main reasons for the focus on manufacturing. First, manufactured exports play a central role in the South African government’s strategy for spurring growth and employment (Edwards and Golub, 2004). Second, South Africa’s flagship investment incentive programmes are targeted at the export manufacturing sector. The paper is organised in two parts as follows. In Part I, Chapter 2 addresses the economic theory behind investment incentives, and Chapter 3 reviews the literature on how they have worked in practice. These two chapters provide a theoretical and empirical underpinning to the arguments that follow. The vast majority of the existing literature demonstrates that investment incentives are rarely effective or efficient, and that the broader investment climate is significantly more important in determining investment decisions. However, there are some interesting exceptions to this conclusion. A careful reading of the literature also provides a set of ‘best practice’ recommendations for the development and implementation of incentives. While it is problematic to make generic policy recommendations for different economies in different circumstances, it is possible to learn from and make specific recommendations about the processes and procedures for incentives. Section 3.3 draws out and identifies these lessons. In Part II, Chapters 4 and 5 present South Africa’s approach to industrial development and the role played by incentives. The government offers over 40 incentives through grants, tax relief and subsidised finance. However, there is no overarching ‘incentive policy’ within official circles and as a result each incentive has its own procedures for qualification and approval. Analysing the available incentives provides a broad picture of how far South Africa conforms to the ‘best practice’ guidelines. Chapter 5 also examines in more detail the country’s two ‘flagship’ incentive programmes, the Motor Industry Development Plan and the Strategic Investment Programme. A case study of a South African manufacturer and exporter illustrates some of the arguments developed. Annex 4 documents the case study in more detail. Assessing an incentive regime qualitatively against ‘best practice’ is only a first stage of the analysis, however. The second is to identify whether the incentives have led to additional investment that would not have occurred otherwise, and whether the costs of the incentive are justified by any additional investment generated. Chapter 6 uses Marginal Effective Tax Rate analysis to assess quantitatively the impact of South Africa’s various incentives. This process demonstrates precisely how much incentives distort the returns faced by investors, and thus how effective they are likely to be in influencing the decision to invest. Chapter 7 concludes the argument by drawing together both the qualitative and quantitative assessments of South Africa’s incentive regime and makes recommendations for possible reform.

Page 10: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

2

PART I: TOWARDS AN ANALYTICAL CONSENSUS ON INVESTMENT INCENTIVES

Chapter 2: Incentives and their Rationale

2.1 Defining an incentive

UNCTAD (2003) defines an incentive as ‘any measurable advantage accorded to specific enterprises or categories of enterprises by (or at the direction of) government’. Using this definition, an across-the-board reduction in corporate taxation is not an incentive scheme even though it may lead to increased corporate investment.1 Lowering corporate taxes to firms locating in a specific region, or producing certain goods or services, is an incentive scheme. By definition, if preferential tax treatment is applied to foreign direct investment (FDI) over local investments then this is an incentive scheme to attract FDI. Incentives can be fiscal or non-fiscal, direct or indirect. Fiscal incentives include direct ‘cash’ grants or tax breaks. Non-fiscal incentives may include fast-track approval processes or exemptions from certain regulations. Investment incentives can be categorised in a number of different ways. The following is one taxonomy. Direct incentives

• Cash payments • Payments-in-kind (such as the provision of land or infrastructure to specific firms)

Indirect (tax) incentives

• Reductions in the rate of direct taxation, either permanent or temporary. These can be in the form of tax holidays with reduced Corporate Income Tax (CIT) rates, accelerated depreciation allowances, investment tax credits, investment tax allowances or deductions of qualifying expenses.

• Reductions in indirect taxation either permanently or temporarily (e.g. reduced import tariffs or VAT on inputs or capital equipment). These can either be upfront reductions in import duties, or administered via duty drawbacks.

• Protection against competition from rival firms through tariff increases. Other, non-fiscal, incentives include:

• Special deals on input prices from parastatals (e.g. electricity, oil). • Streamlined administrative procedures or exemptions from certain pieces of

legislation. • Export Processing Zones (EPZs) which offer a combination of fiscal and non-fiscal

incentives within a particular geographical area, normally near a port.

1 Chua (1995) argues that an across-the-board reduction in corporate income tax is the best ‘incentive’ for investment, as it does not distort the price signals faced by firms and lowers administrative costs. Boadway and Shah (1995) in contrast see corporate income tax reductions as an expensive way to stimulate new additional investment, compared with tax credits, though much depends on the concurrent economic environment.

Page 11: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

3

• Legislation and/or policies that promote investment into certain sectors, or by certain investors.

• Subsidised financing through parastatal lending or equity. From the standpoint of both the government and the beneficiary, there are arguments in favour of both tax incentives and up-front grants (Kaplan, 2001). Grants have the significant advantage of being ‘on-budget’, thus allowing for better oversight and monitoring, whereas indirect (tax) incentives hide the level of revenues forgone unless the ‘tax expenditure’ is calculated ex post. Even though they are less transparent, tax incentives are popular, as they involve no up-front financing cost. Grants are easier to target at specific categories of industry but tend also to be administratively expensive for both governments and businesses. Companies like tax incentives because they are less discretionary and more automatic. They are also less susceptible to budget reductions.

2.2 Why offer investment incentives?

Governments pursue investment incentives as a means to an end. Policy-makers attribute poor economic performance to a lack of investment.2 Incentives are used as a tool to boost investment and growth, even if the causal links between each of these stages is far from proven.3 Incentives work by changing the parameters of an investment project. Companies choose to make investments when the Net Present Value (NPV) of a project’s cash flows (suitably discounted) is greater than zero. In a world where companies face no rationing of capital at its going user cost, companies undertake every project with a NPV greater than zero. In a world where companies face capital rationing, they choose the mix of projects with the greatest Internal Rate of Return. Incentives bias investors’ decision-making positively in favour of investments in certain sectors or regions. 4 By reducing the tax burden or providing cash incentives, there is increased expected profitability of projects in those sectors or regions. Where companies have good access to finance, the introduction of special incentives to certain sectors or regions should in theory lead to an overall increase in investment. The tax code can also influence how an investment is financed. For example, in most countries’ tax systems interest payments on debt qualify as a tax-deductible expense, whereas returns to equity do not. This creates an incentive in favour of debt financing. Incentives can also affect the quality of investment (i.e. its performance as well as its quantity). Neo-classical economic theory argues that providing tax incentives to one group of investors rather than another violates one of the principal tenets of a ‘good tax system’ – that of horizontal equity.5 This inequality distorts the price signals faced by potential investors and leads to an inefficient allocation of capital. The justification most often given for special incentives is that there are market failures surrounding the decision to invest in certain

2 Investment is, for the purposes of this paper, defined as Gross Fixed Capital Formation excluding portfolio flows. 3 See Fletcher (2003) for a discussion of the investment-growth linkages and surrounding debates. 4 Bolnick (2004) shows that there are three ways the government can reduce the user cost of capital: by reducing the corporate tax rate, introducing tax incentives, or adjusting the tax treatment of the cost of funds. 5 A ‘good tax system’ has four other attributes: economic efficiency, administrative simplicity, flexibility, and political responsiveness (Stiglitz, 1986). See Fletcher (2003) for a discussion of tax theory within South Africa’s economy.

Page 12: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

4

sectors and/or locations, which justify government intervention.6 Market failures result in either too much or too little investment in certain sectors or locations. The key market failures most often cited (but hotly debated) are the following: Externalities. Positive externalities (not internalised in the project’s rate of return) are higher in certain sectors than in others. A classic example is Research and Development (R&D), where investment yields a higher social than private rate of return (because not all the technological knowledge can be effectively patented) – and as such there exists an ex ante justification for subsidising R&D investment (Kaplan, 2001). Without subsidy, the level of R&D investment would be below the optimum. A similar argument can be made for the reverse - that investment in sectors with significant negative externalities (such as pollution) should face a higher tax burden. Infant industry. Markets often fail to correct for the gains that can accrue over time from declining unit costs and learning by doing. Capital markets are often very risk-averse and therefore avoid financing start-up companies, and equity markets are weak in developing countries. Hence, one argument for incentives is to support the establishment of businesses in the first few years. Subsidies to help potential investors overcome entry barriers in monopolised sectors, bringing about competition and lower prices, can be justified in a similar manner. Information asymmetries and uncertainty. Both providers and users of capital suffer from less than perfect information. As a result, some investment opportunities may not be financed or undertaken, even though they are NPV-positive. Financiers face imperfect information about the level of risk in certain sectors of the economy because they lack experience in those sectors. Similarly, there is often a ‘first mover disadvantage’ for investors in new sectors, as they assume more risk than those that follow. Successful investments in new sectors or geographic areas have an ‘agglomeration effect’ as they provide information on the level of risk involved. For these reasons, it can be argued that incentives are required to counteract these inherent uncertainties and trigger a positive cycle of investment.7 In addition to market failures, other arguments for investment incentives are the following: Equity. Whilst an allocation of capital directed by unfettered market prices might lead to an efficient outcome, it may not lead to an equitable one. For example, economically depressed remote areas are at a competitive disadvantage because it is harder to attract labour and costlier to transport inputs and outputs. The failure of depressed areas to attract investment is sometimes also categorised as a market failure because of the vicious circle created by a lack of investment feeding off and reinforcing itself. Political economy. Opponents of investment incentives argue that many of them exist to support special (politically connected) interest groups. Politicians representing one region or province might argue for incentives in the region they represent without any economic justification for doing so. There are other purported benefits of incentives, such as symbolic ‘signalling’ effects and the need to compensate for inadequacies in the investment regime elsewhere. For a full discussion of the pros and cons of investment incentives see Bolnick (2004) or Fletcher 6 Although different tax rates based upon the elasticity of demand for each sector do raise a given level of revenue with a minimum dead weight loss (see the discussion of Ramsey taxes in Stiglitz (1986) and Boadway and Shah (1995). Furthermore, applying uniform tax rates to different sectors of the economy results in very different marginal effective tax rates because of differences in capital intensity, financing structure, etc. (Bolnick, 2004). 7 Roberts (2004) goes so far as to argue that such market failures in the financial sector are ‘intrinsic’.

Page 13: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

5

(2003). Having now seen why incentives might be justified in theory, Chapter 3 reviews how they have worked in practice.

Page 14: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

6

Chapter 3: Literature Review of Investment Incentives

3.1 The broad picture

By far the majority of the existing literature is extremely sceptical about the role of incentives in the decision to invest and therefore by extension the ability of incentives to affect investment patterns. The International Monetary Fund (Chua, 1995) takes the firm line that tax incentives do not stimulate investment significantly, and that, when they do, the cost often outweighs the benefits. Firms consider a myriad of factors when deciding whether or not to invest, affecting the perceived levels of both risks and return with specific projects. Major factors include confidence in the future, demand projections, interest rates, political and economic stability and the predicted moves of competitors. Firm surveys routinely show that incentives provided by governments are not particularly important in determining the decision to invest. A substantial body of empirical work exists looking specifically at the efficacy of incentives in driving additional FDI – see, for example, Shah and Slemrod (1995), Slemrod (1995), UNCTAD (2003), Wells et al. (2001), Zee et al. (2002). Investor surveys, econometric studies or case studies are the primary tools used to assess the efficacy of FDI incentives.8 The conclusions of this literature are the following:

• Foreign-based firms look at numerous factors when deciding whether and where to invest: namely, size of market, regulatory policies, natural resource endowments, and human capital availability. These fundamentals are examined first. Evidence from both surveys and econometric studies shows that fiscal incentives play an insignificant role in determining whether to invest. Surveys tend to show that tax incentives are ‘good to have, but not a deciding factor’. Wells et al. conclude: ‘experience strongly suggests that the fiscal investment incentives popular in developing countries have not been effective in making up for fundamental weaknesses in the investment climate. In fact, it seems that multinationals give more importance to simplicity and stability in the tax system than generous tax rebates, especially in an environment with great political and institutional risks.’

• This general conclusion is qualified when foreign firms are deciding where to invest.

When faced with several locations with similar investment climates (in terms of fundamentals such as political/economic stability, infrastructure, skills availability, capital controls, etc.), fiscal incentives can play a significant role in attracting footloose, mobile capital.9 Thus, for example, tax incentives have played a significant role in determining the location of FDI within the United States and the European Union (see Box 3.1). Bu, such ‘tax competition’ can easily lead to a detrimental Prisoners’ Dilemma-type outcome in which competing countries or regions lose tax revenues. The result is often a transfer of resources from the host country government to the home country shareholders or, if there is no double taxation agreement, to the home country government.10

8 Such as that by Wells et al. which uses Indonesia’s historical on-off incentive regime as a case study for testing the efficacy of tax incentives. 9 Clearly, investments to extract natural resources are location-specific. In this case, the only argument for tax incentives is that they can make non-viable investments profitable. 10 This is the so-called ‘race to the bottom’, as regions/countries try to attract investment by successive rounds of tax reductions (see Wells et al., 2001 or Chua, 1995). The solutions proposed include voluntary collective tax agreements or through legal mechanisms such as the World Trade Organisation.

Page 15: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

7

• The costs of doing business matter more where footloose FDI is seeking a location from which to export, rather than where there is a ‘market-seeking’ investor. Incentives are therefore more likely to be attractive to export-focused firms rather than market-seeking ones.

• There is little evidence that the benefits of tax incentives net of costs (i.e. their

efficiency as well as their efficacy) add to the economic welfare of the host country. Existing studies do, however, suffer from severe data problems. Costs include forgone revenue, higher taxes for remaining taxpayers, administrative costs, etc. For a tax incentive to be beneficial to the host country fiscus, the NPV of the costs of the incentive would have to be more than offset by the NPV of the increase in tax revenue resulting from increased investment flows. Because of forecasting errors, incentives are often over-generous.11

• Where tax incentives do work in attracting FDI, effective marginal and effective

average tax rates matter more or less to firms depending on: their home county and its tax regime; the size of firm investing; the industry or service sector; the investing company’s age and capital structure; the strategy of the parent company.

• Incentives interact with a host of other public policies to increase or decrease their

effectiveness. Important considerations are the degree of monopoly power, foreign-exchange rationing, credit rationing, home-country tax regimes and the transfer pricing practices of multinational companies (MNCs).

3.2 Rationale for the continued use of investment incentives

Despite the lack of evidence to support the efficacy or efficiency of fiscal incentives, governments continue to offer them.12 Why is this? Wells et al. (2001) argue that tax incentives offer an easy way to compensate for other government-created obstacles in the business environment. In other words, fiscal incentives respond to government failure as much as market failure. It is far harder, and takes far longer, to tackle the investment impediments themselves (low skills base, regulatory compliance costs, etc.) than to put in place a grant or tax regime to help counterbalance these impediments. Although it is a second-best solution to provide a subsidy to counteract an existing distortion, this is what often happens in practice. Agency problems also exist between government agencies responsible for attracting investment and those responsible for the more generic business environment. Whilst investment-promotion agencies can play an important role in co-ordinating government activity to attract investment, they also often argue for incentives without taking account of the costs borne by the economy as a whole.13 Wells et al. (2001) point to ‘stories’ of potential investors locating elsewhere because of better incentive schemes, ’stories’ that seldom stand up to rigorous analysis.14

11 Estimating the economy-wide costs and benefits is even more problematic because of the diffuse nature of both (Slemrod, 1995; Shah and Slemrod, 1995). 12 There has, however, been a global trend toward incentives which are better targeted and better designed to fit local circumstances (UNCTAD, 2000). 13 Costs (as opposed to benefits) are often not correctly accounted for, because they are especially hard to calculate (Bolnick, 2004). 14 For example, in 2001 a Malaysian textile company seeking an investment location in southern Africa from which to benefit from the United States’ Africa Growth and Opportunity Act , chose Namibia. The story is often cited as an example of South Africa not offering sufficiently attractive investment incentives. The facts point to a far more complicated situation (see James, 2003).

Page 16: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

8

It may also be that incentives are the only policy tool available to the government at the time. A less cynical interpretation of the evidence would accept that governments often choose an active industrial policy that requires tools to implement it. Section 2.2 discussed in some detail the very real market failures that occur within an economy. Governments may legitimately feel that strict horizontal equity with government taxation and expenditure does not adequately address policy objectives and inherent market failures in certain sectors. The policy objectives might include:

• Increasing investment to a specific region, which does not receive as much investment as it should (given the economic fundamentals) because of information asymmetries.

• Increasing investment in R&D, an area often under-invested in by businesses because of its ‘public-good’ nature.

• Enhancing exports. Commentators now broadly accept that the majority of the successful East Asian economies provided incentives to firms to export, resulting in economy-wide benefits (see Wade, 1990).

• Employment promotion because of the economy-wide benefits of greater employment (lower crime, skills transfer, etc.), which are not taken into account by individual firms. (This final point is especially pertinent in South Africa, which has extremely high rates of unemployment and underemployment. Part II explores this issue further.

Box 3.1 The success of tax Incentives in driving FDI in Ireland

Ireland has transformed itself over the last 20 years from a poor backwater of Europe into the continent’s most dynamic economy. Successive Irish governments earned this success through aggressive improvements in economic fundamentals, strengthening the education system, and promoting Ireland as an investment destination, with EU membership and attractive tax incentives as lures. Until the late 1950s, Ireland discouraged foreign investment, and the economy stagnated. In 1959, the government created the Shannon Free Zone to stimulate investment for export. Initially export profits were entirely untaxed. In 1981, a 10% tax rate was established for manufacturing, EPZ operations, and certain service industries, including international financial service centres. The government also provided financial grants tailored to each project. Nevertheless, manufactured exports did not take off until the 1980s, after the government adopted major reforms due to the ‘sheer necessity of economic survival’. The reforms included tight monetary and fiscal policy to achieve macroeconomic stability, a social compact with business and labour, and low overall tax rates. The World Investment Report (1998) states that investment ‘has been visibly influenced by this policy’, attracting thousands of flourishing new enterprises and creating ‘new comparative advantage’ in sectors such as chemicals, office machinery, electrical engineering and computer software. Since 1987, Ireland has been the fastest growing economy in Europe. By the late 1990s, foreign-owned manufacturing firms accounted for nearly 60% of gross output and 45% of manufacturing employment, up from a zero base in the late 1950s. Between 1992 and 1997, full-time employment increased by 22%. Ireland’s current policy regime is focused on maintaining existing investment via a strategy of skills upgrading, a low stable tax regime (10% for all manufacturing and exporting companies until 2010; 12.5% otherwise) and the provision of critical infrastructure. Source: Bolnick (2004) and Hinch (2004). Given that investment incentives remain popular despite the dearth of evidence to support them and that carefully planned incentives can be theoretically justified, the next set of questions revolves around what determines the success or otherwise of an incentive.

Page 17: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

9

3.3 Characteristics of effective investment incentives

Annex 1 draws together the existing evidence on the various incentive options available to government (see Shah, 1995, and Bolnick, 2004, amongst others). Every incentive has advantages and disadvantages, and it is thus extremely difficult to determine one set of ‘incentives which work’ for very different economies with different challenges and circumstances. Much of determining ‘what works’ will depend on the circumstances of the economy, the competence of the tax administration, the type of investment being courted and the budgetary constraints of the government. Having said this, a careful reading of the evidence does provide a set of ‘best practice guidelines’ for policy-makers. The key lessons are necessarily broad and focus on the process and procedures surrounding incentive policy rather than a set of policy prescriptions. An effective and efficient incentive:

• Stimulates investment in the desired sector or location, with minimal revenue leakage, and provides minimal opportunities for tax planning.

• Is transparent and easy to understand, has specific policy goals and is expressed precisely in legislation.

• Is not frequently changed, and provides investors with certainty over its application and longevity.

• Avoids trying to target cyclical depressions due to the lag effects of intervention. • Is developed, implemented, administered and monitored by a single agency. • Has low administrative costs for both governments and firms. • Co-ordinates national, regional and local governments effectively. • Includes follow-up and monitoring, both to ensure that the incentive criteria are

being met and also to provide a monitoring and evaluation feedback loop. • Incorporates sunset clauses for both the scheme itself and for the duration of

benefits to any one firm. • Includes a cap on expenditure, or taxes forgone, to the fiscus. • Is non-discretionary and applied consistently against an open set of transparent

criteria. This last point is debatable. Any benefit (such as an incentive) allocated by public servants or politicians is potentially open to abuse and corruption. There is therefore a strong argument that incentives should be automatically available to all investors who meet a set of open and transparent criteria. However, an alternative argument is that firms should receive just enough incentive to induce them to invest, and no more. Each potential investment therefore needs to receive an incentive specific to its particular situation. Clearly, which of these two alternatives the government chooses depends on the strength of governance within the appropriate institutions. If public servants and politicians retain decision-making power over the allocation of incentives, then the processes and outcomes need to be as transparent as possible. If these guidelines are followed, governments are less likely to enter into some of the more egregious incentive schemes, which have proved so expensive and ineffectual in the past (Boadway and Shah, 1995). Historical experience of the efficacy of incentive schemes also provides, with some caution, the following key policy lessons:

• Incentives need to be carefully designed to achieve a specific policy goal. Poorly targeted tax incentives prove ineffective and expensive. Tax holidays, while being easy to administer, are a good example of a poorly targeted incentive.

Page 18: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

10

• Moderate tax incentives that are targeted to new investment in machinery,

equipment and R&D, and that provide up-front incentives, are more likely to be cost-effective in stimulating desired investment. These can have powerful signalling effects without significant loss of revenue. Investment tax credits and allowances provide specific and targeted policy tools to achieve this.

• Reducing corporate tax to a level comparable with other countries in the region is a

‘sound tax incentive’. However, reductions beyond the level found in capital-exporting countries (say, below 20-30%) often bring about greater revenue losses than increases in investment.

• Removing taxes on imported inputs used in the production of exports (not across the

board) removes a serious disincentive to export production. Such a move eliminates the distortion in international prices created by import tariffs and provides an incentive for firms to respond to the relative cost advantages of the home economy. Duty drawbacks provide a good example of an incentive which supports exports. Such schemes, however, require a competent tax administration.

• In situations where reducing unemployment is a major policy objective, it is

important to bear in mind that many tax incentives (such as accelerated depreciation) can work in the opposite direction by favouring capital-intensive investments. Incentives can be created, however, to explicitly encourage labour-intensive production.

Finally, it is worth re-emphasising a few more general policy issues:

• Incentives play only a marginal role in the investment decision for businesses. Growth in demand, economic and political stability, the state of the infrastructure, the rule of law, and a skilled labour force are more important in determining investment decisions.

• Special features of developing countries (such as market power, accumulated tax

losses by many firms, credit rationing, and exchange controls) can severely constrain the effect of tax incentives in stimulating investment.

• Well-designed but poorly implemented tax incentives are equally ineffective. Clear

and transparent application and screening procedures, and an effective tax administration regime with ‘bite’, are crucially important to the ultimate credibility and success of a tax incentive programme. Governments need to bear in mind the capacity of their tax administration when considering whether to implement incentives, and if so which.

Armed now with both a theoretical justification for incentives and a wealth of experience on what tends to work and what does not in practice, the discussion now turns to the specific case of South Africa.

Page 19: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

11

Box 3.2 Tax behaviour of MNCs: home and host country tax policy

Continued globalisation of capital has changed the environment within which tax incentives operate, making them both more relevant (because of the increased mobility of capital) and also more beneficial to MNCs because of the increased opportunities for tax planning and transfer pricing. This development has increased the focus on how home and host country tax policies combine to affect the level of FDI. There are three categories of tax regime, each with significant implications for the effectiveness of incentives: 1. Some home countries (e.g. France) do not tax income earned overseas. In such situations, the host country government need not concern itself with the combined effective corporate tax rate when determining the corporate tax for FDI. 2. The ‘worldwide’ approach to taxation (e.g. as followed by the US, UK and Japan) taxes resident investors on their worldwide income, which includes income from foreign sources. To avoid double taxation, the home country authorities usually provide a tax credit for foreign income tax paid. Without ‘tax sparing’ agreements, (see no. 3) however, the effect of this system is to nullify the effect of tax incentives. 3. Under a ‘tax sparing’ system, the home country treats offshore income that has benefited from host country tax incentives as if it had been fully taxed (Hanson 2001). This is a form of overseas aid. The US is the most high-profile example of a government that will not enter into tax sparing agreements. South Africa does have a tax sparing agreement with the UK, which is a major source of FDI. Tax sparing can, however, encourage repatriation of profits rather than their reinvestment in the host country subsidiary. The exact details of home and host country tax regimes are usually included in double taxation agreements. South Africa has 53 such agreements in place or under negotiation. Source: Slemrod (1995) and Slemrod and Shah (1995)

Page 20: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

12

PART II: ASSESSMENT OF SOUTH AFRICA’S INVESTMENT INCENTIVES

Chapter 4: Industrial Development Policy in South Africa

4.1 Policy objectives

The primary over-arching macroeconomic policy document produced by the South African Government since 1994 has been the GEAR (Growth, Employment and Redistribution) Strategy of 1996. GEAR identified low savings and low investment as key causes of slow growth in the South African economy in the early 1990s. A key recommendation, therefore, was to raise savings and investment, both domestically and through Foreign Direct Investment (FDI). Policies to achieve this were orthodox, including gradual trade liberalisation, deficit reduction, ‘consistent’ monetary policy, the gradual relaxation of exchange controls, and an expansion of trade and investment flows in Southern Africa. The role apportioned to active industrial policy in GEAR is modest. The GEAR document refers to the need to implement ‘trade and industrial policies … to promote an outward-oriented industrial economy’. Specific reforms mentioned (but not spelled out in detail) are:

• ‘… a further lowering of tariffs to compensate for the real depreciation, • the introduction of tax incentives for a fixed period to stimulate investment, • a campaign to boost small and medium firm development, • a strengthening of competition policy and the development of industrial cluster

support programmes, amongst other initiatives’. Both the National Treasury (NT) and the Department of Trade and Industry (DTI) take a lead in industrial policy. Since GEAR was launched, the DTI has produced three other key policy documents: Micro-Economic Reform Strategy (2001a), Driving Competitiveness: Towards a New Integrated Industrial Strategy for Sustainable Employment and Growth (2001b), and Accelerated Growth and Development: The Contribution of an Integrated Manufacturing Strategy (2002). The Micro-Economic Reform Strategy document was released by the DTI in an effort to supplement the GEAR document which is principally macroeconomic, while the Integrated Manufacturing Strategy documents outlined the shift in the government’s thinking toward supply-side measures such as enhanced competition, the creation of sector-specific regulators and a new small business institutional framework and legislation. At the same time, the DTI has spent considerable time and resources developing overall strategies for different sectors – much of this under a cluster framework that owed a great deal to the ideas of Michael Porter (Kaplan, 2003). Integral to the Integrated Manufacturing Strategy documents is the concept of strategies for a number of so-called priority sectors, namely, clothing and textiles; agro-processing; metals and minerals; tourism; automotives and transport; crafts; chemicals and biotechnology; and knowledge-intensive service (IT). These sectors of the economy are targeted for what is vaguely termed ‘government support’. The criteria for choosing them are based on the DTI’s views of South Africa’s comparative advantage (factor endowment, geographic location, trade agreements, etc.) and the impact the sectors will have on reducing unemployment. The focus of official policy-makers on

Page 21: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

13

finding ways to reduce unemployment is understandable, given the almost unprecedented levels of unemployment and underemployment in the country (Kingdon and Knight, 2004). Kaplan argues that sectoral strategies such as those put forward by the DTI can play a positive role by unveiling new opportunities, spurring confidence and overcoming failures in co-ordination. This is particularly the case where the strategies result from a close working relationship between government and industry, and sectoral strategies consequently enjoy the support of the firms in the sector. Kaplan cites ‘anecdotal evidence’ and a survey commissioned by the DTI to show that few firms regard the DTI as having industrial and trade policies suitable for their particular sector, and that only a limited number of them regard these policies as being effective. The exceptions to this are in the clothing/textiles and, more especially, the automotive manufacturing sectors which receive significant government support (see Chapter 5). South Africa has not pursued FDI actively. The GEAR policy makes general reference to the expectation that FDI will respond favourably to more prudent fiscal deficits, the gradual relaxation of exchange controls and low inflation, arguing that such FDI will ‘play an important part in encouraging growth through importing modern technology skills, management expertise, access to international sources of finance and access to global markets’.15 In addition, South Africa has signed over 30 bilateral investment treaties that extend protection to both portfolio and direct investment, and is also a signatory to the World Bank's Multilateral Investment Guarantee Agency (see Gelb, 2003 and 2004a, Jenkins and Thomas, 2002, and Vickers, 2002). Yet South Africa has not implemented any incentives specifically targeted at FDI.16 Gelb and Black (2004a) argue that attracting FDI has not been a major policy thrust of the government since 1994, citing a lack of any clear policy documentation on the issue. Yet GEAR is only one policy document within a much broader political and economic framework within South Africa. The next issue to consider therefore is the extent to which GEAR has combined with other policies and processes to create a positive investment climate in the country.

4.2 The investment climate

Macro- and microeconomic policies in South Africa have had a mixed impact on the investment climate. Table 4.1 illustrates how South Africa compares with its peers, using data from the World Development Report 2005: A Better Investment Climate for Everyone. On overall investment risk, South Africa performs well in comparison with the rest of the world, other middle-income countries and sub-Saharan Africa. A similar picture emerges with regard to the intensity of local competition; South Africa has fewer entrenched monopolies than its peers. The South African government also scores well in terms of policy transparency. Only in the category of regional disparities does it not perform well.

15 See GEAR Appendix 12 (Government of South Africa, 1996). 16 It is an interesting, but separate, debate whether South Africa should offer specific incentives for FDI. Arguments for preferential incentives for FDI centre on the information asymmetries faced by foreign investors and the positive externalities created by technology spillover, etc. Hanson (2001) argues that subsidies to FDI are more likely to be warranted where MNCs make intensive use of elastically supplied factors, where the arrival of MNCs in a market does not lower the market share of domestic firms, and where the FDI generates strong positive productivity spillover for domestic agents. Hanson is sceptical that these conditions hold in most cases, concluding ‘A sensible approach for policy-makers in host countries is to presume that subsidising FDI is unwarranted, unless clear evidence is presented to support the argument that the social returns to FDI exceed the private returns’.

Page 22: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

14

Table 4.1 South Africa’s investment climate performance in comparison

Metric South Africa

World Average

Middle Income Average

Sub-Saharan Africa Average

Investment risk profile

1-12 1= highest risk

10.5 8.8 8.7 7.2

Intensity of local competition

1-7 1= no competition

5.3 4.7 4.6 4.2

Regional disparities in investment climate

1-7 1= no disparities

2.9 3.4 3.1 2.9

Transparency in policy-making

1-7 1= zero transparency

4.3 3.9 3.5 3.8

Given this generally favourable report, it is pertinent to ask why South Africa has not performed better in terms of investment and growth (see next section). In part, this can be attributed to South Africa’s ambitions, which are not to be ‘a well performing African economy’ but to compete on the global stage. However, there is also a sense that the South African economy has not performed as well as it could, or should, have done, given its widely praised macroeconomic record. There is a heated debate about why this is so, which it is impossible to consider fully within the confines of this paper. One set of analyses, however, highlights the fact that the microeconomic reforms have not matched the progress made with the macroeconomy. Distortions have occurred within both the input and output markets, and especially within the labour market.17 The mismatch between macroeconomic and microeconomic policy has created an environment where businesses are not investing and growth rates are disappointing. FDI has also been lacklustre (see below). There has been considerable research into why this is so, given South Africa’s stable macroeconomic and political environment (see Chandra et al., 2000 and 2001a, Gelb, 2003, Gelb and Black, 2004a, and Jenkins and Thomas, 2002). Analysts point to the following problems:

• For market-seeking FDI, the southern African economies are too small and are growing too slowly.

• Regional political instability (especially in Zimbabwe) spills over to South Africa, creating uncertainty for potential investors.

• There are high levels of HIV/AIDS and crime in South Africa. • There is a shortage of skilled labour, not helped by South Africa's bureaucratic and

complex immigration policy. • There is regulatory uncertainty, particularly in the telecommunications, electricity

and transport sectors. This chapter has already hinted that the positive investment climate in South Africa has failed to deliver the sort of growth rates envisaged and certainly not sufficient to make significant inroads into the depth and extent of poverty. The following section discusses the results in more detail.

17 This argument remains extremely controversial. For a good review of wider debates, see Fedderke (2004) and Lewis (2002).

Page 23: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

15

4.3 Investment outcomes

The GEAR programme envisaged ‘a brisk expansion of private sector capital formation’ and ‘an improvement in the employment intensity of investment and output growth’. This has not materialised. Despite a widely admired macroeconomic policy programme, growth and investment in the South African economy have remained disappointingly low since 1994. Total investment remains at around 16% of GDP.18 Expectations were that annual private sector investment would grow at 12% on average between 1995 and 2000. The GEAR document argues further, ‘In the aggregate, these developments are expected to provide sufficient impetus for GDP growth to climb to the targeted 6 percent by the year 2000’. Tables 4.2 and 4.3 show more specifically that outcomes have not matched expectations especially as regards private sector and government investment. Figs. 4.1 and 4.2 demonstrate that, although all sources of fixed capital formation have risen, this has only kept pace with overall economic growth.

Table 4.2 GEAR’s annual growth rate targets for investment (%)

1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 Average Real government investment growth 3.4 2.7 5.4 7.5 16.7 7.1 Real parastatal investment growth 3.0 5.0 10.0 10.0 10.0 7.6 Real private sector investment growth 9.3 9.1 9.3 13.9 17.0 11.7 Additional FDI (US$m.) 155 365 504 716 804 509

Source: Government of South Africa (1996) and South Africa Reserve Bank data. Note: ‘Average’ figures are the arithmetic mean.

Table 4.3 Actual annual investment growth rates (%)

1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 Average Real government investment growth 14.1 7.3 -4.4 -9.6 -0.2 1.4 Real parastatal investment growth 60.2 13.3 13.3 -8.5 6.7 11.7 Real private sector investment growth 8.1 5.5 6.3 -8.8 1.9 2.6 Inward FDI (US$m.)a 818 3,817 561 1,502 877 1,515

Source: Reserve Bank of South Africa Note: a) Data taken from World Investment Report (UNCTAD, 2004). Not directly comparable with ‘additional’ FDI targets in the GEAR document as the latter does not specify what these are additional to. The quantity of FDI has been disappointing when compared with other developing economies. Since 1994, FDI in South Africa has averaged less than 1% of GDP. By comparison, over the same period, FDI/GDP averaged 2.5-3% for Argentina, Brazil, and Mexico, 4-5% for Hungary and the Czech Republic, and 3-5% for Malaysia, the Philippines and Thailand. Furthermore, much of this FDI has been market-seeking (not export-orientated), has been directed to the natural resources sector (rather than manufacturing and services) and has been driven by privatisations rather than being greenfield (Lewis, 2002). The poor investment record has been cited as one of the causes of South Africa’s poor overall economic growth rates. Average growth in the 1990s was a mere 0.94%. Of this Total Factor Productivity (TFP) growth contributed 1.07%, growth in capital 0.44% and the contribution from labour actually fell by 0.58% (Hartzenberg and Stuart, 2002; Fletcher, 2003). These figures show that firms have increasingly managed to increase output by

18 South African Reserve Bank, Quarterly Bulletin No. 231 (2004). For the purposes of this paper, investment is defined as Gross Fixed Capital Formation, excluding portfolio flows.

Page 24: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

16

squeezing existing capital equipment harder and by shedding workers, rather than by investing in new capital equipment or employment.

Table 4.4 Average annual real growth rates of fixed capital stock by sector

1960-70 1970-80 1980-90 1990-2002 1994-2002 Agriculture 2.34 2.68 -0.97 -0.81 -0.27 Mining 1.93 6.19 6.04 0.58 0.44 Manufacturing 7.86 8.19 3.28 2.65 2.44 Electricity, gas and water 5.67 7.90 4.22 -2.37 -2.24 Construction 11.49 10.41 -0.48 -0.25 0.44 Retail 5.37 5.15 1.86 1.73 2.17 Transport, storage and communication 4.76 5.88 1.31 1.45 2.07 Financial 5.00 4.95 3.17 1.45 1.66 Community 7.52 6.47 2.84 1.31 1.06 Total 5.36 6.00 2.79 1.13 1.27 General government 6.09 5.90 -0.13 -1.68 0.77 Public corporations 8.47 13.59 8.98 5.47 0.85 Private corporations 4.41 4.60 4.00 2.57 -0.20

Source: Fletcher (2003)

Fig. 4.1 Relative investment rates in South Africa

90

100

110

120

130

140

150

160

1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004

Gro

ss F

ixed

Inve

stm

ent

(199

4=10

0)

Gross fixed capital form ation Gross fixed capital form ation: General governm ent

Gross fixed capital form ation: Manufacturing Gross fixed capital form ation: Private Sector

Source: Reserve Bank of South Africa

Page 25: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

17

Fig. 4.2 Gross capital formation to GDP ratio

0%

2%

4%

6%

8%

10%

12%

14%

16%

18%

20%

1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003

Gro

ss C

apita

l Fo

rmat

ion

/GD

P

Total capital form ation General governm ent

Public corporations Private enterprise

Source: Reserve Bank of South Africa Growth in manufacturing output averaged only 1% between 1990 and 2001 (Roberts, 2004). Kaplan (2003) has undertaken a comprehensive review of investment in the manufacturing sector and concludes, ‘Over the last two decades, South Africa’s share of developed market and world Manufactured Value Added (MVA) has declined persistently. Given the more rapid rate of population growth in South Africa, the relative decline in South African MVA per capita has been particularly pronounced’. Kaplan’s observation is especially interesting when taken together with the data in Table 4.4, which reveal that the manufacturing sector has in fact shown the highest level of fixed capital formation over the last ten years in South Africa. The simplest explanation for this apparent inconsistency is that the investment which has taken place in the manufacturing sector has simply not been enough and secondly that there has been very little investment in the government’s target sector of ‘labour-intensive manufacturing’. Kaplan summarises the situation as ‘low rates of growth in the labour intensive sectors have combined with overall rising capital intensity resulting in consistent declines in manufacturing employment’. Kaplan uses official data provide by the Government of South Africa to show that total employment in the manufacturing sector fell from 1.5 million in 1990 to 1.3 million in 2003. Given the government’s focus on labour-intensive manufacturing, this is especially disappointing. It is beyond the scope of this paper to enquire into the causes of the low savings, investment and FDI rates in South Africa, though it is clear that these have limited the growth potential of the economy (see Roberts, 2004, for a more detailed review). Chapter 5 considers the extent to which investment incentives may have mitigated a low rate of investment in manufacturing.

Page 26: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

18

Chapter 5: Assessing South Africa’s Incentive Regime

5.1 Incentive policy

Prior to the democratic elections in 1994, the South African Government pursued a deliberate and well funded regional development strategy designed to support the homelands created by apartheid. Further industrial back-up was provided by high tariff barriers and government investment in state-supported enterprises such as SASOL (oil) and ISCOR (steel). The transition to democracy saw the termination of these spatial support programmes and the exposure of the manufacturing economy to global markets as a result of the removal of sanctions and South Africa’s re-integration into the global economy (Nel, 2002). In 1995, only one year after the first democratic election, the Katz Commission reported on a comprehensive review of the country’s tax structure, and recognised the ‘tenuous links between taxation, capital spending and economic growth’. Its primary recommendation was to ‘broaden the tax base and remove or limit deductions, exemptions and other preferences’ (Republic of South Africa, 1995). However, the GEAR document, which followed the Katz Report a year later, was more open to the concept of investment incentives designed to ‘stimulate competitive and labour-absorbing industrial development’. The key section of the GEAR document states the desire to introduce ‘tax incentives for a fixed period to stimulate investment’. The reference in GEAR to incentives for a ‘fixed period’ demonstrates the government’s awareness of the international lessons on incentives. As Chapter 3 pointed out, giving incentives a specific term is one of the key lessons from international best practice. South Africa’s entry into the World Trade Organization (WTO) helped accelerate the elimination of import-substitution programmes and other protectionist policies. For example, in 1997 South Africa phased out the General Export Incentive Scheme (a poorly targeted scheme that the WTO found to be illegal). The GEAR document put forward three specific incentives: an accelerated depreciation scheme to ‘enable existing manufacturing entities to expand in response to the challenge of globalisation’, second, a tax holiday scheme aimed at ‘new projects in key regions and industries, designed to favour labour-absorbing manufacturing activities,’ and third a set of incentives to assist small-scale enterprises. The government phased out the tax holiday scheme as early as 1999, following internal reviews showing it to be expensive, poorly targeted and ineffectual. However, the accelerated depreciation scheme and the incentives for small businesses have remained. Other incentives were developed and implemented following GEAR, including the Motor Industry Development Programme and the Strategic Industrial Programme, which are discussed further in Section 5.4. The set of incentives to support small businesses were proposed both as a means of promoting labour-intensive growth and also as a vehicle for enhancing Black Economic Empowerment. GEAR also flagged the creation of a number of matching grant-based incentive schemes for technological innovation and skill creation. The absolute and relative level of expenditure is small, however, and these measures will not be discussed further in this paper. Finally, in part response to the poor record in generating additional investment, provincial economic development agencies have been set up in each of the nine provinces, the most active being in Guateng, Western Cape and KwaZulu-Natal. These agencies tend to focus on investment promotion, actively marketing nationally available incentives and the provision of key infrastructure. There is almost no scope, however, for the provinces to implement tax

Page 27: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

19

incentives, given their reliance on national transfers.19 Municipal governments have more opportunity to affect the investment climate (by reducing the red tape surrounding planning, etc.) and to reduce property rates and/or utility charges for services such as sanitation and electricity. Cape Town municipality, for example, is currently considering investment incentives. Though the primary focus is on reducing red tape, it is also considering reductions in utility charges in certain, very poor, localities within the city for new and expanding businesses.20

5.2 Tax structure and incentives

The broad thrust of South Africa’s fiscal policy since 1994 has been to lower tax rates and broaden the scope of the policy in order to improve the efficiency of the overall tax system. In consequence, the top marginal rate of tax on personal income has fallen from 45% in 1990 to 40% in 2003 and the corporate tax rate has come down from 50% to 30% over the same period. There is a secondary tax of 12.5% on dividends distributed to shareholders. Branches of foreign companies with management outside the country are subject to a 40% tax rate. South Africa also has a capital gains tax21 and VAT of 14%. Like the global norm, nominal interest payments are deductible from taxable income. Despite the praise given to South Africa for its relatively simple and broad-based tax structure, a surprising number of tax and grant incentives exist. Annex 2 collates a comprehensive directory of those currently available. Reviewing this list reveals some interesting observations, as follows:

• There are an equal number (14-17) of ‘on-budget’ grants and ‘off-budget’ tax incentives. The number of policy-specific grants has burgeoned over the past decade. The DTI accounts for these grants transparently through the annual reporting of expenditure.

• The level of spend, however, is heavily skewed towards tax incentives. An accurate

assessment of the revenue forgone through these incentives is not therefore possible, as South Africa does not yet compute ‘tax expenditures’.22 Kaplan (2003) estimates the forgone revenue from the Motor Industrial Development Programme at 8.4 billion Rand in 2002. This programme and the Strategic Investment Programme totalled 9 billion Rand foregone in 2002/3, over 900% of the value attributed to the on-budget grant incentives.

• There is a set of both grants and tax incentives aimed at supporting small and

medium-sized enterprises. This includes a CIT rate of 15% and the Small and Medium Manufacturers Development Programme. The rationale behind the government’s policy of supporting small businesses is that they are both employment-intensive and part of the black economic empowerment agenda.

19 For example, the Western Cape Province collected only 7% of its own revenue in 2002/3, with the remainder coming from central government allocations. http://www.capegateway.gov.za/Text/2004/3/budgetstateone.pdf. 20 Interview with Interim Manager, City of Cape Town Economic Development Agency, July 2004. 21 Effective rates are between 0% and 17.5% depending on who is affected. See PricewaterhouseCoopers (2002). 22 The exception to this is the Strategic Investment Programme (SIP), which has a ceiling for forgone revenue, and reports specifically on revenue forgone. 600 million Rand has been forgone in revenue since its launch in 2001.

Page 28: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

20

• There are also a number of development finance institutions such as the Investment Development Corporation, the Land Bank and Khula.23 The precise amount of subsidy embedded in these ‘soft loans’ is difficult to estimate. As a rough estimate, however, the IDC committed 4.8 billion Rand in loans or equity in 2004. Assuming its debt and equity investments amount to 2.5% discounted over commercial rates of return,24 this equates to a subsidy of 120 million Rand. The IDC plays a significant role, financing 12% of gross fixed capital formation in manufacturing between 1998 and 2000 (Roberts, 2004). Access to loans and equity from these institutions is limited and discretionary.

• South Africa has a fledgling system of Industrial Development Zones (IDZs) which

offer ‘Customs Secured Areas’ exempt from excise duties, VAT and import duty on assets and inputs used in the production of exports. The IDZs also provide dedicated customs officials (to help speed up the administration surrounding importing/exporting) and key infrastructure. They do not, however, provide for concessions on regulations such as labour laws and health and safety legislation or environmental safeguards.

While GEAR refers to the need for ‘labour-intensive manufacturing’, this is not uniformly the policy objective of many of the incentives offered. As will be discussed in Section 5.3, many of the incentives support capital-, not labour-, intensive industries. Furthermore, incentives are offered in each sector, primary, tertiary and secondary. This may be an effort to be ‘fair’ to each sector and each segment of the economy, or may simply be a response to political lobbying. Either way, the result is an incentive regime which appears to lack strategic focus. Section 5.3 investigates in more detail how South Africa’s incentive regime matches up in comparison with international best practice.

5.3 Evaluation of South Africa’s incentives: international best practice

Through both design and trial and error, South Africa has avoided many of the worst examples of incentives. The positive features of the regime (using Section 3.3 as a guide) are:

• Corporate income tax of 30% is comparable with that in other countries in the region and other emerging market economies. Many argue, however, that the additional 12.5% tax on dividends paid pushes South Africa into the top tier of income tax countries when compared with its peers (Bolnick, 2004; Fletcher, 2003; PricewaterhouseCoopers, 2002).

• Apart from a brief period (1996-9), the government has eschewed tax holidays, one of

the least effective investment incentives. • Most incentives are well designed, well targeted and have a specific policy goal. The

40-20-20-20 depreciation schedule effectively targets additional rather than existing investment. The SIP is a well-designed Investment Credit Allowance scheme, though it is not possible to say yet what the redundancy rate is. The MIDP has successfully

23 Khula Enterprise Finance Limited is an agency of the Department of Trade and Industry established in 1996 to facilitate access to finance for small and medium enterprises. Khula provides both financial and non-financial assistance to small enterprises through various delivery channels including commercial banks, retail financial intermediaries and micro credit outlets. 24 IDC website states that ‘loans are risk-related and based on prime lending rates’. Experience shows that IDC loans are between 2 and 3% lower than a corresponding commercial loan for a similar project. http://www.mallinicks.co.za/invest_info.

Page 29: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

21

stimulated additional investment in the motor industry, as designed, but at an unknown cost (see Box 5.1).

• South African exporting firms can obtain relief on duties paid on products used in

the manufacture of exports, even if the inputs are sourced from within the SACU region. Furthermore, in the IDZs exporters can also import capital machinery duty-free, thus providing effective support for manufacturing exports.

• The DTI and the National Treasury carry out regular assessments of the incentives

on offer and which are removed or reformed accordingly. The policy process shows that the government is learning from past experience, and the most recent incentive (the Strategic Investment Programme) contains most of the features of a well designed incentive scheme (Bolnick, 2004).

In sum, the South African investment regime has much to recommend it, and it compares well with that in other countries in the region. However, there is also evidence that the regime is not as much in line with international best practice as might at first appear. Key problems include:

• Poor awareness of existing incentives, especially on the part of small and medium-scale enterprises. Only between 7% and 35% of South Africa’s small businesses are aware of existing incentives for which they are eligible (UNCTAD, 2003). A separate survey by Business Map (2003) and the World Bank supports this point.

• For all but the largest schemes, application and approval processes are excessively

bureaucratic and complex, especially for small and medium-sized enterprises. Businesses view the costs of applying as sometimes higher than the benefits provided.25 By way of illustration, a large international accountancy firm in South Africa has a practice dedicated to assisting clients to apply and qualify for incentives. Further anecdotal evidence of this problem is provided by the case study of Bell Equipment (Annex 4), which complains bitterly about the level of bureaucracy involved in many of the DTI’s grant-based incentives.

• Too many incentives lack sunset clauses, for the scheme itself and for the duration of

the benefit provided. Both are needed to stop industries or businesses surviving on incentives, rather than using them simply to get started. The MIDP (see Section 5.4), for example, has been extended twice, and may be again, creating uncertainty for investors.

• South Africa has a relatively low tariff structure and is fully compliant with its WTO

obligations. Tariff protection in manufacturing decreased from 15.6% in 1997 to 11.8% in 2002, but high rates still apply to certain manufactured products: textiles, clothing and related products remain the most heavily protected, with the ad valorem components of certain tariffs ranging up to 60% (WTO, 2003).

• South Africa also suffers from overlapping government agencies, each with a degree

of responsibility for designing, budgeting and implementing incentives. The National Treasury focuses on costs and forgone revenue, whereas the DTI is more

25 UNCTAD (2003). A similar situation exists with the Sector Education Training Authority awards, which cover 75% of training costs. But businesses, especially small ones, complain bitterly that the administrative procedures around access to this funding are so cumbersome that the net benefit is marginal at best.

Page 30: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

22

focused on ‘marketing’ South Africa as an investment destination. The revenue service is most concerned with administrative simplicity. Semi-autonomous government agencies, such as Khula, the IDC, the National Research Foundation and the International Trade Administration Commission (ITAC), also play a role in various incentives.

• Too many incentives are applied in a discretionary manner, including requests for

adjustments in import tariffs (see below). This complicates and slows down the approval process and adds to the level of uncertainty faced by companies.

• Outside the five IDZs, there is no clear strategy on tariff protection or relief. Firms

may seek tariff protection from imports for their sector, and rebates or more general tariff reductions on inputs. Any manufacturing company, exporting or not, may apply to the Board on Tariffs and Trade for tariff adjustments which must then be approved on a discretionary basis by the Minister for Trade and Industry. The process whereby applications for tariff adjustments or rebates are considered, appraised and evaluated is opaque and potentially open to abuse.

• The government tends to introduce grant incentives in response to lobbying by

different sectors within both the public and the private sectors without a rigorous ex ante assessment of the costs and benefits or a coherent strategic justification.26

Finally, there is a dearth of existing evidence on the efficiency or otherwise of South Africa’s investment incentive regime.27 There are internal reviews of specific programmes, commissioned by the relevant department and usually undertaken by independent outside consultants. While the majority of these do provide a critical evaluation of the incentive scheme under review, they tend to lack a rigorous analysis of the efficacy and the efficiency of the incentive. Instead, the evaluation focuses on whether the incentive has/has not led to a rise in investment, but not the counter-factual (would investment have risen anyway?), or whether the benefits were worth the costs. 28 South Africa does not yet calculate and report the ‘tax expenditures’ of revenue forgone through its tax incentives, with the exception of the SIP.

5.4 MIDP and SIP

It is worth looking in more detail at the Strategic Investment Programme (SIP) and the Motor Industry Development Programme (MIDP). These two programmes are financially the largest and also the schemes which have had the biggest impact on FDI (Business Map, 2002). Box 5.1 provides details on how the MIDP and SIP programmes operate.

26 As recently as June 2004, new incentives were created for the film industry. Incentives for the Back Office Processing sector are under consideration. 27‘Up to now, assessment of the impact of our industrial policy in general, and of particular policies, has been lacking’. DTI (2001a) p. 43. 28 For example, the mid-term review of the MIDP undertaken in 2000 (see Damoense and Simon, 2004).

Page 31: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

23

Box 5.1 MIDP and SIP

The Motor Industry Development Programme (MIDP) was initiated in 1995. It entailed a phasing down of tariffs; a removal of local content requirements; duty-free imports of components up to 27% of the wholesale value of the vehicle; and duty rebate credits earned on exports. Duty credits are tradable and can either be used to import local content duty-free, or sold to provide a separate source of revenue for the exporter. The MIDP has been hailed as a great success, having achieved significant growth in vehicle imports and exports as well as substantial investments by major vehicle manufacturers such as BMW, Volkswagen and Toyota (Black and Mitchell, 2002). The SIP is a more recent programme introduced in November 2001. The sole tax benefit is an initial capital allowance (ICA) of 50 or 100%, depending on the qualifying points score; points are awarded for the ‘fit’ of the project to strategic goals and employment creation. The ICA is additional to the normal accelerated depreciation provided through existing legislation. As companies are able to carry forward paper losses, the combined result is that companies operating under the SIP can operate in a tax-free environment for many years. The qualifying criterion is that projects must have a capital investment of at least R 50 million. The SIP imposes a ceiling (up to R600m.) on the cost of the industrial assets that may qualify for the ICA for any one project. Apart from this, the law sets a ceiling of R3 billion on the cumulative amount of ICA benefits that can be granted under the programme. The qualifying criteria are explicit and substantive, applications are gazetted, awards are reported annually, and revenue costs have to be monitored. The SIP is very attractive to investors and yet is fiscally reasonable; the initial allowance substantially lowers the Marginal Effective Tax Rate (METR) for most projects, while yielding revenue in the medium run (Bolnick, 2004). The primary aim of the SIP is to contribute to the growth, development and competitiveness of specific sectors of industry by providing investment allowances (tax relief) to industrial projects that qualify. The key objective of the programme is to attract investment to South Africa in order to upgrade industry and create employment opportunities. However, this incentive is relatively new and there are little data on which to assess its performance. While the SIP is well-designed (see Bolnick, 2004), its impact in terms of generating additional investment is unclear. The DTI recently reviewed SIP.29 The MIDP is a longer-running programme which has become the subject of much debate (see Black and Mitchell, 2002; Barnes et al., 2003; Flatters, 2002). There is a consensus that the scheme has undoubtedly led to significant new investment in the automobile sector and associated downstream products such as leather seating. The debate surrounding the MIDP concerns whether this has been worth the cost to customers, taxpayers and the government in terms of forgone revenue. Table 5.1 looks in more detail at how these two programmes measure up against the lessons developed in Section 3.3 on what makes for an effective and efficient incentive. It shows that both programmes have many of the characteristics of a well designed and effective incentive scheme. However, in terms of generating ‘labour-intensive manufacturing’, they have, on the balance of the evidence, failed. The motor industry in South Africa is extremely capital-intensive (Black and Mitchell, 2002; Damoense and Simon, 2004; Roberts, 2004) and the SIP has resulted in very few businesses which generate any significant long-term employment.30 In fact, as Kaplan shows, the manufacturing sector has become increasingly capital-intensive over the past decade, requiring skilled labour (in short supply) rather than unskilled (in abundant supply). Annex 4 provides a case study of a South African manufacturer and exporting firm which has benefited from MIDP - Bell Equipment. Bell Equipment employs 1,000 people in its South

29 Neither the terms of reference nor the results of the review were made available to the author by the DTI. 30 Discussion by the author with staff of the National Treasury and Revenue Service.

Page 32: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

24

African facility. On average, it receives R32m. a year from the MIDP, equivalent to R32,000 per job per annum (not taking account of indirect employment). On the assumption that Bell Equipment would close were it not for the MIDP, the government of South Africa is paying R32,000 per annum per job in this case. Using the average minimum wage in South Africa as a proxy alternative,31 this figure appears extremely high. Bell Equipment makes intensive use of fixed capital and, to an even greater extent, working capital.

Table 5.1 Analysis of South Africa’s two primary indirect investment incentives

Effective and Efficient Incentives

SIP MIDP

Effectiveness: Stimulate the desired investment (in the sector or location) with minimum revenue leakage, including minimal opportunities for tax planning.

Approval clearly linked to policy goals. Has been rapidly taken up by industry but at an unknown redundancy rate. Loss of revenue is approaching the R3bn ceiling.

Has effectively stimulated motor industry investment which rose from R85.4m. in 1995 to R2,345m. in 2001 (Roberts, 2004).

'Evaluability': Are evaluated on a regular basis against pre-agreed criteria.

Regular reporting to Parliament of revenue forgone and which companies are benefiting. Review of SIP in 2004 by DTI.

Substantially met. Evaluated both internally by government and externally by commentators. But exact costs to customers and revenue loss unknown.

Transparency: Are transparent and easy to understand for corporations.

Legislation is clear on how points are awarded and why.

Legislation is clear and close interaction between industry and government has helped ensure rapid take-up.

Precision: Have clearly specified and quantified objectives, which are expressed precisely in legislation.

Yes. Yes.

Stability and Duration: Are not changed frequently. Have a well publicised finite life (in terms of time or revenue loss ceilings) both for the scheme and for the benefits provided to individual firms.

Substantially met. No changes as yet to criteria and benefits. Clear end date (2005 or when R3bn forgone revenue envelope is met, whichever is sooner). May or may not be extended.

Partly met. Reviewed and changed in 2002, extended until 2007, then to 2012. Uncertain future after that.

Are developed, implemented, administered and monitored by one agency.

No. Approval committee made up of several departments (DTI, NT, SARS). Agency co-ordination and co-operation is a problem.a

No. DTI, ITAC, NT and SARS all involved. Agency co-ordination and co-operation is a problem.

Have low administration costs to both government and firms.

Yes. Only 4% of incentive budget used in administration by government.b The size of the benefit to firms dwarfs any application and reporting costs.

Yes. Only 4% of incentive budget used in administration by government. The size of the benefit to firms dwarfs any application and reporting costs.

Are non-discretionary and applied consistently against a set of open criteria.

No. Applicants must apply and be recommended by a committee to the Minister of Trade and Industry.

Substantially, yes. However, there is some debate about definitions of ‘motor vehicle’ etc.

Notes: a) Private discussions with a large multinational accountancy and consulting firm in Johannesburg, which has virtually cornered the market for helping firms apply for incentives; b) Government of South Africa, Estimates of National Expenditure, February 2004.

31 Minimum wages in South Africa are determined by sector and differ according to the exact nature of the job. The range is between 650 and 1,356 per month. http://www.labour.gov.za.

Page 33: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

25

Chapter 6: Marginal Effective Tax Rate Analysis

Given the discussion so far, the salient question is, ‘in those sectors which benefit from incentives, has there been higher investment than would have occurred otherwise?’ This is a difficult question to answer. A full answer would require a comprehensive survey of firms that had both chosen and not chosen to invest. However, one indicator of the effectiveness of tax incentives is to use Marginal Effective Tax Rate (METR) analysis, which is a standard technical method for evaluating the impact of the tax system on investment decisions (Box 6.1). Bolnick (2004) has amended a METR model originally developed by Dunn and Pellechio (1990). This ‘Bolnick model’ allows the user to evaluate the impact of different tax incentives on the METR faced by investors. In turn, this provides some indication of the likelihood that an investment would have been stimulated, given changes in the METRs.

Box 6.1 The Marginal Effective Tax Rate (METR)

The METR measures the extent to which the tax system reduces the real rate of return on investment, at the margin. More formally, the METR is defined as:- METR = (RORbT – RORaT)/RORbT where RORbT and RORaT are the real rates of return before and after tax, and ROR is: Present discounted value of annual net earnings = PDV(E) Capital Expenditure K For example, let us assume that the rate of return on an incremental capital project is 20% before tax and 10% after, from the equation: METR = (20-10)/20 = 0.5 or 50%. The METR of 50% indicates that the tax system diminishes the real rate of return by 50%. The METR shows how much the tax system distorts investment incentives by driving a ‘wedge’ between the underlying profitability of a project and the after-tax return to the investor. The METR can be compared across projects, sectors, and countries. The larger the METR, the bigger the tax wedge. Differences in the METR reveal tax-induced biases in the incentives that drive the allocation of productive resources. In some cases, the biases are deliberate aims of policy, such as preferences for exporters or for manufacturers in certain locations. In many cases, however, the biases are unintended consequences of the tax system. It is possible to have a METR which is zero and yet also revenue-positive, as long as the rates of return before and after tax are the same. Bolnick shows how this can be the case with, for example, 100% deductibility of investment in the first year. The tax wedge appears at two levels—one arising from taxes on the company, and the second stemming from taxes on the remittance of earnings or capital gains to the owners. There are thus two METRS. The first is in terms of the returns seen by the company undertaking the investment. The second analyses the rate of return to the equity holders themselves rather than the company. The present paper uses the second approach. It is the approach recommended by Bolnick, since it gives a better indication of the impact of the tax system on investment decisions. This is especially pertinent in South Africa, which has a substantial secondary tax of 12.5% on companies in addition to the standard corporate income tax of 30%. It is important to recognise that this METR analysis only addresses how much the overall tax and incentive system reduces the relative rate of return to equity holders32 before and after tax. It says nothing about the absolute rates of return to different projects. It is possible to have two projects with identical METRs but with very different rates of return. The Bolnick 32 As discussed in Box 6.1, the model reflects cash flow to equity holders. Cash flow is thus determined after taxes on dividend distributions and after the taxation of capital gains on any sale of the enterprise.

Page 34: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

26

model does not allow for any judgement on whether an enterprise is more profitable in one sector than another. Rather, it analyses how much the tax and incentive system distorts the decision to invest in that particular project. Some projects with very high rates of return can remain profitable even with a very high METR. Other projects will remain unviable, however low the METR. Adjustments in the METR are most likely to have an impact on projects that have a rate of return very close to the threshold rate for the investor, in other words the most marginal investments. Tables 6.1 to 6.5 apply the Bolnick model to hypothetical manufacturing, agricultural and tourism/services firms in South Africa. Annex 3 details how the Bolnick model was configured to represent the South African investment climate. The model only allows for the incorporation of tax incentives, not cash grants. There are three financing scenarios shown: debt at 0% of financing (equivalent to full equity financing); debt providing 28% of financing; and debt providing 50% of financing. The more likely scenario for South African companies is for debt to provide about 28% of all financing. The 50% ratio more accurately reflects the situation for smaller companies, which would use owner equity to start up and be less able to secure debt financing. This ‘base case’ is extended to include the accelerated depreciation allowances provided for each type of enterprise. Separate models are developed for the SIP and for SMMEs. The SIP is available only to large corporations. SMME tax incentives include the immediate expensing of capital equipment and 15% CIT rate. The SMME scenario also includes a higher cost of debt (14% as against 12%) which they are more likely to face. The SIP and SMME incentives are mutually exclusive, but both build on and include the accelerated depreciation allowances. The Bolnick model includes the effects of import tariffs on initial investments. However, it does not provide for an analysis of the impact of indirect taxes on working capital inputs. As a result, it is not possible to model the impact of the MIDP on the METR.

Table 6.1 Base case: Asset structure of different business sectors

Land Buildings M&E Vehicles Manufacturing 50% 20% 20% 10% Agriculture 60% 15% 20% 5% Tourism/services 20% 30% 20% 30%

Table 6.2 How capital structure affects the METR in different sectors

1 2 3 0% debt 28% debt 50% debt Manufacturing 35.78 31.15 27.03 Agriculture 33.41 28.49 23.84 Tourism/Services 38.59 34.42 31.29

Note: Does not include accelerated depreciation allowed with each category of enterprise.

Page 35: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

27

Table 6.3 How incentive schemes affect the METR for manufacturing businesses

1 2 3 0% debt 28% debt 50% debt Manufacturing 35.78 31.15 27.03 W/ Accelerated depreciationa 34.52 30.55 26.79 W/ SIP 50% 27.19 23.88 20.90 W/ SIP 100% 22.52 19.35 17.36 As an SMME 27.26 25.46 24.42 R&D Investment 31.33 27.42 24.20

Note: a) 40-20-20-20

Table 6.4 How incentive schemes affect the METR for agricultural businesses

1 2 3 0% debt 28% debt 50% debt Agriculture 33.41 28.49 23.84 W/ Accelerated depreciationa 32.52 27.55 23.00 W/ SIP 50% 27.70 23.08 19.04 W/ SIP 100% 24.22 20.21 16.58 As an SMME 27.33 23.42 19.93

Note: a) 50-30-20

Table 6.5 How incentive schemes affect the METR for tourism/services businesses

1 2 3 0% debt 28% debt 50% debt Tourism/services 38.59 34.42 31.29 W/ Accelerated depreciationa 38.20 34.16 31.17 W/ SIP 50% 30.96 28.09 25.77 W/ SIP 100% 26.53 23.68 21.87 As an SMME 33.93 31.18 29.42

Note: a) 20-20-20-20-20 assumed for ‘hotel equipment’ Table 6.2 illustrates two important results. First, as would be expected, debt-financed projects face a significantly lower METR than equity-financed firms because of the tax shield provided to interest payments. The rate of return is higher for debt- over equity-financed projects in the manufacturing, agricultural and services sectors. The imposition of South Africa’s standard corporate tax regime reduces the rate of return in each sector by roughly the same proportion. Second, under each financial structure scenario the METR is highest for the tourism/service sector, and lowest for agriculture, with manufacturing enterprises midway between the two. Analysis of the model shows that this is principally due to the differences in import taxes (rather than corporate taxes on profits, dividend taxes or capital gains tax). The tourism/services model in Table 6.1 assumes that the capital start-up costs of such enterprises are skewed towards imported capital (vehicles, machinery and equipment) rather than locally procured capital (land or buildings). This is probably a safe assumption in terms of the relative mix of start-up capital. However, the absolute level of fixed capital investment by a tourism or services firm is likely to be less than that for manufacturing or agricultural enterprises. Tourist and service enterprises are more likely to invest in human and working capital. Therefore, it is probably the case that tourism and services firms face a lower METR than manufacturing or agricultural enterprises. The Bolnick model does not allow for different absolute levels of investment at start-up.

Page 36: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

28

Although flawed, this application of the model illustrates the importance of import taxes in determining the METR of a project. Agricultural enterprises, for example, face a lower METR than manufacturing enterprises (assuming equal absolute investment) because a greater proportion of manufacturing enterprises’ capital is imported. The MIDP, which provides automobile manufacturers with tax relief on imported parts used in export production, targets this issue very effectively. The MIDP is extremely important to the automobile manufacturers precisely because it eliminates one of the largest tax burdens they face, tariffs on imported parts, and provides a second revenue stream if the credits are sold to another importer. Table 6.3 looks in more detail at how South Africa’s investment incentives affect the METR for manufacturing firms. The main features of this analysis are the following:

• Accelerated depreciation provides a very small improvement in the METR, especially as the debt/equity ratio increases.

• SIP at the 50% level provides a reduction in the METR similar to that provided by SMME incentives.

• SIP at the 100% level provides a substantial METR reduction, greater than that provided to SMMEs.

• R&D investment incentives, which are especially applicable to manufacturing firms, provide a small but noticeable reduction in the METR.

• All incentives, but especially the SMME incentives and accelerated depreciation, provide a greater reduction in the METR when applied to firms that are equity-financed.

This last point makes intuitive sense. Equity-financed firms face a greater tax burden than debt-financed firms and incentives help to reduce that burden. Equity-financed firms are more likely to be small firms (unable to obtain credit at an early stage of development) and large public companies (more able to raise private or public equity). While the incentives available to manufacturing firms provide noticeable reductions in the METR, this is less than that provided by the deductibility of interest payments. In other words, the biggest incentive manufacturing firms face is to ‘lever-up’. As shown in Table 6.4, accelerated depreciation allowances are marginally more generous for agricultural enterprises than for manufacturing firms. Yet the benefits are still small. Table 6.5 shows that accelerated depreciation allowances for the tourism/services sector make even less of an impact on the METR than in manufacturing because this sector is less fixed-capital-intensive. The SIP also rewards large fixed-capital-intensive investments by requiring investments of at least R50m. As a result, manufacturing firms benefit more from the SIP than agricultural or tourism/services firms. The SIP, especially at the 100% level, provides the largest reduction in the METR of any of the formal incentive programmes. At the 50% level the reduction in the METR is small but not insignificant and similar to that provided to SMMEs. But at the 100% level the SIP has far greater impact than SMME incentives – especially as the debt/equity ratio rises. This is perhaps a surprising result. The SIP programme, allocated to a few large capital-intensive firms, provides more generous relief than the incentives provided to SMMEs. Even though the SIP is not automatically available, this result demonstrates that small firms in South Africa may face a higher tax burden, after relief, than large public companies. This chapter has used a simple METR model to illustrate a few facts about the South African tax and incentive system. First, it shows that import taxes matter a lot in the calculation of

Page 37: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

29

the total tax wedge. South Africa is ahead of its WTO obligations, but tariffs on imports of capital equipment and inputs remain high relative to consumer goods. This makes intuitive sense if the intention is to create incentives for firms to choose labour-intensive techniques. The irony is that, while the tariff system meets the goal of supporting ‘labour-intensive manufacturing’, the incentive schemes do not. Finally, South Africa offers incentives to both SMME and very large and capital-intensive companies, and this appears inconsistent and contradictory.

Page 38: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

30

Chapter 7: Conclusions and ways forward

This paper has begun to analyse whether the existing fiscal incentives available to the South African manufacturing sector effectively improve the incentive to invest. The literature on investment incentives (both tax and grants) is extremely cautious about their ability to induce additional investment and consistently highlights instead the fundamentals affecting the firms’ decisions to invest, namely, expectations of future demand, the cost of capital, economic and political certainty, and the existence of strong legal institutions and good infrastructure. The literature also acknowledges that incentives remain a popular tool, despite the dearth of evidence in their support. Given this reality, there is also a broad consensus by policy analysts on the characteristics of an effective and efficient investment incentive, characteristics such as minimal revenue loss, simple and transparent rules, revenue caps, sunset clauses and low administrative costs. Since 1996, the system of incentives in South Africa has broadly attempted to follow the principles outlined in the GEAR policy document, namely, the desire to increase ‘labour-intensive manufacturing’. This is understandable given the extremely high unemployment and underemployment in the country and the associated economy-wide costs. Over the past decade, South Africa has adopted a cautious approach to incentives, abolishing some and introducing others. On the whole, there has been a reduction in the number and complexity of tax incentives and grants, and there is more emphasis on evaluating their impact. The result is that, today, South Africa operates a system of investment incentives that is comparatively well defined, effectively implemented, and evaluated on a regular basis. The system thus has many merits and is better aligned with ‘best practice’ than that of most other African economies. The effects of these and other macroeconomic reforms have, however, been disappointing. The lacklustre investment performance in South Africa over the past decade of democracy shows that incentives have not been effective in delivering the sorts of levels of investment (either domestic or foreign) needed to raise the economic growth rate above the 2-3% range. Perhaps most importantly, there has been very little investment in the key target area of labour-intensive manufacturing. The critique of South Africa’s investment incentive regime has been both qualitative and quantitative. It is clear that South Africa has experienced a learning curve with its incentive schemes. Those most recently introduced are well targeted to achieve a specific policy goal and are the subject of scrutiny by government and non-governmental commentators alike. Many, but not all, are on-budget or have specifically calculated tax expenditures. South Africa has a competitive corporate tax rate and supports manufactured exports by providing duty relief on inputs and a fledgling set of Export Processing Zones. The qualitative review also highlights a few areas of concern. First, despite rationalisation, there remains a proliferation of direct incentives with overlapping and sometimes incoherent mandates. Many incentives are too bureaucratically complex and there is confusion and uncertainty about the eligibility and approval process for many schemes. Too many incentives are discretionary, in particular the opportunity provided to firms to lobby government for tariff protection. Sunset clauses are being increasingly used, but this practice needs to become systematic for all incentives. The largest incentive schemes in South Africa in terms of expenditure are tax incentives, which are principally ‘off-budget’ (with the exception of the SIP). The calculation of ‘tax expenditures’ would be an effective first step towards a more rigorous analysis of the efficacy and (crucially) efficiency of the various tax incentives on offer. There is also some evidence that South Africa does not market its incentive schemes well.

Page 39: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

31

The quantitative review applied the Bolnick model to calculate marginal effective tax rates. The results indicate that most widely available incentives have no significant effect on the METR of manufacturing enterprises. The financial structure of the firm has a far greater effect. A striking result is that manufacturing enterprises face a particular hurdle in having to pay import taxes on capital. Faced with a heavy tax burden on imported capital, as well as a host of other issues in South Africa’s unpredictable business environment, it is not surprising that the effect of incentives on the METR is minor. This goes some way towards explaining why investment (and especially labour-intensive manufacturing investment) has continued to stagnate despite the existence of incentives. The flagship SIP and SMME incentives, which produce the largest effects, reduce the marginal effective tax rate by 17%. It is ironic, however, that some of the incentive schemes with the largest impact (SIP and MIDP) support capital-intensive rather than labour-intensive manufacturing. The fact that South Africa subsidises both very large and very small firms equally does not appear to make strategic sense. Rather than subsidising both very small and very large firms, in the hope that these firms will generate employment, it would appear a priori more logical to target the subsidy directly, by, for example, providing a double tax deduction on low-wage labour expense for all firms. Providing employment subsidies, either directly to the employer or through employees, would be a simpler and more transparent way of creating incentives for greater employment than trying to select which firms are the most likely to create jobs. The case study of Bell Equipment in Annex 4 provides only one data point, and many more are needed to get a clearer picture. However, its feedback does appear to support the wider conclusions of this paper. Bell Equipment welcomes the benefits provided by the MIDP and is desperate to retain them. It does, however, see the MIDP as a form of compensation for a volatile exchange rate, a manufacturing location far from its main market and an increasing regulatory and taxation burden on its business. Given these conclusions, the key recommendations of this paper are as follows

• to continue the process of rationalisation, and focus all incentives in support of a clearly defined strategy. One way to do this might be to set a cap of (say) 20 fiscal incentives.

• to market existing incentives more effectively. • to introduce sunset clauses both for the incentive schemes themselves and for the

period a firm may benefit. This would help ensure that firms do not come to rely on incentives to survive, but instead that incentives reduce the risk of the initial and subsequent investments.

• to simplify the application and approval process so that decisions are quicker and more transparent.

• to bring all incentive schemes ‘on-budget’ by using tax expenditure analysis. This will help to illuminate each incentive and determine its effectiveness and efficiency in achieving the stated objectives.

• over time, to realign incentives to target directly the stated policy goal, namely greater employment, rather than ‘labour-intensive manufacturing’ - a fuzzy term which is hard to identify.

• finally, in common with other reviews of incentive systems, South Africa needs to continue to tackle the ‘big picture’ issues currently acting as a disincentive for firms to invest in labour-intensive manufacturing. A reading of the literature, informed by the case study of Bell Equipment, points toward areas such as currency (in)stability, crime, skills shortages and the ever increasing regulatory and tax burden businesses face when hiring labour.

Page 40: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

32

Bibliography

Barnes, J., Kaplinsky, R. and Morris, M. (2003) Industrial Policy in Developing Economies: Developing Dynamic Comparative Advantage in the South African Automobile Sector, paper presented at the Trade and Industry Policy Strategies (TIPS)/Development Policy Research Unit (DPRU, University of Cape Town) Annual Forum, 2003, held at Indaba Hotel, 8-10 September. Black, A. and Mitchell, S. (2002) Policy in the South African Motor Industry: Goals, Incentives and Outcomes, paper presented at the TIPS Annual Forum, 2002. Boadway, R., Flatters, F. and Chua, D. (1995) Indirect Taxes & Investment Incentives in Malaysia., in A. Shah (ed.) Fiscal Incentives for Investment and Innovation, Washington, DC: World Bank. Boadway, R. and Shah, A. (1995) Perspectives on the Role of Investment Incentives, in A. Shah (ed.), Fiscal Incentives for Investment and Innovation, Washington, DC: World Bank. Bolnick, B. (2004) Effectiveness and Economic Impact of Tax Incentives in the Southern Africa Development Community (SADC) Region, report by Nathan-MSI Group to the SADC Tax Subcommittee. Gabarone, Botswana: SADC. Business Map (2003) Investment 2002: Challenges and Opportunities, Johannesburg: The Business Map Foundation. www.businessmap.co.za. Chandra, V., Moorty, L., Rajaratnam, B., and Schaefer, K. (2000) Constraints to Growth and Employment in South Africa: Report No. 1, Statistics from the Large Manufacturing Firm Survey, Informal Discussion Paper No. 14, Washington, DC: World Bank. Chandra, V., Moorty, L., Rajaratnam, B., and Schaefer, K. (2001) Constraints to Growth and Employment in South Africa: Report No. 2, Evidence from the Small Medium and Micro-Enterprise Survey, Informal Discussion Paper No. 15, Washington, DC: World Bank. Chua, D. (1995) Tax Incentives, in P. Shome (ed.), Tax Policy Handbook, International Monetary Fund, Fiscal Affairs Department, Washington, DC: World Bank. Damoense, M. and Simon, A. (2004) An Analysis of the Impact of the First Phase of South Africa’s Motor Industry Development Programme (MIDP), 1995-2000, Development Southern Africa, Vol. 21, No. 2. pp. 251-68. Department of Trade and Industry (2001a) Micro-economic Reform Strategy, Pretoria: Government of South Africa. www.dti.gov.za. Department of Trade and Industry (2001b) Driving Competitiveness: Towards a New Integrated Industrial Strategy for Sustainable Employment and Growth, Pretoria: Government of South Africa. www.dti.gov.za. Department of Trade and Industry (2002) Integrated Manufacturing Strategy, Pretoria: Government of South Africa. www.dti.gov.za. Dimson, E., Marsh, P. and Staunton, M. (2003) Global Evidence on the Equity Risk Premium, Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, Vol. 15, No. 4, pp. 27-38.

Page 41: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

33

Dunn, D. and Pellechio, A. (1990) Analysing Taxes on Business Income with the Marginal Effective Tax Rate Model, World Bank Discussion Paper No. 79, Washington, DC: World Bank. Edwards, L. and Golub, S. (2004) South Africa’s International Cost Competitiveness and Exports in Manufacturing, World Development, Vol. 32, No. 8, pp. 1323-39. Fedderke, J. (2004) From Chimera to Prospect: Toward an Understanding of the South African Growth Absence, Cape Town: University of Cape Town Press. Flatters, F. (2002) From Import Substitution to Export Promotion: Driving the South African Motor Industry, paper presented to the Annual Forum of the South Africa Trade and Industry Policy Secretariat, Muldersdrift, 9-11 September. http://qed.econ.queensu.ca/pub/faculty/flatters/writings/ff_driving_the_motor_industry.pdf Fletcher, K. (2003) An Evaluation of Marginal Effective Tax Rates on Domestic Investment in South Africa between 1994 and 2002, MA thesis, University of Witwatersrand. Gelb, S. (2003) Foreign Companies in South Africa: Entry, Performance and Impact, Johannesburg: EDGE Institute. www.the-edge.org.za. Gelb, S. and Black, A. (2004a) Foreign Direct Investment in South Africa in S. Estrin and K. E. Meyer (eds), Investment Strategies in Emerging Markets, London Business School Centre for New and Emerging Markets (CNEM), Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Press. Gelb, S. and Black, A. (2004b) South African Case Studies, in S. Estrin and K. E. Meyer (eds), Investment Strategies in Emerging Markets, London Business School Centre for New and Emerging Markets (CNEM), Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Press. Gelb, S. and Black, A. (2004c) Globalization in a middle income economy: FDI, production and the labor market in SA, in W. Milberg (ed.), Labor and the Globalization of Production, Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. Government of South Africa (1996) Growth Employment and Redistribution: A Macro-economic Strategy, Pretoria. www.polity.org.za. Government of South Africa (2004) Estimates of National Expenditure, Pretoria: National Treasury, February. Hanson, G. (2001) Should Countries Promote Foreign Direct Investment?, UNCTAD/HIID G-24 Discussion Paper Series No. 9, New York and Geneva: United Nations, February. Hartzenberg, T. and Stuart, J. (2002) South Africa’s Growth Performance since 1960: A Legacy of Inequality and Exclusion, paper prepared for AERC Growth Project, School of Economics, University of Cape Town, May. Hinch, M. (2004) Presentation to the SADC Workshop on Tax Incentives, 5-9 July. James, S. (2003) The Ramatex Case, background paper to Bolnick (2004), Cambridge, MA: John F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University. Jenkins, C. and Thomas, L. (2002) Foreign Direct Investment in Southern Africa: Determinants, Characteristics and Implications for Economic Growth and Poverty

Page 42: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

34

Alleviation, Oxford: Centre for the Study of African Economies (CSAE), University of Oxford and London: Centre for Research into Economics and Finance in Southern Africa (CREFSA), London School of Economics. Kaplan, D. (2001) Rethinking Government Support for Business Sector R&D in South Africa: The Case for Tax Incentives, The South African Journal of Economics, Vol. 69, No 1, pp. 72-91. Kaplan, D. (2003) Manufacturing Performance and Policy in South Africa: A Review, paper prepared for the TIPS/DPRU Forum, ‘The Challenge of Growth and Poverty: The South African Economy since Democracy’. Kingdon, G. and Knight, J. (2004) Unemployment in South Africa: The Nature of the Beast, World Development, Vol. 32, No. 3, pp. 391-408. Lewis, J. (2002) Policies to Promote Growth and Employment in South Africa, World Bank Africa Regional Working Paper Series No. 32, Pretoria: World Bank. Nel, E. (2002) South Africa’s Manufacturing Economy: Problems and Performance, in A. Lemon and C. M. Rogerson (eds), Geography and Economy in South Africa and its Neighbours, Urban and Regional Planning and Development Series, Aldershot: Ashgate. PricewaterhouseCoopers (2002) Income Tax Guide 2002-2003, Durban: LexisNexis Butterworths. Republic of South Africa (1995) Third Interim Report of the Commission of Enquiry into Certain Aspects of the Tax Structure of South Africa, Republic of South Africa, Pretoria: Department of Finance, Government of South Africa. Roberts, S. (2004) Investment in South Africa – A Comment on Recent Contributions, Development Southern Africa, Vol. 21, No. 4. pp. 743-56. Shah, A. (ed.) (1995) Fiscal Incentives for Investment and Innovation, Washington, DC: Oxford University Press for the World Bank. Shah, A. (1995) Overview, in A. Shah (ed.), Fiscal Incentives for Investment and Innovation, Washington, DC: Oxford University Press for the World Bank. Shah, A. and Slemrod, J. (1995) Do Taxes Matter for Foreign Direct Investment?, in A. Shah (ed.), Fiscal Incentives for Investment and Innovation, Washington, DC: Oxford University Press for the World Bank. Slemrod, J. (1995) Tax Policy Toward Foreign Direct Investment in Developing Countries in Light of Recent International Tax Changes, in A. Shah (ed.), Fiscal Incentives for Investment and Innovation, Washington, DC: Oxford University Press for the World Bank. Stiglitz, J. (1986) Economics of the Public Sector, 2nd edn., New York and London: WW Norton and Company. TSG Services Group (1999) Informal Paper to the Government of South Africa on the Compatibility of Existing Investment Incentives with WTO Obligations. www.tsginc.com.

Page 43: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

35

UNCTAD (2000) Tax Incentives and Foreign Direct Investment: A Global Survey, ASIT Advisory Studies No. 16, Geneva and New York: United Nations Conference on Trade and Development. UNCTAD (2003) FDI and Performance Requirements: Evidence from Selected Countries, Geneva: UNCTAD, based on a background paper by Gostner. UNCTAD (2004) World Investment Report: The Shift Toward Services, Geneva: UNCTAD. Vickers, B. (2002) An Overview of South Africa’s Investment Regime and Performance, Institute for Global Dialogue, Issue No. 16, April. Wade, R. (1990) Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian Industrialization, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Wells, L., Allen, N., Morisset, J. and Pirnia, N. (2001) Tax Incentives to Compete for Foreign Investment: Are They Worth the Costs?, Foreign Investment Advisory Service Occasional Paper No. 15, Washington, DC: FIAS. World Bank (2004) World Development Report 2005: A Better Investment Climate for Everyone, Washington, DC: Oxford University Press for the World Bank. World Trade Organisation (2003) Trade Policy Review: Southern Africa Customs Union, Geneva: WTO, April. Zee, H. H., Stotsky, J. G., and Ley, E. (2002) Tax Incentives for Business Investment: A Primer for Policy Makers in Developing Countries, World Development, Vol. 30, No. 9, pp. 1497-1516.

Page 44: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

36A

nn

ex 1

: Th

e M

ain

Fis

cal I

nce

nti

ves:

Th

eir

Pro

s an

d C

ons

Ince

nti

ve

Com

pon

ents

P

ros

Con

s Su

ppor

tin

g ci

rcu

mst

ance

s

Dir

ect i

nce

nti

ves

Cas

h p

aym

ents

G

ran

ts (

som

etim

es ta

x-fr

ee)

pro

vid

ed to

com

pan

ies

on

pro

of o

f sta

rt u

p, o

r af

ter

x n

um

ber

of y

ears

of o

per

atio

n

On

bu

dge

t, tr

ansp

aren

t, e

asie

r ov

ersi

ght

Firm

s p

refe

r gr

ants

as

they

p

rovi

de

up

from

cas

h b

enef

its

Up

fron

t, c

ash

cos

ts to

the

fiscu

s C

an r

equ

ire

nee

d to

rec

oup

cos

ts

(dif

ficu

lt)

ex-p

ost i

f in

vest

men

t m

oves

aw

ay p

rem

atu

rely

A c

ash

ric

h fi

scu

s

Cri

tica

l in

fras

tru

ctu

re

pro

visi

on

Gov

ern

men

t fu

nd

s, o

r p

artl

y fu

nd

s, th

e p

rovi

sion

of

infr

astr

uct

ure

su

ch a

s ac

cess

ro

ads,

dam

s, e

lect

rici

ty

con

nec

tion

s

Tra

nsp

aren

t E

asy

to m

onit

or

Pro

vid

es la

stin

g in

fras

tru

ctu

re

(tan

gib

le a

sset

s)

Up

fron

t cas

h c

ost t

o th

e fis

cus

Fun

gib

ility

mea

ns

that

the

sub

sid

y co

uld

be

to a

ny

par

t of t

he

corp

orat

ion

s op

erat

ion

s

Lon

g le

ad ti

mes

Eco

nom

ies

in n

eed

of

infr

astr

uct

ure

up

grad

ing

Indi

rect

(ta

x) in

cen

tive

s - D

irec

t tax

es

Tax

hol

iday

s E

xem

pti

on fr

om c

orp

orat

e in

com

e ta

x fo

r th

e fi

rst f

ew

year

s of

op

erat

ion

(ty

pic

ally

3-

5 ye

ars)

Eas

y to

ad

min

iste

r es

pec

ially

if

corp

orat

e ta

x is

rec

entl

y in

trod

uce

d

Red

uce

tax

adva

nta

ges

of d

ebt

fin

anci

ng

by

red

uci

ng

the

tax

dis

tort

ion

aga

inst

equ

ity

fin

anci

ng

R

edu

ce in

cen

tive

to ‘l

ever

up

’ th

e d

ebt/

equ

ity

rati

o an

d

ther

efor

e re

du

ce th

e ch

ance

s of

ban

kru

ptc

y T

arge

t in

fan

t in

du

stry

sp

ecif

ical

ly (

vers

us

acro

ss th

e b

oard

low

er c

orp

orat

e ta

xes)

P

rovi

de

a st

ron

g si

gnal

to

pot

enti

al in

vest

ors

Exp

ensi

ve, a

nd

un

cert

ain

, los

s of

re

ven

ue

for

give

n le

vel o

f ad

dit

ion

al in

vest

men

t Le

ss e

ffec

tive

in h

igh

infla

tion

en

viro

nm

ents

, if i

nte

rest

cos

ts a

re

fully

ded

uct

ible

for

tax

pu

rpos

es

(deb

t fin

ance

d in

vest

men

t), o

r if

in

vest

men

t fin

ance

d in

par

t wit

h

loca

l bor

row

ing

Irre

leva

nt t

o fir

ms

that

are

not

in

itia

lly p

rofi

tab

le -

mos

t oft

en

larg

e ca

pit

al s

tart

-up

s E

nco

ura

ge s

hor

t- te

rm

inve

stm

ents

, an

d fo

otlo

ose

firm

s w

ho

‘hop

aro

un

d’ f

or ta

x h

olid

ays

avoi

din

g ta

x at

all

Dis

crim

inat

e ag

ain

st fu

ture

in

vest

men

t C

reat

e in

cen

tive

s fo

r ta

x p

lan

nin

g (a

void

ance

) N

ot ti

ed to

the

amou

nt i

nve

sted

Low

infla

tion

en

viro

nm

ents

B

enef

it c

omp

anie

s la

rgel

y fi

nan

cin

g in

vest

men

t wit

h e

qu

ity

Imp

act d

epen

ds

cru

cial

ly u

pon

w

het

her

acc

rued

init

ial a

nd

/or

ann

ual

dep

reci

atio

n a

llow

ance

s ca

n b

e ca

rrie

d fo

rwar

d. I

f not

, fir

ms

mak

ing

loss

es in

the

firs

t few

yea

rs

(oft

en th

e ca

se w

ith

sta

rt-u

ps)

en

d

up

pay

ing

mor

e C

IT th

an th

ey

wou

ld w

ith

out t

he

tax

hol

iday

) T

ax h

olid

ays

less

wor

thw

hile

if th

ey

take

pla

ce m

any

year

s in

the

futu

re

Page 45: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

37

Com

pon

ents

P

ros

Con

s Su

ppor

tin

g ci

rcu

mst

ance

s

Inve

stm

ent t

ax

cred

its

Cre

dit

s ea

rned

for

inve

stm

ent

un

der

take

n

Cre

dit

s ca

n b

e u

sed

in li

eu o

f C

IT p

aym

ents

C

an b

e ei

ther

incr

emen

tal

(on

ly o

n in

vest

men

ts a

bov

e a

cert

ain

thre

shol

d)

or fi

xed

(a

pp

licab

le to

all

inve

stm

ent)

Mor

e co

st e

ffec

tive

than

tax

hol

iday

s In

crem

enta

l cre

dit

s ta

rget

tru

ly

add

itio

nal

inve

stm

ent

Rev

enu

e co

sts

dir

ectl

y re

late

d

to a

mou

nts

inve

sted

E

nco

ura

ges

firm

s to

take

a

lon

g-te

rm v

iew

, bec

ause

n

arro

wly

bas

ed

Har

d to

rev

erse

, so

hav

e go

od

cred

ibili

ty

Eas

ier

to e

stim

ate

max

imu

m

reve

nu

e co

sts

Qu

alif

icat

ion

req

uir

emen

ts

easi

er to

def

ine

and

mon

itor

Favo

ur

mor

e es

tab

lish

ed fi

rms

over

n

ew o

nes

Fa

vou

rs n

on-i

nve

nto

ry a

nd

cap

ital

in

ten

sive

inve

stm

ent

Favo

urs

cap

ital

goo

ds

that

d

epre

ciat

e q

uic

kly

– re

qu

irin

g fr

equ

ent r

e-in

vest

men

t Ir

rele

van

t to

firm

s w

hic

h w

ould

pay

n

o ta

x (l

oss

mak

ing)

in th

e ab

sen

ce

of th

e ta

x al

low

ance

/cre

dit

(oft

en

star

t-u

ps)

If

tem

por

ary,

can

sim

ply

bri

ng

forw

ard

inve

stm

ent d

ecis

ion

s D

iffi

cult

an

d c

omp

lex

to d

esig

n

and

imp

lem

ent

Allo

w ta

x p

lan

nin

g vi

a ‘s

ham

’ sa

les/

pu

rch

ases

of a

sset

s

Pro

fici

ent a

nd

wel

l ad

min

iste

red

re

ven

ue

regi

mes

(es

pec

ially

as

rega

rds

incr

emen

tal i

nve

stm

ents

)

Cre

dit

s ca

n s

omet

imes

be

trad

ed,

so u

sefu

l wit

hin

a d

ynam

ic b

road

ly

bal

ance

d e

con

omy

Inve

stm

ent t

ax

allo

wan

ces

Tax

able

cor

por

ate

inco

me

red

uce

d v

ia a

n in

vest

men

t al

low

ance

(a

pro

por

tion

of t

he

inve

stm

ent c

ost)

As

abov

e A

s ab

ove

Eq

uiv

alen

t to

ITC

if th

ere

is a

sin

gle

CIR

rat

e

Acc

eler

ated

d

epre

ciat

ion

Fa

ster

than

eco

nom

ic

dep

reci

atio

n s

ched

ule

red

uce

s th

e N

PV

of t

ax p

aym

ents

Low

rev

enu

e co

sts

Neu

tral

wit

h r

egar

d to

the

du

rab

ility

of t

he

inve

stm

ent

Sim

ple

to im

ple

men

t

Favo

urs

cap

ital

-in

ten

sive

in

vest

men

t Le

ss s

oph

isti

cate

d ta

x re

gim

es

Ded

uct

ion

of

qu

alify

ing

exp

ense

s

Inve

stm

ents

in c

erta

in ty

pes

of

inve

stm

ent (

e.g.

R&

D)

are

ded

uct

ible

for

tax

pu

rpos

es

Can

be

very

sp

ecif

ical

ly

targ

eted

at c

erta

in p

olic

y ob

ject

ives

Cre

ate

com

ple

x ta

x re

gim

e A

dm

inis

trat

ion

an

d o

vers

igh

t cos

ts

hig

h

Wh

ere

ther

e is

a c

lear

ly id

enti

fied

n

eed

to in

vest

in o

ne

spec

ific

sect

or

(R&

D is

a g

ood

exa

mp

le)

In

dire

ct (

tax)

ince

nti

ves

- In

dire

ct ta

xes

Imp

ort d

uty

in

crea

ses

Pro

tect

ion

from

com

pet

itor

s E

asy

to a

dm

inis

ter

No

up

-fro

nt c

osts

M

ay c

ontr

aven

e W

TO

ob

ligat

ion

s P

rote

ctio

nis

t an

d d

isto

rtio

nar

y

Imp

ort d

uty

d

ecre

ases

(on

in

pu

ts o

r ca

pit

al

equ

ipm

ent)

Ch

eap

er im

por

ts o

f raw

m

ater

ials

or

cap

ital

eq

uip

men

t E

asy

to a

dm

inis

ter

No

up

-fro

nt c

osts

La

rge

reve

nu

e lo

sses

R

edu

ced

tari

ffs

on c

apit

al im

por

ts

enh

ance

cap

ital

bia

s P

rovi

de

tax

pla

nn

ing

opp

ortu

nit

ies

for

mis

clas

sify

ing

con

sum

er g

ood

s as

cap

ital

goo

ds

Eff

icac

y d

epen

ds

on w

het

her

the

tari

ffs

cost

s on

imp

orte

d in

pu

ts c

an

be

pas

sed

on

to c

onsu

mer

s or

not

(i

f so,

ince

nti

ves

are

less

eff

ecti

ve)

Page 46: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

38

Com

pon

ents

P

ros

Con

s Su

ppor

tin

g ci

rcu

mst

ance

s

Du

ty d

raw

bac

ks

A r

efu

nd

of d

uty

pai

d o

n

imp

orte

d m

erch

and

ise

wh

en it

is

late

r ex

por

ted

, wh

eth

er in

th

e sa

me

or a

dif

fere

nt f

orm

V

AT

is u

sual

ly z

ero

rate

d a

lso

Eff

ecti

vely

pro

mot

e ex

por

t-or

ien

tate

d c

omp

anie

s W

TO

com

pat

ible

Com

ple

x to

ad

min

iste

r R

equ

ire

com

pet

ent c

ust

oms

and

ex

cise

reg

ime

Wh

ere

exp

ort g

row

th is

sp

ecif

ical

ly

the

econ

omic

goa

l (e.

g. n

eed

to

earn

fore

ign

exc

han

ge)

Oth

ers

(non

-fis

cal)

Red

uce

d

regu

lato

ry

com

plia

nce

; or

stre

amlin

ed

adm

inis

trat

ion

Inve

stm

ent i

n c

erta

in s

ecto

rs,

or in

cer

tain

geo

grap

hic

are

as,

are

exem

pte

d fr

om c

erta

in

legi

slat

ion

, or

rece

ive

pri

orit

y tr

eatm

ent w

ith

res

pec

t to

legi

slat

ive

requ

irem

ents

No

fisca

l cos

t R

egu

lato

ry c

omp

lian

ce c

an b

e on

e of

the

mai

n b

urd

ens

to

inve

stm

ent i

n d

evel

opin

g co

un

trie

s

A p

refe

rred

pol

icy

resp

onse

wou

ld

be

to r

edu

ce th

e re

gula

tory

co

mp

lian

ce c

osts

for

all b

usi

nes

s Su

b-o

pti

mal

res

pon

se

Can

lead

to a

‘rac

e to

the

bot

tom

’ in

term

s of

reg

ula

tion

Wh

ere

regu

lato

ry r

equ

irem

ents

are

a

bar

rier

to in

vest

men

t, a

nd

wh

ere

dif

fere

nt s

ecto

rs fa

ce d

iffe

ren

t co

mp

lian

ce c

osts

(e.

g. S

MM

Es

face

h

igh

er c

osts

pro

por

tion

atel

y th

an

larg

e fir

ms)

E

xpor

t P

roce

ssin

g Z

ones

Geo

grap

hic

are

as (

nor

mal

ly

nea

r a

por

t/ai

rpor

t) o

ffer

ing

fisc

al in

cen

tive

s (a

s ou

tlin

ed

abov

e), o

r n

on-f

isca

l in

cen

tive

s su

ch a

s ex

emp

tion

s fr

om r

egu

lato

ry r

egim

es

Nor

mal

ly h

ave

qu

alifi

cati

on

requ

irem

ents

(% e

xpor

t etc

.)

Focu

sed

on

att

ract

ing

exp

ort

inte

nsi

ve in

vest

men

t C

an r

esu

lt in

exi

stin

g d

omes

tic

inve

stm

ent r

e-lo

cati

ng

to E

PZ

s Le

akag

e p

robl

ems

(sm

ugg

ling)

an

d

asso

ciat

ed lo

ss o

f rev

enu

e

Mos

t eff

ecti

ve w

hen

lin

ked

to

exp

orti

ng

loca

tion

s w

ith

goo

d

infr

astr

uct

ure

su

ch a

s se

a an

d a

ir

por

ts

Req

uir

es c

omp

eten

t cu

stom

s an

d

exci

se r

egim

e

Sub

sid

ised

fi

nan

ce th

rou

gh

par

asta

tal

len

din

g

Gov

ern

men

t ow

ned

d

evel

opm

ent b

anks

pro

vid

e lo

w c

ost d

ebt a

nd

/or

equ

ity

Spec

ific

ally

ad

dre

sses

on

e m

ajor

mar

ket f

ailu

re (r

isk-

aver

se p

riva

te s

ecto

r fi

nan

cial

se

ctor

) C

an b

e ta

rget

ed to

thos

e se

ctor

s m

ost i

n n

eed

of

inve

stm

ent (

e.g.

agr

icu

ltu

re)

Non

-tra

nsp

aren

t C

an c

row

d o

ut p

riva

te s

ecto

r fi

nan

ce

Pot

enti

ally

op

en to

ab

use

Par

asta

tals

wit

h a

ver

y cl

ear

man

dat

e, w

ith

str

ong

com

mer

cial

gu

idel

ines

, an

d w

ith

ove

rsig

ht

Low

inp

ut

pri

ces

from

p

aras

tata

l co

mp

anie

s

Gov

ern

men

t-ow

ned

co

mp

anie

s p

rovi

de

inp

uts

(e.g

. el

ectr

icit

y, o

il, tr

ansp

ort)

at

bel

ow m

arke

t pri

ce

No

imm

edia

te b

ud

geta

ry

imp

act

Non

-tra

nsp

aren

t P

oten

tial

ly o

pen

to a

bu

se

Par

asta

tals

wit

h a

ver

y cl

ear

man

dat

e, w

ith

str

ong

com

mer

cial

gu

idel

ines

, an

d w

ith

ove

rsig

ht

Dis

cret

ion

ary

sch

emes

(c

an a

pp

ly to

all

of th

e ab

ove)

Ind

ust

ries

ap

ply

for

ince

nti

ves

wh

ich

are

gra

nte

d a

t th

e d

iscr

etio

n o

f an

ind

ivid

ual

or

Boa

rd

Allo

w n

egot

iati

ng

spac

e fo

r th

e h

ost c

oun

try

gove

rnm

ent

Can

targ

et in

cen

tive

s to

thos

e fi

rms

wh

o w

ould

not

hav

e in

vest

ed w

ith

out t

hem

(re

du

ce

the

red

un

dan

cy r

ate)

Inco

nsi

sten

tly

app

lied

O

pen

to a

buse

H

igh

ad

min

istr

ativ

e co

sts

C

reat

e u

nce

rtai

nty

for

the

inve

stor

Bes

t pra

ctic

e w

ith

dis

cret

ion

ary

regi

mes

is to

dis

clos

e p

roce

du

res

and

ou

tcom

es o

f dec

isio

ns

(e.g

. to

Par

liam

ent)

Sou

rces

: Bol

nic

k (2

004)

, Ch

ua

(199

5) a

nd

Fle

tch

er (

2003

)

Page 47: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

39A

nn

ex 2

: S

outh

Afr

ica:

Inve

stm

ent

Ince

nti

ves

Act

ive

in A

ugus

t 2

00

4

Exp

endi

ture

su

bsid

ies

(cas

h p

aym

ents

) Im

plem

enti

ng

agen

cy

Obj

ecti

ves

Det

ails

B

udg

et c

ost/

take

-u

p/ot

her

issu

es

Exp

ort M

arke

tin

g &

In

vest

men

t Ass

ista

nce

Sc

hem

e (E

MIA

)

DT

I T

o in

crea

se e

xpor

t bas

e of

in

du

stry

in S

A b

y h

elp

ing

exp

orte

rs fi

nd

new

m

arke

ts

Gra

nts

to a

ssis

t exp

orte

rs w

ith

the

cost

s of

fin

din

g n

ew

mar

kets

an

d a

ttra

ctin

g in

vest

ors.

9 s

chem

es in

tota

l V

agu

ely

def

ined

‘cri

teri

a’ fo

r q

ual

ific

atio

n fo

r ea

ch o

f th

e sc

hem

es. 5

0-10

0% o

f flig

ht c

osts

, per

die

m, v

ehic

le r

enta

l, p

lus

up

to R

10,0

00 o

n m

arke

tin

g m

ater

ials

A

pp

lies

to S

outh

Afr

ican

exp

orti

ng

man

ufa

ctu

rers

incl

ud

ing

SMM

Es,

PD

I, a

nd

oth

er S

A T

rad

ing

Hou

ses.

Als

o in

clu

des

SA

E

xpor

t Cou

nci

ls a

nd

Ind

ust

ry A

ssoc

iati

ons.

Oth

er b

usi

nes

s co

nce

rns

qu

alif

yin

g in

term

s of

the

dis

cret

ion

ary

pro

visi

ons33

R58

.2m

. use

d in

20

02/3

Tec

hn

olog

y fo

r H

um

an

Res

ourc

es in

Ind

ust

ry

Pro

gram

(T

HR

IP)

DT

I / N

RF

To

imp

rove

the

com

pet

itiv

enes

s of

Sou

th

Afr

ican

ind

ust

ry, b

y su

pp

orti

ng

rese

arch

an

d

tech

nol

ogy

dev

elop

men

t ac

tivi

ties

an

d e

nh

anci

ng

the

qu

alit

y an

d q

uan

tity

of

suit

ably

ski

lled

peo

ple

50%

mat

chin

g gr

ant t

o in

du

stry

’s c

ontr

ibu

tion

for

pri

orit

ised

re

sear

ch

R15

0,00

0 gr

ant t

o th

e fir

m fo

r ea

ch s

tud

ent i

nvo

lved

an

d

trai

ned

thro

ugh

the

pro

gram

me

R21

4m. i

n 2

002

Smal

l/M

ediu

m

Man

ufa

ctu

rers

D

evel

opm

ent P

rogr

am

(SM

MD

P)

(Rep

lace

d a

s Sm

all/

Med

ium

E

nte

rpri

se D

evel

opm

ent

Pro

gram

in Ja

nu

ary

2001

)

DT

I P

rom

ote

Smal

l/M

ediu

m

En

terp

rise

s in

the

man

ufa

ctu

rin

g, a

gro-

, aq

ua-

cult

ure

, bio

-tec

h,

tou

rism

, cu

ltu

re, b

usi

nes

s se

rvic

e an

d IC

T s

ecto

rs

On

ly fi

rms

form

ed a

fter

Oct

199

6 (w

as li

mit

ed to

m

anu

fact

uri

ng

firm

s p

rior

to Ja

nu

ary

2001

) P

rovi

des

an

est

ablis

hm

ent g

ran

t (1-

10%

of q

ual

ifyi

ng

asse

ts)

up

to a

max

imu

m o

f R10

0m. p

er e

nte

rpri

se p

er p

roje

ct. T

his

ta

x-fr

ee g

ran

t is

pay

able

for

thre

e ye

ars

on q

ual

ifyi

ng

asse

ts

R16

9m. u

sed

in

2002

/3

33

For

mor

e in

form

atio

n, s

ee w

ww

.dti

.gov

.za/

exp

orti

ng/

exp

orti

nce

nti

ves.

htm

.

Page 48: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

40E

xpen

ditu

re s

ubs

idie

s (c

ash

pay

men

ts)

Impl

emen

tin

g ag

ency

O

bjec

tive

s D

etai

ls

Bu

dget

cos

t/ta

ke-

up/

oth

er is

sues

Fore

ign

Inve

stm

ent

Gra

nt (

FIG

) (T

he

only

ince

nti

ve

spec

ific

ally

aim

ed a

t FD

I, m

inim

um

50%

fo

reig

n h

old

ing)

DT

I E

nh

ance

tech

nol

ogy

tran

sfer

from

FD

I T

he

FIG

will

cov

er u

p to

15%

of t

he

cost

s of

mov

ing

new

m

ach

iner

y an

d e

qu

ipm

ent,

to a

max

imu

m a

mou

nt o

f R3m

. p

er e

nti

ty. (

Tax

-fre

e gr

ant)

FI

G is

con

dit

ion

al u

pon

en

terp

rise

gai

nin

g ap

pro

val f

or th

e SM

ED

P

N/A

Skill

s Su

pp

ort

Pro

gram

me

DT

I/D

OL

Imp

rove

ski

lls w

ith

in

SMM

Es

Tra

inin

g gr

ant (

50%

cos

ts),

up

to m

ax o

f 30%

wag

e b

ill;

Lear

nin

g P

rogr

amm

e D

evel

opm

ent G

ran

t, p

aid

to

dev

elop

men

t tra

inin

g p

rogr

amm

es (

max

R3m

.)

Cap

ital

gra

nt f

or in

vest

men

t in

trai

nin

g ca

pac

ity

Ava

ilab

le to

firm

s ga

inin

g ap

pro

val f

or S

IP o

r SM

ED

P

40 p

roje

cts

as o

f 20

02/3

Bla

ck B

usi

nes

s Su

pp

lier

Pro

gram

me

DT

I P

rovi

de

HD

I SM

ME

s w

ith

ac

cess

to b

usi

nes

s d

evel

opm

ent s

ervi

ces

that

ca

n a

ssis

t th

em to

imp

rove

th

eir

core

com

pet

enci

es,

up

grad

e m

anag

eria

l ca

pab

iliti

es a

nd

re

stru

ctu

re to

bec

ome

mor

e co

mp

etit

ive

An

80:

20 c

ost-

shar

ing,

cas

h g

ran

t in

cen

tive

sch

eme,

wh

ich

of

fers

su

pp

ort t

o b

lack

-ow

ned

en

terp

rise

s. T

he

sch

eme

pro

vid

es s

uch

com

pan

ies

wit

h a

cces

s to

bu

sin

ess

dev

elop

men

t ser

vice

s in

ord

er to

ass

ist t

hem

in im

pro

vin

g th

eir

core

com

pet

enci

es, u

pgr

adin

g m

anag

eria

l cap

abili

ties

an

d r

estr

uct

uri

ng

to b

ecom

e m

ore

com

pet

itiv

e

Max

imu

m fr

om o

ne

of m

ore

gran

ts is

R10

0,00

0 on

an

80:

20

cost

-sh

arin

g b

asis

R9m

. pro

ject

ed fo

r 20

03/4

Inn

ovat

ion

Fu

nd

D

ept o

f Art

s,

Cu

ltu

re, S

cien

ce

& T

ech

nol

ogy

Sup

por

t to

larg

e-sc

ale

rese

arch

wit

h a

sig

nif

ican

t R

&D

com

pon

ent t

o ad

dre

ss r

esea

rch

to

over

com

e p

rob

lem

s af

fect

ing

soci

o-ec

onom

ic

dev

elop

men

t or

Sou

th

Afr

ica’

s ab

ility

to c

omp

ete

in p

rod

uct

s an

d s

ervi

ces

Gra

nts

of a

bet

wee

n R

1m. a

nd

R5m

. per

yea

r u

p to

a

max

imu

m o

f 3 y

ears

(I

nfo

rmat

ion

Tec

hn

olog

y; B

iote

chn

olog

y V

alu

e-ad

din

g in

nat

ura

l res

ourc

es a

nd

mat

eria

ls a

nd

m

anu

fact

uri

ng)

P

roje

cts

mu

st b

e la

rge-

scal

e sc

ien

ce, e

ngi

nee

rin

g an

d

tech

nol

ogy

(SE

T)

inn

ovat

ion

pro

gram

mes

Fu

nd

acc

esse

d v

ia c

omp

etit

ive

bid

din

g b

y st

atu

tory

res

earc

h

and

tech

nol

ogy

inst

itu

tion

s, h

igh

er e

du

cati

on b

odie

s, th

e b

usi

nes

s an

d in

du

stri

al c

omm

un

ity

and

non

-gov

ern

men

tal

bod

ies

R71

m. i

n 2

003

Page 49: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

41E

xpen

ditu

re s

ubs

idie

s (c

ash

pay

men

ts)

Impl

emen

tin

g ag

ency

O

bjec

tive

s D

etai

ls

Bu

dget

cos

t/ta

ke-

up/

oth

er is

sues

Sup

por

t Pro

gram

for

Ind

ust

rial

Inn

ovat

ion

(S

PII

)

IDC

(on

beh

alf

of D

TI)

Su

pp

ort S

A b

ased

pro

du

ct

or p

roce

ss d

evel

opm

ent

that

rep

rese

nts

a

sign

ific

ant t

ech

nol

ogic

al

adva

nce

an

d p

rovi

des

a

com

mer

cial

ad

van

tage

ov

er e

xist

ing

pro

du

cts

Sup

por

t is

in th

e fo

rm o

f a g

ran

t of 5

0 %

of a

ctu

al c

osts

in

curr

ed in

dev

elop

men

t act

ivit

ies.

Th

e M

atch

ing

Sch

eme

sup

por

ts p

rod

uct

/pro

cess

dev

elop

men

t to

a m

axim

um

of

R1.

5m. p

er p

roje

ct. T

he

Par

tner

ship

Sch

eme

sup

por

ts la

rge-

scal

e in

nov

atio

n a

nd

pro

du

cts/

pro

cess

dev

elop

men

t by

pro

vid

ing

a co

nd

itio

nal

gra

nt (

>R1.

5m, n

o u

pp

er li

mit

), b

ut

rep

ayab

le in

the

form

of a

levy

on

sal

es if

the

pro

ject

is

succ

essf

ully

com

mer

cial

ised

Fe

asib

ility

Sch

eme

sup

por

ts c

osts

of c

onsu

ltan

ts fo

r SM

ME

s u

p to

R30

,000

R79

m in

200

2/3

Par

tner

ship

s in

In

du

stri

al In

nov

atio

n

(PII

)

IDC

(on

beh

alf

of D

TI)

Su

pp

ort R

&D

(as

abo

ve)

wh

ere

pro

ject

is >

R3m

. T

ax-f

ree

loan

s ar

e aw

ard

ed to

dev

elop

men

t pro

ject

s (f

or a

m

axim

um

of 5

0% o

f its

qu

alif

yin

g co

sts)

N

/A

Com

pet

itiv

enes

s Fu

nd

D

TI

En

cou

rage

s co

mp

etit

iven

ess

in S

A

ente

rpri

ses

bot

h a

s ex

por

ters

an

d im

por

t-su

bst

itu

tors

50%

mat

chin

g gr

ant t

o su

pp

ort t

he

intr

odu

ctio

n o

f tec

hn

ical

an

d m

arke

tin

g kn

ow-h

ow a

nd

exp

erti

se to

firm

s A

vaila

ble

to a

ll SA

pri

vate

firm

s on

a fi

rst-

com

e fir

st-s

erve

b

asis

(U

sed

to in

clu

de

the

Bu

mbl

ebee

pro

gram

me

that

is n

o lo

nge

r op

erat

ive)

R39

.98m

. in

200

2/3

Sect

or P

artn

ersh

ip F

un

d

DT

I Im

pro

ves

com

pet

itiv

enes

s an

d p

rod

uct

ivit

y of

the

man

ufa

ctu

rin

g se

ctor

an

d

agro

-pro

cess

ing

thro

ugh

su

b-s

ecto

r p

artn

ersh

ips

in

pre

par

atio

n o

f tec

hn

ical

an

d m

arke

tin

g p

rogr

amm

es

65%

of c

osts

of p

roje

cts

up

to m

ax o

f R1m

. fin

ance

d

Ava

ilab

le to

an

y p

artn

ersh

ip o

f 5 o

r m

ore

orga

nis

atio

ns

wit

hin

SA

man

ufa

ctu

rin

g or

agr

o-p

roce

ssin

g se

ctor

s M

axim

um

pro

ject

siz

e is

R1.

5m.

R9.

134m

. in

200

2/3

Film

Ind

ust

ry

DT

I E

nco

ura

ges

film

an

d

tele

visi

on p

rogr

amm

e p

rod

uct

ion

in S

A

Reb

ate

of 1

5% (

for

fore

ign

pro

du

ctio

ns)

or

25%

for

qu

alify

ing

Sou

th A

fric

an p

rod

uct

ion

s. A

fin

ite

sum

has

bee

n a

lloca

ted

ov

er a

n in

itia

l 3-y

ear

per

iod

. Th

e m

axim

um

reb

ate

for

each

p

roje

ct w

ill b

e R

10m

.

Too

ear

ly to

jud

ge

Cal

l Cen

tres

/Bac

k O

ffic

e P

roce

ssin

g D

TI

Un

der

dis

cuss

ion

Page 50: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

42E

xpen

ditu

re s

ubs

idie

s (P

rovi

sion

of f

irm

-sp

ecif

ic in

fras

tru

ctu

re)

Impl

emen

tin

g ag

ency

O

bjec

tive

s D

etai

ls

Bu

dget

cos

t/ta

ke-

up/

oth

er is

sues

Cri

tica

l In

fras

tru

ctu

re

Pro

gram

me

Mu

nic

ipal

itie

s/D

TI

Faci

litat

es in

vest

men

t in

cr

itic

al in

fras

tru

ctu

re

Fin

anci

al s

up

por

t (10

-30%

) of c

osts

of r

equ

ired

in

fras

tru

ctu

re, s

uch

as

road

s, e

lect

rici

ty c

able

s et

c.

Ava

ilab

le to

pri

vate

bu

sin

esse

s or

mu

nic

ipal

itie

s P

roje

cts

>R15

m. o

nly

R29

6m.u

sed

in

2002

/3

Indi

rect

(T

ax)

Ince

nti

ves

Red

uct

ion

in d

irec

t ta

xes

Impl

emen

tin

g ag

ency

O

bjec

tive

s D

etai

ls

Bu

dget

cos

t/ta

ke-

up/

oth

er is

sues

Scie

nti

fic

R&

D

(11

P&

Q)

Nat

ion

al

Tre

asu

ry &

SA

RS

Stim

ula

tes

R&

D

inve

stm

ent

Allo

ws

a 25

% d

edu

ctio

n fo

r R

&D

Cap

ital

Exp

end

itu

re

(ap

pro

val b

y C

SIR

)

Farm

ing

equ

ipm

ent

(12

B)

Nat

ion

al

Tre

asu

ry &

SA

RS

Stim

ula

tes

farm

ing

inve

stm

ent

Allo

ws

a 50

-30-

20 d

epre

ciat

ion

sch

edu

le fo

r ta

x p

urp

oses

Man

ufa

ctu

rin

g (1

2 C

)

Nat

ion

al

Tre

asu

ry &

SA

RS

Stim

ula

tes

man

ufa

ctu

rin

g in

vest

men

t & h

otel

eq

uip

men

t

Allo

ws

a 40

-20-

20-2

0 d

epre

ciat

ion

sch

edu

le fo

r ta

x p

urp

oses

Per

man

ent s

tru

ctu

res

(pip

elin

es, r

ail-

lines

, te

lcom

-lin

es a

nd

el

ectr

icit

y ca

bles

) (1

2 D

)

Nat

ion

al

Tre

asu

ry &

SA

RS

Bri

ng

per

man

ent

stru

ctu

res

into

lin

e w

ith

ot

her

man

ufa

ctu

rin

g in

cen

tive

s

10%

dep

reci

atio

n a

llow

ance

per

an

nu

m fo

r ta

x p

urp

oses

for

pip

elin

es

5% p

er a

nn

um

for

all o

ther

str

uct

ure

s

Smal

l bu

sin

ess

(12

E)

Nat

ion

al

Tre

asu

ry &

SA

RS

Ass

ista

nce

to S

MM

E c

ash

flo

ws

Im

med

iate

exp

ensi

ng

of c

apit

al e

qu

ipm

ent f

or S

MM

Es

Gra

du

ated

rat

e st

ruct

ure

(15

% C

IT o

n fi

rst R

150,

000)

SM

ME

def

ined

a g

ross

inco

me

<R3m

.

Air

craf

t han

gers

, ap

ron

s,

run

way

s, e

tc.

(12

F)

Nat

ion

al

Tre

asu

ry &

SA

RS

Ince

nti

ves

inve

stm

ent i

n

airp

orts

5%

an

nu

al d

epre

ciat

ion

for

tax

pu

rpos

es

Page 51: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

43R

edu

ctio

n in

dir

ect

taxe

s Im

plem

enti

ng

agen

cy

Obj

ecti

ves

Det

ails

B

udg

et c

ost/

take

-u

p/ot

her

issu

es

Stra

tegi

c In

vest

men

t P

rogr

am

(12

G)

Nat

ion

al

Tre

asu

ry &

SA

RS

Stim

ula

tes

inve

stm

ent i

n

‘pro

ject

s th

at h

ave

sign

ific

ant d

irec

t an

d

ind

irec

t ben

efit

s fo

r th

e So

uth

Afr

ican

Eco

nom

y’

Cri

teri

a:

Val

ue-

add

ed

Em

plo

ymen

t Li

nka

ges

to S

MM

Es

Dou

ble

ded

uct

ion

dep

reci

atio

n a

llow

ance

- o

ver

and

ab

ove

exis

tin

g al

low

ance

s -

is p

rovi

ded

for

on in

vest

men

ts in

in

du

stri

al a

sset

s (o

ver

R50

m.)

. To

qu

alif

y fo

r th

e al

low

ance

a

pro

ject

mu

st b

e re

gard

ed a

s a

‘str

ateg

ic in

du

stri

al p

roje

ct’

(Def

ined

as:

-

the

man

ufa

ctu

rin

g of

an

y p

rod

uct

s, g

ood

s, a

rtic

les

(oth

er

than

tob

acco

or

tob

acco

-rel

ated

pro

du

cts)

; -

com

pu

ter

and

com

pu

ter-

rela

ted

act

ivit

ies;

or

- R

&D

act

ivit

ies

as d

efin

ed in

the

sect

ion

or

in th

e re

gula

tion

s is

sued

un

der

the

sect

ion

O

nly

pro

ject

s w

hic

h m

eet t

he

requ

irem

ents

as

spec

ifie

d in

se

ctio

n 1

2G a

re a

pp

rove

d. T

he

amou

nt t

hat

qu

alifi

es fo

r d

edu

ctio

n is

a s

pec

ified

pro

por

tion

of t

he

cost

of i

nve

stm

ent

in in

du

stri

al a

sset

s In

du

stri

al a

sset

s ar

e:

· pla

nt a

nd

mac

hin

ery

not

pre

viou

sly

use

d, b

rou

ght i

nto

use

w

ith

in th

ree

year

s af

ter

app

rova

l, in

an

ind

ust

rial

pro

ject

in

SA; a

nd

· b

uild

ings

or

imp

rove

men

ts to

bu

ildin

gs, n

ot p

revi

ousl

y u

sed

, bro

ugh

t in

to u

se w

ith

in th

ree

year

s af

ter

app

rova

l, u

sed

wh

olly

or

mai

nly

for

carr

yin

g on

a p

roce

ss in

wh

ich

the

pla

nt a

nd

mac

hin

ery

refe

rred

to in

the

pre

viou

s p

arag

rap

h

are

use

d

Up

to 1

0 P

oin

ts a

re a

war

ded

to p

rop

osed

pro

ject

s,

dep

end

ing

on th

e m

etri

cs a

bov

e. A

pro

ject

sco

rin

g 6

or m

ore

poi

nts

is r

egar

ded

as

a qu

alify

ing

ind

ust

rial

pro

ject

wit

h

pre

ferr

ed s

tatu

s an

d a

pro

ject

sco

rin

g 4

or 5

poi

nts

is

rega

rded

as

a q

ual

ifyin

g in

du

stri

al p

roje

ct. W

her

e th

e p

roje

ct

has

pre

ferr

ed s

tatu

s, th

e ta

xpay

er m

ay d

edu

ct 1

00%

of t

he

cost

of t

he

asse

t in

the

year

in w

hic

h it

is fi

rst b

rou

ght i

nto

u

se. D

edu

ctio

n li

mit

ed to

the

less

er o

f th

e am

oun

t of t

he

asse

ts r

efle

cted

in th

e ap

plic

atio

n fo

r ap

pro

val o

r R

600m

. In

al

l oth

er c

ases

the

taxp

ayer

may

ded

uct

50%

of t

he

cost

of t

he

asse

t, li

mit

ed to

the

less

er o

f th

e am

oun

t of t

he

asse

ts a

s re

flect

ed in

the

app

licat

ion

for

app

rova

l, or

R30

0m.

R3

bn

fore

gon

e re

ven

ue

enve

lop

e al

lott

ed o

ver

per

iod

20

01-5

. 70%

co

mm

itte

d a

s of

July

20

04

Page 52: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

44R

edu

ctio

n in

dir

ect

taxe

s Im

plem

enti

ng

agen

cy

Obj

ecti

ves

Det

ails

B

udg

et c

ost/

take

-u

p/ot

her

issu

es

Bu

ildin

gs a

nd

im

pro

vem

ents

(1

3)

Nat

ion

al

Tre

asu

ry &

SA

RS

Stim

ula

te n

ew b

uild

ing

and

imp

rove

men

ts in

ce

rtai

n s

ecto

rs

Man

ufa

ctu

rin

g an

d h

otel

bu

ildin

g (n

ew a

nd

imp

rove

men

ts)

dep

reci

ate

at 5

% p

.a.

Hou

sin

g P

roje

cts

(def

ined

as

>5 d

wel

lings

) rec

eive

(10

%-2

%-

2%...

) d

epre

ciat

ion

sch

edu

le

Hot

el Im

pro

vem

ents

: 20%

per

an

nu

m a

llow

ance

(in

tern

al)

5% (e

xter

nal

) E

mp

loye

e H

ousi

ng

50%

ded

uct

ible

, up

to R

6000

per

dw

ellin

g

Urb

an D

evel

opm

ent

Zon

es

(13

QU

AT

)

Nat

ion

al

Tre

asu

ry, S

AR

S an

d

Mu

nic

ipal

itie

s

Cou

nte

r d

ecay

an

d

stim

ula

te u

rban

re

gen

erat

ion

Acc

eler

ated

Dep

reci

atio

n a

llow

ance

for

new

an

d r

enov

ated

co

nst

ruct

ion

in d

esig

nat

ed U

DZ

s 20

-20-

20-2

0-20

Dep

reci

atio

n S

ched

ule

for

new

bu

ildin

gs;

20-5

-5-

for

reh

abili

tate

d b

uild

ings

Val

ue-

add

ed p

roce

sses

(3

7E)

Nat

ion

al

Tre

asu

ry &

SA

RS

Stim

ula

te v

alu

e-ad

ded

m

anu

fact

uri

ng

12(c

) an

d 1

3 ap

ply

for

equ

ipm

ent a

nd

bu

ildin

gs u

sed

in

man

ufa

ctu

rin

g p

roce

sses

, wh

ich

are

at l

east

35%

val

ue-

add

ed

Dis

con

tin

ued

, bu

t ex

isti

ng

cert

ific

ates

st

ill v

alid

C

hal

len

ged

un

der

W

TO

ru

les

Tax

hol

iday

(3

7H)

Nat

ion

al

Tre

asu

ry &

SA

RS

En

cou

rage

man

ufa

ctu

rin

g in

vest

men

t U

p to

10

year

CIT

-fre

e h

olid

ay

(In

itia

l ap

pro

val 2

-6 y

ears

), s

tart

ing

as s

oon

as

CIT

bec

ame

du

e

No

new

ap

plic

atio

ns

acce

pte

d a

s of

199

9

Spec

ific

tax

trea

tmen

t fo

r th

e m

inin

g se

ctor

Nat

ion

al

Tre

asu

ry, S

AR

S,

DM

E

En

sure

s th

e fa

ir ta

xati

on o

f So

uth

Afr

ica’

s n

on-

ren

ewab

le n

atu

ral

reso

urc

es

En

cou

rage

s ex

plo

rati

on

and

op

enin

g-u

p o

f new

m

inin

g op

por

tun

itie

s

Bas

ic G

old

For

mu

la: R

ate

= 37

– 1

85/p

rofit

mar

gin

In

lieu

of t

he

30%

rat

e, th

e fo

rmu

la im

pos

es n

o ta

x on

m

argi

nal

min

es (u

p to

5%

pro

fit) w

ith

top

-en

d m

ines

pay

ing

up

to 3

5%

Op

tion

al G

old

For

mu

la: R

ate

= 46

– 2

30/p

rofit

mar

gin

In

lieu

of t

he

30%

rat

e, th

e fo

rmu

la im

pos

es n

o ta

x on

m

argi

nal

min

es (u

p to

5%

pro

fit) w

ith

top

-en

d m

ines

pay

ing

up

to 4

3%. T

his

form

ula

elim

inat

es th

e 12

.5%

div

iden

d ta

x C

apit

al e

xplo

rati

on c

osts

are

elig

ible

for

a 10

0% im

med

iate

w

rite

-off

, bu

t can

on

ly o

ffse

t min

ing

inco

me;

the

Com

mis

sion

er h

as th

e d

iscr

etio

nar

y au

thor

ity

to r

edu

ce to

an

nu

alis

ed a

mou

nts

E

xplo

rati

on e

xpen

ses

are

imm

edia

tely

ded

uct

ible

, bu

t all

exp

lora

tion

incu

rred

bef

ore

min

ing

can

on

ly o

ffse

t in

com

e fr

om th

at m

inin

g tr

ade

once

the

trad

e b

egin

s

Page 53: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

45R

edu

ctio

n in

dir

ect

taxe

s Im

plem

enti

ng

agen

cy

Obj

ecti

ves

Det

ails

B

udg

et c

ost/

take

-u

p/ot

her

issu

es

Spec

ific

tax

trea

tmen

t fo

r th

e m

inin

g se

ctor

(c

ont.)

Min

ing

Cap

ital

Cos

ts p

rovi

de

a 10

0% im

med

iate

wri

te-o

ff,

incl

ud

ing:

Sh

aft s

inki

ng

and

min

ing

equ

ipm

ent &

pre

-p

rod

uct

ion

dev

elop

men

t, a

dm

inis

trat

ion

an

d m

anag

emen

t co

sts

Em

plo

yee/

Com

mu

nit

y C

apit

al C

osts

pro

vid

e a

10%

per

an

nu

m w

rite

-off

, in

clu

din

g: E

mp

loye

e h

ousi

ng;

Hos

pit

als,

sc

hoo

ls a

nd

sh

ops;

Min

eral

tran

spor

t fro

m th

e m

ine

to th

e n

eare

st tr

ansp

ort o

utl

et

Red

uct

ion

in in

dire

ct

taxe

s Im

plem

enti

ng

agen

cy

Obj

ecti

ves

Det

ails

B

udg

et c

ost/

take

-u

p/ot

her

issu

es

Mot

or In

du

stry

D

evel

opm

ent P

rogr

am

(MID

P)

DT

I/IT

AC

Im

pro

ves

inte

rnat

ion

al

com

pet

itiv

enes

s of

ori

gin

al

equ

ipm

ent m

anu

fact

ure

s an

d th

e au

tom

otiv

e co

mp

onen

t fir

ms

Imp

rove

s ve

hic

le

affo

rdab

ility

in r

eal t

erm

s;

Imp

rove

s th

e in

du

stry

’s

trad

e b

alan

ce

An

imp

ort-

exp

ort c

omp

lem

enta

tion

sch

eme

allo

ws

bot

h

orig

inal

equ

ipm

ent m

anu

fact

uri

ng

and

com

pon

ent

man

ufa

ctu

res

to e

arn

du

ty c

red

its

from

exp

orti

ng.

Th

ese

du

ty c

red

its

can

then

be

use

d to

off

set i

mp

ort d

uti

es o

n c

ars,

co

mp

onen

ts o

r m

ater

ials

. Th

ey c

an a

lso

be s

old

on

the

open

m

arke

t -

Veh

icle

man

ufa

ctu

rers

pro

du

cin

g on

a C

KD

bas

is e

njo

y a

27%

du

ty-f

ree

allo

wan

ce o

f th

eir

wh

oles

ale

veh

icle

sal

es

turn

over

-

For

ever

y R

1 of

loca

l con

ten

t veh

icle

s ex

por

ted

, R1

wor

th o

f d

uty

-fre

e im

por

ts o

n v

ehic

les

or c

omp

onen

ts a

re a

llow

ed

For

ever

y R

1 of

com

pon

ents

exp

orte

d, R

0.75

of v

ehic

les

and

R

1 of

com

pon

ents

can

be

imp

orte

d d

uty

-fre

e -

Th

ere

is a

n a

dd

itio

nal

form

ula

-bas

ed s

mal

l veh

icle

du

ty-

free

allo

wan

ce in

res

pec

t of v

ehic

les

bel

ow a

net

ex-

fact

ory

pri

ce o

f R40

,000

-

Th

ere

is a

n e

xcis

e d

uty

on

CB

U’s

pen

alis

ing

imp

orts

of

exp

ensi

ve v

ehic

les

Mot

or in

du

stry

in

vest

men

t ros

e fr

om R

85.4

m. i

n

1995

to R

2,34

5m. i

n

2001

V

ehic

le e

xpor

ts

incr

ease

d b

y 12

74%

in

infla

tion

-ad

just

ed

Ran

d v

alu

e d

uri

ng

the

sam

e p

erio

d

Du

e fo

r p

has

e-ou

t b

y 20

12

Kap

lan

(20

03)

esti

mat

es v

alu

e of

fo

rgon

e re

ven

ue

to

be

R8.

4 b

n in

200

2 (f

orgo

ne

tax

reve

nu

e at

40%

of 2

1 bn

cr

edit

reb

ates

ea

rned

)

Page 54: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

46R

edu

ctio

n in

indi

rect

ta

xes

Impl

emen

tin

g ag

ency

O

bjec

tive

s D

etai

ls

Bu

dget

cos

t/ta

ke-

up/

oth

er is

sues

MID

P –

Pro

du

ctiv

e A

sset

A

llow

ance

D

TI/

ITA

C

En

cou

rage

s in

vest

men

t in

th

is s

ecto

r an

d th

e ra

tion

alis

atio

n o

f mod

el

ran

ges

by

man

ufa

ctu

rers

of

sp

ecif

ied

ligh

t mot

or

veh

icle

s

20%

of t

he

valu

e of

the

inve

stm

ent,

sp

read

eq

ual

ly o

ver

a 5-

year

per

iod

Du

ty C

red

it C

erti

fica

te

Sch

eme

for

Tex

tile

s In

du

stry

DT

I T

emp

orar

y ki

ck-s

tart

m

easu

re to

en

han

ce

exp

ort c

omp

etit

iven

ess

(Tar

gete

d a

t SM

ME

s)

Exp

orte

rs o

f tex

tile

s an

d c

loth

ing

can

ear

n d

uty

cre

dit

s on

im

por

ts o

f in

pu

ts a

s fo

llow

s: c

loth

ing

& c

loth

ing

acce

ssor

ies

(30%

); h

ouse

hol

d te

xtile

s (2

0%);

fab

ric

& o

ther

text

iles

(15%

);

and

yar

n (

10%

)

Less

su

cces

sfu

l th

an

envi

sage

d34

Tar

iff R

ebat

e/R

efu

nd

P

rovi

sion

s D

TI/

BT

T

Pro

mot

ion

of

man

ufa

ctu

rin

g an

d

exp

orti

ng

Ava

ilab

le to

all

man

ufa

ctu

rin

g in

du

stri

es

Pro

visi

on fo

r re

bat

e or

dra

wb

ack

of c

erta

in d

uti

es a

pp

licab

le

to im

por

ted

goo

ds,

raw

mat

eria

ls a

nd

com

pon

ents

use

d in

m

anu

fact

uri

ng,

pro

cess

ing

or fo

r ex

por

t

Tar

iff i

ncr

ease

s to

p

rovi

de

pro

tect

ion

D

TI/

BT

T

Pro

tect

dom

esti

c in

du

stry

fr

om o

vers

eas

com

pet

itio

n

Ap

plic

atio

n fo

r ta

riff

incr

ease

s ca

n b

e m

ade

to th

e D

TI/

BT

T

Non

-fis

cal

Impl

emen

tin

g ag

ency

O

bjec

tive

s D

etai

ls

Bu

dget

cos

t/ta

ke-

up/

oth

er is

sues

Red

uce

d e

lect

rici

ty r

ates

Esk

om o

r lo

cal

mu

nic

ipal

ity

Faci

litat

e in

vest

men

t ‘S

pec

ial d

eals

’ are

ava

ilab

le w

ith

Esk

om fo

r sp

ecif

ic la

rge

cust

omer

s on

a n

egot

iate

d b

asis

. Or:

- So

me

loca

l au

thor

itie

s of

fer

low

er e

lect

rici

ty r

ates

as

ince

nti

ves

to c

erta

in s

ecto

rs o

r lo

cati

ons

Red

uce

d tr

ansp

orta

tion

ra

tes

Tra

nsn

et

Faci

litat

e in

vest

men

t R

edu

ced

rai

l rat

es a

re a

vaila

ble

for

com

mod

itie

s ex

por

ted

on

a

con

trac

tual

bas

is

Roa

d tr

ansp

ort c

once

ssio

ns

can

be

neg

otia

ted

wit

h th

e lo

cal

Roa

d T

ran

spor

tati

on B

oard

Ind

ust

rial

Dev

elop

men

t Z

ones

DT

I/SA

RS

Ric

har

ds

Bay

; JIA

; Eas

t Lo

nd

on; C

oega

IDZ

D

uty

-fre

e an

d V

AT

-fre

e im

por

ts fo

r ex

por

ters

bas

ed in

IDZ

lo

cati

ons

G

ood

tran

spor

t an

d o

ther

infr

astr

uct

ure

lin

ks

On

e-st

op s

hop

reg

ula

tory

ap

pro

val

Inve

stm

ent l

ess

than

fo

reca

st; p

artl

y b

ecau

se ID

Z

adva

nta

ges

erod

ed

by

gen

eral

tari

ffs

red

uct

ion

s

34

UN

CT

AD

(20

03).

Page 55: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

47Le

gisl

atio

n a

nd

poli

cies

pr

omot

ing

inve

stm

ent

Impl

emen

tin

g ag

ency

O

bjec

tive

s D

etai

ls

Bu

dget

cos

t/ta

ke-

up/

oth

er is

sues

R

estr

uct

uri

ng

of S

tate

- O

wn

ed E

nte

rpri

ses

DP

E

Rai

se b

lack

ow

ner

ship

of

equ

ity

in S

A b

usi

nes

ses

19%

of l

icen

ces

for

2nd

fixe

d li

ne

net

wor

k op

erat

or r

eser

ved

fo

r b

lack

eq

uit

y in

vest

ors

M

iner

als

& P

etro

leu

m D

evel

opm

ent B

ill (2

002)

cre

ates

a

seri

es o

f op

por

tun

itie

s fo

r b

lack

en

trep

ren

eurs

to g

ain

acc

ess

to m

inin

g lic

ence

s

Ind

epen

den

t B

road

cast

ing

Au

thor

ity

Act

D

ereg

ula

tes

the

bro

adca

stin

g in

du

stry

, an

d

enco

ura

ges

dom

esti

c in

vest

men

t

Issu

ed a

free

to a

ir T

V li

cen

ce

Issu

ed 8

pri

vate

sou

nd

bro

adca

ster

lice

nce

s Li

mit

s fo

reig

n o

wn

ersh

ip to

20%

of t

otal

eq

uit

y in

an

in

div

idu

al b

road

cast

er

Spat

ial D

evel

opm

ent

Init

iati

ves

DT

I E

con

omic

dev

elop

men

t of

geog

rap

hic

ally

dis

cret

e re

gion

s w

ith

bot

h h

igh

gr

owth

pot

enti

al a

nd

a

his

tory

of e

con

omic

m

argi

nal

isat

ion

Com

ple

men

tary

pu

blic

an

d p

riva

te in

vest

men

ts, n

eith

er o

f w

hic

h w

ould

hav

e b

een

mad

e w

ith

out t

he

pre

sen

ce o

f th

e ot

her

Now

som

ewh

at

def

un

ct

Dou

ble

Tax

atio

n

Agr

eem

ents

SA

RS

Pro

mot

e FD

I by

neg

otia

tin

g d

oub

le-

taxa

tion

agr

eem

ents

wit

h

sou

rce/

hos

t cou

ntr

ies

53 e

xist

ing

and

26

un

der

neg

otia

tion

-

Wor

k P

lace

Ch

alle

nge

D

TI

En

han

ces

co-o

per

atio

n

bet

wee

n w

orke

rs a

nd

m

anag

emen

t to

boos

t co

mp

etit

iven

ess

and

em

plo

ymen

t th

rou

gh

imp

rove

d in

du

stri

al

per

form

ance

an

d

pro

du

ctiv

ity

DT

I pay

s 75

% o

f cos

t of t

he

sch

eme.

Com

pan

ies

pay

25%

B

i-p

arti

san

bu

sin

ess/

trad

e u

nio

n c

omm

itte

e es

tab

lish

ed th

at

is c

omm

itte

d to

the

WP

C

Min

imu

m c

omp

any

size

det

erm

ined

on

sec

tora

l bas

is (e

.g. 6

co

mp

anie

s in

ch

emic

als)

Ind

ust

rial

Par

tici

pat

ion

P

rogr

am (

Off

-Set

) D

TI/

NT

T

o le

vera

ge th

e b

enef

its

and

su

pp

ort t

he

dev

elop

men

t of S

A

ind

ust

ry b

y ef

fect

ivel

y u

tilis

ing

gove

rnm

ent

pro

cure

men

t. (N

ot a

n

ince

nti

ve, b

ut o

blig

atio

n

wh

en c

ontr

acti

ng

wit

h th

e go

vern

men

t)

All

gove

rnm

ent a

nd

par

asta

tal p

urc

has

es o

r le

ase

con

trac

ts

wit

h a

n im

por

ted

con

ten

t >U

S$10

m. (

Sup

plie

rs to

the

gove

rnm

ent a

re s

ub

ject

to a

n in

du

stri

al p

arti

cip

atio

n

oblig

atio

n o

f 30%

of t

he

imp

orte

d c

onte

nt)

Page 56: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

48In

dust

rial

fin

anci

ng

acti

viti

es

Impl

emen

tin

g ag

ency

O

bjec

tive

s D

etai

ls

Bu

dget

cos

t/ta

ke-

up/

oth

er is

sues

Kh

ula

En

terp

rise

s K

hu

la is

par

t of

DT

I E

stab

lish

ed to

en

han

ce th

e av

aila

bili

ty o

f loa

n a

nd

eq

uit

y ca

pit

al to

sm

all,

med

ium

an

d m

icro

-en

terp

rise

s

Kh

ula

is r

egis

tere

d a

s in

sure

r u

nd

er th

e In

sura

nce

A

men

dm

ent A

ct (4

9 of

199

8). I

t is

gove

rned

in te

rms

of th

e re

gula

tion

s of

the

Fin

anci

al S

ervi

ces

Boa

rd

Kh

ula

Sta

rt

T

o p

rom

ote

acce

ss to

m

icro

-cre

dit

in r

ura

l are

as,

esp

ecia

lly w

omen

to

star

t/ex

pan

d a

ny

bu

sin

ess

acti

vity

Loan

s to

gro

up

s of

3-1

0 m

emb

ers

of R

300-

R3,

500

Kh

ula

: Tec

hn

olog

y T

ran

sfer

Gu

aran

tee

Fun

d

T

o p

rovi

de

loan

gu

aran

tees

for

SMM

Es

for

the

sole

pu

rpos

e of

ac

qu

irin

g m

anu

fact

uri

ng

tech

nol

ogy,

wh

ich

cou

ld

be

from

Sou

th A

fric

a or

in

tern

atio

nal

Ava

ilab

le to

SM

ME

s w

ith

an

ap

pro

val c

erti

fica

te fr

om C

SIR

fo

r a

tech

nol

ogy

eval

uat

ion

on

the

pro

pos

ed te

chn

olog

y to

b

e tr

ansf

erre

d b

efor

e ap

ply

ing

to a

fin

anci

al in

stit

uti

on fo

r a

TT

GF

guar

ante

e

Kh

ula

: Bu

sin

ess

Loan

for

RFI

s

To

exp

and

len

din

g to

SM

ME

s th

rou

gh p

rovi

sion

of

bu

sin

ess

loan

s to

RFI

s fo

r on

-len

din

g

Less

exp

erie

nce

d R

FIs:

R1m

. to

R10

m.

Mor

e ex

per

ien

ced

RFI

s: R

2m. t

o R

100m

. N

egot

iab

le in

tere

st r

ates

, rep

aym

ent t

erm

s an

d s

ecu

rity

Kh

ula

: Cap

acit

y-B

uild

ing

Sup

por

t for

R

etai

l Fin

anci

al

Inte

rmed

iari

es (

RFI

s)

P

rovi

de

cap

acit

y-b

uild

ing

sup

por

t to

RFI

s C

apac

ity-

bu

ildin

g su

pp

ort t

o R

FIs

in s

uch

form

s as

: str

ateg

ic

pla

nn

ing

and

acc

oun

tin

g sy

stem

s, d

ebto

r sy

stem

s, tr

ain

ing

of lo

an o

ffic

ers,

an

d s

kills

dev

elop

men

t for

BoD

Kh

ula

: Cre

dit

Gu

aran

tee

Sch

eme

E

nab

les

entr

epre

neu

rs to

ac

cess

fin

ance

from

the

form

al fi

nan

cial

sec

tor

thro

ugh

cre

dit

gu

aran

tees

to

the

form

er, f

or th

e es

tab

lish

men

t, ex

pan

sion

or

acq

uis

itio

n o

f a n

ew o

r ex

isti

ng

bu

sin

ess

Ind

ivid

ual

Gu

aran

tees

: Sec

uri

ty o

f up

to R

600,

000

over

3

year

s to

ban

k p

rovi

din

g lo

an to

ind

ivid

ual

In

stit

uti

onal

Gu

aran

tees

: Gu

aran

tees

to b

ank

to p

rovi

de

loan

s fo

r on

-len

din

g b

y R

FIs

Por

tfol

io G

uar

ante

es: I

nd

emn

ity

for

up

to 8

0% o

f los

ses

on

RFI

’s lo

an p

ortf

olio

Page 57: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

49In

dust

rial

fin

anci

ng

acti

viti

es

Impl

emen

tin

g ag

ency

O

bjec

tive

s D

etai

ls

Bu

dget

cos

t/ta

ke-

up/

oth

er is

sues

Kh

ula

: Eq

uit

y Fu

nd

Fun

d jo

int v

entu

res,

ex

pan

sion

s, r

e-ca

pit

alis

atio

ns

and

bu

yin

g ou

t of e

xist

ing

shar

ehol

der

s

Eq

uit

y st

ake

in e

nte

rpri

se o

f not

mor

e th

an 4

9%, d

isin

vest

ed

wit

hin

7 y

ears

Kh

ula

: See

d L

oan

s fo

r R

etai

l Fin

anci

al

Inte

rmed

iari

es (

RFI

s)

P

rovi

de

star

t-u

p c

apit

al to

n

ew R

FIs

wh

ose

targ

et

mar

ket i

s SM

ME

s an

d fu

nd

op

erat

ion

al e

xpen

ses

over

a

pre

det

erm

ined

per

iod

Inte

rest

-fre

e lo

ans

of b

etw

een

R50

,000

an

d R

20m

. Se

ed lo

ans

can

be

con

vert

ed to

gra

nts

on

ce m

utu

ally

agr

eed

p

erfo

rman

ce c

rite

ria

are

met

Dev

elop

men

t Ban

k of

So

uth

Afr

ica

DB

SA

Sub

sid

ised

loan

s to

fa

cilit

ate

infr

astr

uct

ure

(W

ater

an

d S

anit

atio

n,

Solid

Was

te M

anag

emen

t, T

ran

spor

t, E

ner

gy,

Tel

ecom

mu

nic

atio

ns,

H

ealt

h, E

du

cati

on, E

co-

Tou

rism

)

Pro

vid

es fi

nan

cial

an

d/o

r te

chn

ical

ser

vice

s to

leve

rage

p

riva

te s

ecto

r in

fras

tru

ctu

re p

rovi

sion

that

wou

ld n

ot

oth

erw

ise

be

real

ised

thro

ugh

com

mer

cial

ban

ks

Fin

ance

: Lon

g-te

rm (

20 –

25

year

s) fi

nan

ce in

the

follo

win

g fo

rms:

Lo

an fi

nan

ce

Eq

uit

y in

vest

men

ts

Gu

aran

tees

R

efin

anci

ng

com

mit

men

ts

Tec

hn

ical

ass

ista

nce

: Ass

ista

nce

in fi

nan

ce s

tru

ctu

rin

g,

neg

otia

tion

an

d w

ith

res

pec

t to

the

ten

der

pro

cess

Lan

d B

ank

Lan

d B

ank

Faci

litat

e ag

ricu

ltu

ral

dev

elop

men

t th

rou

gh

con

cess

ion

al lo

ans

Spec

ific

Sch

emes

incl

ud

e:

Pro

du

ctio

n c

red

it. L

oan

s fo

r 3-

5 ye

ars

top

cov

er a

cqu

isit

ion

of

inp

uts

Se

ctio

n 3

4 Lo

ans:

Med

ium

term

fin

ance

(5-

8 ye

ars)

to c

over

ac

qu

isit

ion

of l

ives

tock

, veh

icle

s, tr

acto

rs e

tc.

Mor

tgag

e Lo

ans

(25

year

s): A

cqu

isit

ion

of l

and

or

pro

per

ty

Step

-Up

loan

s of

R25

0-R

18,0

00 r

epay

able

ove

r 6

mon

ths

All

req

uir

e ad

equ

ate

secu

rity

, deb

t rat

io a

nd

rep

aym

ent

abili

ty

Page 58: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

50In

dust

rial

fin

anci

ng

acti

viti

es

Impl

emen

tin

g ag

ency

O

bjec

tive

s D

etai

ls

Bu

dget

cos

t/ta

ke-

up/

oth

er is

sues

IDC

ID

C

Con

trib

uti

ng

to e

con

omic

gr

owth

, in

du

stri

al

dev

elop

men

t an

d

econ

omic

em

pow

erm

ent

thro

ugh

its

fin

anci

ng

acti

viti

es. (

Deb

t, e

qu

ity

or

qu

asi-

equ

ity)

Se

e w

ww

.idc.

co.z

a

Loan

s at

2-2

.5%

less

than

pri

me

Eq

uit

y or

qu

asi-

equ

ity

stak

es

R 2

6 b

n o

f deb

t an

d

equ

ity

un

der

m

anag

emen

t in

20

03/2

004

IDC

: Bri

dgi

ng

Fin

ance

Ass

ista

nce

to e

mer

gin

g in

du

stri

alis

ts w

ith

sh

ort-

term

fin

anci

ng

nee

ds

An

nu

al tu

rnov

er m

ust

be

>R1m

., an

d fi

nan

cin

g re

quir

emen

t >R

500,

000

IDC

: Em

pow

erm

ent

Fin

ance

Ass

ista

nce

to e

mer

gin

g in

du

stri

alis

ts w

ish

ing

to

acq

uir

e a

stak

e in

a fo

rmal

b

usi

nes

s

Tot

al fi

nan

cin

g re

quir

emen

t bet

wee

n R

5m a

nd

R10

0m.

Min

imu

m c

ash

con

trib

uti

on fr

om th

e en

trep

ren

eur

of 1

0%

IDC

: En

trep

ren

euri

al

Min

ing

& Je

wel

lery

Fi

nan

ce

A

ssis

tan

ce to

SM

ME

s in

m

inin

g an

d b

enef

icia

tion

ac

tivi

ties

an

d je

wel

lery

m

anu

fact

uri

ng

Est

ablis

h o

r ex

pan

d ju

nio

r m

inin

g h

ouse

s, a

cqu

ire

min

ing

asse

ts b

y H

DIs

, un

der

take

min

ing-

rela

ted

act

ivit

ies

such

as

con

trac

t min

ing,

or

esta

blis

h o

r ex

pan

d je

wel

lery

m

anu

fact

uri

ng

acti

viti

es

IDC

: Tec

hn

olog

y In

du

stry

Fin

ance

Dev

elop

men

t an

d

exp

ansi

on o

f tec

hn

olog

y-in

ten

sive

bu

sin

esse

s in

IT,

tele

com

s, e

lect

ron

ic a

nd

el

ectr

ical

ind

ust

ries

New

tech

ven

ture

s w

ith

pro

ven

tech

nol

ogy.

Min

imu

m

fin

anci

ng

of R

1m. (

loan

s, e

quit

y or

qu

asi-

equ

ity)

IDC

: Tou

rism

Fin

ance

Dev

elop

men

t an

d

exp

ansi

on o

f th

e to

uri

sm

ind

ust

ry

Med

ium

term

fin

anci

ng

(loa

ns,

equ

ity,

qu

asi-

equ

ity)

for

new

or

up

grad

ed to

uri

st fa

cilit

ies

IDC

: Man

ufa

ctu

rin

g Fi

nan

ce

D

evel

opm

ent a

nd

ex

pan

sion

of t

he

man

ufa

ctu

rin

g in

du

stry

Med

ium

term

fin

anci

ng

(loa

ns,

equ

ity,

qu

asi-

equ

ity)

, wit

h

min

imu

m fi

nan

cin

g re

qu

irem

ent o

f R1m

.

Page 59: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

51In

dust

rial

fin

anci

ng

acti

viti

es

Impl

emen

tin

g ag

ency

O

bjec

tive

s D

etai

ls

Bu

dget

cos

t/ta

ke-

up/

oth

er is

sues

IDC

: Agr

o Sc

hem

e

To

esta

blis

h fa

rmin

g in

fras

tru

ctu

re (o

rch

ard

s,

dam

s, c

anal

s, ir

riga

tion

sy

stem

s et

c.)

Med

ium

-ter

m fi

nan

cin

g (l

oan

s, e

quit

y, q

uas

i-eq

uit

y), w

ith

m

inim

um

fin

anci

ng

req

uir

emen

t of R

1m. O

rch

ard

s co

vere

d

are

citr

us,

dec

idu

ous

and

su

b-t

rop

ical

, an

d a

t lea

st 1

0 n

ew

jobs

at a

cap

ital

cos

t per

job

of R

100

000

or le

ss n

eed

to b

e cr

eate

d to

qu

alify

IDC

: Tra

de

Fin

ance

Sy

stem

To

assi

st lo

cal i

mp

orte

rs

and

exp

orte

rs o

f cap

ital

go

ods

Imp

orte

rs o

f cap

ital

goo

ds

and

ser

vice

s ar

e p

rovi

ded

acc

ess

to c

red

it a

nd

gu

aran

tee

faci

litie

s (s

uch

as

Def

erm

ent o

f P

aym

ent S

chem

e an

d D

uty

Dra

wb

ack

Sch

eme)

IDC

: Ven

ture

cap

ital

sc

hem

e

To

stim

ula

te th

e d

evel

opm

ent o

f new

p

rod

uct

s w

ith

sou

nd

gr

owth

pot

enti

al

A fi

nan

cin

g p

acka

ge is

ava

ilab

le, w

hic

h c

an in

clu

de

a st

ake-

hol

din

g b

y th

e ID

C (

equ

ity

or q

uas

i-eq

uit

y)

IDC

: En

trep

ren

euri

al

fin

ance

sch

eme

Th

e p

urp

ose

is to

ass

ist

new

en

trep

ren

eurs

or

his

tori

cally

dis

adva

nta

ged

in

div

idu

als

(HD

Is)

to g

ain

ac

cess

to m

ain

stre

am

econ

omic

act

ivit

ies

Man

ufa

ctu

rin

g b

usi

nes

s u

sual

ly r

equ

ires

ow

ner

fun

din

g of

at

leas

t 33%

to 4

0% o

f tot

al fu

nd

ing

to e

nsu

re lo

ng-

term

vi

abili

ty. T

he

sch

eme

pro

vid

es fo

r a

red

uce

d c

ontr

ibu

tion

, w

ith

the

IDC

pro

vid

ing

a la

rger

than

nor

mal

con

trib

uti

on o

f th

e p

roje

ct fu

nd

ing

IDC

: Tak

eove

r an

d

acq

uis

itio

n s

chem

e

To

assi

st H

DIs

in a

cqu

irin

g a

sign

ific

ant s

take

in a

n

ind

ust

rial

con

cern

Max

imu

m o

f R10

0m. p

er p

roje

ct

IDC

: Con

sort

ium

fi

nan

ce s

chem

e

Aim

ed a

t ass

isti

ng

emp

ower

men

t gro

up

s to

in

crea

se th

eir

equ

ity

bas

e

IDC

: Wh

oles

ale

fin

ance

sc

hem

e

En

han

ce w

hol

esal

e fu

nd

ing

to in

term

edia

ries

T

his

sch

eme

is a

vaila

ble

to c

omp

anie

s or

fran

chis

es fo

r on

-le

nd

ing

to e

mer

gin

g en

trep

ren

eurs

. It h

as to

invo

lve

a m

inim

um

of t

en p

roje

cts

(at l

east

60%

HD

I) a

nd

a m

inim

um

fi

nan

cin

g re

qu

irem

ent o

f R1m

.

IDC

: Cle

aner

pro

du

ctio

n

sch

eme

Pro

mot

e in

vest

men

t in

cl

ean

er te

chn

olog

ies

Th

is s

chem

e p

rovi

des

fin

ance

for

acq

uis

itio

n o

f fix

ed a

sset

s to

con

trol

/ab

ate

pol

luti

on, p

rote

ct e

nvi

ron

men

t, s

afeg

uar

d

exp

orts

(at

nor

mal

inte

rest

rat

es)

Page 60: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

52In

dust

rial

fin

anci

ng

acti

viti

es

Impl

emen

tin

g ag

ency

O

bjec

tive

s D

etai

ls

Bu

dget

cos

t/ta

ke-

up/

oth

er is

sues

IDC

: Mid

i pro

ject

s in

itia

tive

Th

e p

urp

ose

is to

st

imu

late

the

esta

blis

hm

ent o

f new

, in

tern

atio

nal

ly

com

pet

itiv

e m

ediu

m-s

ized

in

du

stri

al m

anu

fact

uri

ng

pro

ject

s

Th

is is

don

e th

rou

gh fi

nan

cin

g an

d k

now

led

ge-b

ased

inp

uts

w

ith

res

pec

t to

esta

blis

hm

ent o

f via

ble

ind

ust

rial

pro

ject

s w

ith

fun

din

g n

eed

s b

etw

een

R10

m. a

nd

R50

0m. t

hat

are

co

mp

etit

ive

inte

rnat

ion

ally

IDC

: Sta

nd

ard

Lea

sed

Fa

ctor

y Sc

hem

e

To

incr

ease

ind

ust

rial

ists

’ ca

pit

al, c

ash

flow

an

d

bor

row

ing

pow

er

IDC

mak

es g

ener

al p

urp

ose

fact

ory

bu

ildin

gs a

vaila

ble

for

leas

e

Exp

ort C

red

it a

nd

Fo

reig

n In

vest

men

t R

ein

sura

nce

+Sc

hem

e

CG

IC

Faci

litat

e an

d e

nco

ura

ge

Sou

th A

fric

an e

xpor

t tra

de

by

un

der

wri

tin

g b

ank

loan

s an

d in

vest

men

t ou

tsid

e th

e co

un

try

in

ord

er to

en

able

fore

ign

b

uye

rs to

pu

rch

ase

cap

ital

go

ods

and

ser

vice

s fr

om

the

Rep

ubl

ic. T

o ac

hie

ve

this

ob

ject

ive,

the

corp

orat

ion

eva

luat

es

exp

ort c

red

it a

nd

fore

ign

in

vest

men

t ris

ks a

nd

p

rovi

des

exp

ort c

red

it a

nd

fo

reig

n in

vest

men

t in

sura

nce

cov

er o

n b

ehal

f of

gov

ern

men

t (R

ein

sura

nce

by

DT

I)

Off

ered

in te

rms

of E

xpor

t Cre

dit

an

d F

orei

gn In

vest

men

t R

ein

sura

nce

Act

. All

faci

litie

s ar

e av

aila

ble

thro

ugh

Cre

dit

G

uar

ante

e In

sura

nce

Cor

por

atio

n o

f Afr

ica

Lim

ited

(C

HIC

).

Wh

ere

app

licab

le, f

acili

ties

are

rei

nsu

red

wit

h th

e D

TI.

Fiv

e d

iffe

ren

t fac

iliti

es a

re a

vaila

ble

: 1.

SM

ME

Exp

ort F

inan

ce S

chem

e: L

oan

bet

wee

n R

50,0

00

and

R1m

. Pre

miu

m r

ates

of 0

.75%

to 3

% d

epen

din

g on

loan

p

erio

d a

nd

ris

k. S

MM

E d

efin

ed a

s to

tal a

sset

s <R

5m.

2. S

hor

t-te

rm fi

nan

ce: (

Pre

-sh

ipm

ent c

over

; pos

t sh

ipm

ent

cove

r; C

onsi

gnm

ent s

tock

cov

er)

3.

Med

ium

/Lon

g-T

erm

Insu

ran

ce: I

nsu

ran

ce o

f rep

aym

ent

risk

s ov

er 2

-10

year

s

4. E

xpor

t Fin

ance

for

Cap

ital

Goo

ds

and

Pro

ject

s: M

inim

um

p

urc

has

e of

R10

0,00

0. L

oan

an

d F

orE

x co

ver

pro

vid

ed

5. F

orei

gn In

vest

men

t Gu

aran

tees

: In

sure

s SA

inve

stor

s in

fo

reig

n c

oun

trie

s ag

ain

st p

olit

ical

ris

ks. M

inim

um

in

vest

men

t R10

0,00

0

Pay

men

ts to

CG

IC

of R

195m

. in

200

2/3

Dom

esti

c C

red

it

Insu

ran

ce

CG

IC

Faci

litat

e ex

por

ts

Pro

tect

ion

aga

inst

non

-pay

men

t of d

ebts

incu

rred

by

deb

tors

bas

ed in

Sou

th A

fric

a an

d th

e C

MA

. Cov

er a

gain

st

non

-pay

men

t of d

ebts

Incl

ud

ed in

the

abov

e fig

ure

Sou

rces

: ww

w.t

hed

ti.g

ov.z

a; D

PR

U (

2001

); w

ww

.idc.

co.z

a

Page 61: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

53A

nn

ex 3

: A

pp

lica

tion

to

Sou

th A

fric

a of

th

e U

ser’

s G

uid

e to

th

e D

unn

-Pel

lech

io M

ETR

M

odel

: 2

00

4

Par

amet

er

SA B

ench

mar

k P

hys

ical

Inve

stm

ent.

Use

r sp

ecif

ies

the

com

pos

itio

n o

f th

e ca

pit

al in

vest

men

t by

des

ign

atin

g p

erce

nta

ges

(wh

ich

sh

ould

ad

d to

100

%)

for

each

of f

our

cate

gori

es: L

and

, B

uild

ing,

Mac

hin

ery

and

Eq

uip

men

t, a

nd

Veh

icle

s U

ser

has

the

opti

on to

sp

ecify

wh

eth

er th

e ca

pit

al s

tock

is m

ain

tain

ed th

rou

gh r

e-in

vest

men

t eac

h y

ear

to r

epla

ce e

con

omic

wea

r an

d te

ar. T

his

is d

one

by

ente

rin

g ‘1

’ fo

r th

e p

aram

eter

‘Rep

lace

Ori

gin

al In

vest

men

t’ in

cel

l C12

. Th

is is

the

def

ault

op

tion

. (T

he

rate

of d

epre

ciat

ion

is s

pec

ifie

d s

epar

atel

y in

the

blo

ck s

tart

ing

at c

ell B

40)

Init

ially

set

at L

and

(20%

), B

uild

ing

(20%

), M

ach

iner

y (5

0%)

and

V

ehic

les

(10%

) In

itia

lly s

et a

s ca

pit

al s

tock

mai

nta

ined

Op

erat

ion

. Th

e u

ser

mu

st p

rovi

de

the

targ

et ‘R

eal B

efor

e T

ax R

ate

of R

etu

rn’ a

nd

the

oper

atin

g p

erio

d fo

r th

e in

vest

men

t. T

he

Mod

el a

ssu

mes

that

the

pro

ject

is s

hu

t dow

n

and

sol

d a

t th

e en

d o

f th

e op

erat

ing

per

iod

, gen

erat

ing

a ca

pit

al g

ain

M

axim

um

op

erat

ing

per

iod

is 3

0 ye

ars

T

he

shar

e of

an

nu

al p

rofi

ts r

etai

ned

by

the

firm

aft

er e

xpen

ses

and

taxe

s is

en

tere

d a

s th

e p

aram

eter

‘Ret

. Ear

. % o

f aft

er ta

x’. T

he

def

ault

val

ue

is 0

%

Est

imat

e vi

a C

AP

M o

f (re

al) 1

6%. (

9.27

%35

+ β

*6.7

%36

= 1

6%, a

ssu

min

g β

of 1

) N

omin

al is

ther

efor

e (1

.16/

1.07

2-1)

= 8

.2%

Se

t at 1

0 ye

ars.

Th

e m

odel

is v

ery

sen

siti

ve to

this

par

amet

er

Set a

t 20%

bec

ause

: (a)

mod

el s

imu

late

s a

star

t-u

p c

omp

any,

like

ly to

u

se R

Es

as c

apit

al; a

nd

(b

) h

elp

s ca

ptu

re th

e ef

fect

of S

econ

dar

y T

ax o

n

Com

pan

ies

(ST

C)

- (L

ikel

y to

be

zero

in fo

r p

riva

te li

mit

ed c

omp

anie

s)

Fin

anci

ng.

If th

e p

roje

ct is

fin

ance

d e

nti

rely

by

equ

ity

then

the

use

r se

ts th

e ‘D

ebt’

p

aram

eter

to 0

%; o

ther

wis

e en

ter

the

app

rop

riat

e sh

are

of d

ebt f

inan

cin

g. If

deb

t is

use

d, t

hen

it is

nec

essa

ry to

en

ter

the

‘Loa

n T

erm

’ an

d ‘I

nte

rest

rat

e on

Deb

t’

(nom

inal

). T

he

def

ault

loan

term

is th

e op

erat

ing

per

iod

for

the

pro

ject

T

he

cell

‘Con

stan

t D/E

?’ is

use

d to

sp

ecif

y w

het

her

the

Deb

t to

Eq

uit

y ra

tio

is to

be

hel

d c

onst

ant t

hro

ugh

the

du

rati

on o

f th

e p

roje

ct. I

f th

e p

aram

eter

is 0

, th

en th

e st

ock

of d

ebt d

rop

s ea

ch y

ear.

Set

tin

g th

is to

1 (t

he

def

ault

op

tion

) im

plie

s th

at th

e in

vest

or

bor

row

s ea

ch y

ear

to k

eep

the

deb

t-eq

uit

y ra

tio

con

stan

t. T

he

‘Yea

rs In

tere

st O

nly

’ p

aram

eter

allo

ws

the

use

r to

sp

ecif

y a

grac

e p

erio

d in

wh

ich

ther

e is

no

rep

aym

ent o

f p

rin

cip

al. T

he

def

ault

val

ue

is 0

Init

ially

set

at 2

8% d

ebt,

72%

eq

uit

y. A

vera

ge P

LC d

ebt/

equ

ity

rati

o in

SA

is 4

0%. (

60%

for

SMM

Es)

37

Loan

term

10

year

s to

mat

ch p

roje

ct li

fe

35

Ris

k Fr

ee R

etu

rn o

n a

10

year

GSA

Bon

d.

36 E

qu

ity

Ris

k P

rem

ium

of 6

.7%

take

n fr

om D

imso

n, e

t al.

(200

3).

37 S

ourc

e: R

BSA

, Qu

arte

rly

Bu

lleti

n a

nd

ad

vice

from

a c

orp

orat

e la

w fi

rm in

Sou

th A

fric

a.

Page 62: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

54P

aram

eter

SA

Ben

chm

ark

Fin

anci

ng

(con

t.).

Th

e ‘A

mou

nt B

orro

wed

’ is

com

pu

ted

au

tom

atic

ally

from

the

inve

stm

ent a

mou

nt a

nd

the

per

cen

tage

of D

ebt.

Th

is c

ell s

hou

ld n

ot b

e ch

ange

d. T

he

‘Loa

n P

aym

ent’

par

amet

er is

als

o d

eter

min

ed a

uto

mat

ical

ly b

ased

on

con

stan

t p

aym

ents

(in

tere

st a

nd

pri

nci

pal

) fo

r th

e sp

ecif

ied

loan

term

an

d in

tere

st r

ate.

T

he

def

ault

val

ue

for

the

‘In

tere

st R

ate

on D

ebt’

is s

et e

qual

to th

e ta

rget

bef

ore-

tax

rate

of r

etu

rn fo

r th

e p

roje

ct. T

his

sp

ecifi

cati

on k

eep

s th

e b

efor

e-ta

x ra

te o

f ret

urn

co

nst

ant f

or a

ny

give

n d

ebt r

atio

. Bu

t it i

s an

un

real

isti

c as

sum

pti

on, s

o th

e u

ser

may

w

ish

to e

nte

r a

dif

fere

nt i

nte

rest

rat

e. In

this

cas

e th

e re

alis

ed r

ate

of r

etu

rn b

efor

e ta

x m

ay d

iffe

r fr

om th

e ta

rget

rat

e in

the

pre

sen

ce o

f deb

t or

reta

ined

ear

nin

gs. S

ince

the

nu

mer

ator

an

d d

enom

inat

or fo

r th

e M

ET

R c

alcu

lati

on a

re e

qual

ly a

ffec

ted

, th

e M

ET

R

resu

lt is

un

chan

ged

. T

he

mod

el a

ssu

mes

a c

onst

ant r

ate

of in

flati

on r

ate

thro

ugh

out t

he

pro

ject

life

. Th

is is

en

tere

d a

s th

e p

aram

eter

‘In

flati

on R

ate’

Init

ially

set

at 1

= c

onst

ant d

ebt/

equ

ity

rati

o In

itia

lly s

et a

t zer

o: n

o ye

ars

of in

tere

st, o

nly

pay

men

ts

Inte

rest

rat

e se

t at 1

2% =

cu

rren

t ave

rage

med

ium

/ lo

ng-

term

inte

rest

ra

te in

the

com

mer

cial

mar

ket

7.2%

(= p

rod

uce

r p

rice

infla

tion

bet

wee

n 1

996

and

200

3)

Tax

es o

n In

com

e. T

he

inco

me-

tax

rate

is th

e st

atu

tory

rat

e. In

cas

e of

a p

rogr

essi

ve ta

x ra

te, t

he

use

r sh

ould

en

ter

the

rate

that

is a

pp

rop

riat

e fo

r th

e ca

se u

nd

er in

vest

igat

ion

. Fo

r la

rge

taxp

ayer

s, u

sin

g th

e m

axim

um

rat

e is

ap

pro

pri

ate.

Th

e ce

lls ‘S

urt

ax R

ate’

an

d ‘S

urt

ax Y

ears

’ allo

w th

e u

ser

to s

pec

ify

a su

rtax

as

a p

erce

nta

ge o

f th

e in

com

e ta

x,

app

licab

le fo

r sp

ecif

ied

yea

rs fr

om th

e st

art o

f th

e p

roje

ct. I

f th

e ta

x sy

stem

has

a

min

imu

m ta

x as

a p

erce

nta

ge o

f rev

enu

e or

ass

ets,

then

the

use

r en

ters

the

per

tin

ent

tax

rate

in th

e ce

ll so

lab

elle

d. T

he

def

ault

val

ues

are

0%

, i.e

. no

min

imu

m ta

x

30%

CIT

Rat

e N

o su

rtax

N

o m

inim

um

tax

Ded

uct

ion

s. T

hes

e ce

lls in

dic

ate

wh

eth

er th

e ta

x sy

stem

allo

ws

ded

uct

ion

s fo

r w

ages

, m

ater

ials

an

d d

epre

ciat

ion

(yes

=1, n

o=0)

. Th

ere

is a

lso

an o

pti

on fo

r in

dic

atin

g w

het

her

an

d to

wh

at e

xten

t dep

reci

atio

n is

ind

exed

. If s

o, th

e d

efau

lt v

alu

e fo

r th

e ra

te

of in

dex

atio

n is

the

infla

tion

rat

e

Wag

es, m

ater

ials

an

d d

epre

ciat

ion

ded

uct

ion

s ar

e al

low

ed

No

ind

exat

ion

Deb

t. In

this

blo

ck th

e u

ser

can

allo

w fo

r th

e d

edu

ctio

n o

f in

tere

st p

aid

, an

d fo

r in

tere

st to

be

ind

exed

if a

llow

ed in

the

tax

cod

e. If

ind

exat

ion

is a

llow

ed, t

he

def

ault

va

lue

is th

e in

flati

on r

ate

Inte

rest

is d

edu

ctib

le, b

ut t

her

e is

no

ind

exin

g in

the

SA ta

x co

de

Cap

ital

Gai

ns.

In th

is b

lock

the

use

r sp

ecif

ies

the

Cap

ital

Gai

ns

Tax

(C

GT

) ra

te a

s ap

plie

d a

t th

e co

mp

any

leve

l. T

he

mod

el a

llow

s fo

ur

met

hod

s to

cal

cula

te C

apit

al

Gai

ns

in th

e ce

ll ‘C

ap G

ain

Op

tion

’. T

he

usu

al v

alu

e is

‘3.’

Th

is c

alcu

late

s th

e C

apit

al

Gai

n a

s Sa

le P

rice

less

the

adju

sted

bas

is, w

hic

h is

the

orig

inal

cos

t of t

he

asse

ts le

ss

dep

reci

atio

n a

llow

ance

s al

read

y ta

ken

. Th

e ad

just

ed b

asis

is s

omet

imes

cal

led

the

Wri

tten

Dow

n V

alu

e or

Boo

k V

alu

e of

the

Ass

ets.

Th

e m

odel

als

o al

low

s th

e u

ser

to

ind

icat

e w

het

her

cap

ital

gai

ns

are

ind

exed

, an

d if

so

by

how

mu

ch. A

not

her

imp

orta

nt

par

amet

er is

‘Cap

ital

Los

s O

ffse

t.’ I

f th

is is

set

to ‘1

’ th

e ta

x sy

stem

allo

ws

Cap

ital

Lo

sses

to b

e se

t off

aga

inst

inco

me

from

oth

er s

ourc

es. T

he

par

amet

er s

hou

ld b

e se

t to

‘0’ i

f cap

ital

loss

es a

re r

ing-

fen

ced

CG

T E

ffec

tive

rat

e fo

r co

mp

anie

s is

15%

(30

% o

f an

elig

ible

50%

) C

apit

al G

ain

s O

pti

on 3

ap

plie

s in

SA

N

o in

dex

ing

on C

apit

al G

ain

s

CG

T lo

sses

are

rin

g-fe

nce

d (

Set a

t 0)

Page 63: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

55P

aram

eter

SA

Ben

chm

ark

Loss

es a

nd

Un

use

d C

red

its.

Th

e M

odel

allo

ws

the

use

r to

sp

ecif

y th

e tr

eatm

ent o

f tax

lo

sses

. If t

he

par

amet

er F

ull

loss

off

set i

s se

t to

‘1’ t

hen

the

firm

ob

tain

s fu

ll be

nef

it

from

loss

es in

the

curr

ent p

erio

d b

y ap

ply

ing

usi

ng

them

to o

ffse

t in

com

e fr

om o

ther

ac

tivi

ties

. Th

is m

ay b

e th

e ca

se w

hen

the

pro

ject

is a

par

t of a

n e

nte

rpri

se g

rou

p w

ith

ot

her

taxa

ble

inco

me.

In th

is c

ase

the

offs

et a

uto

mat

ical

ly o

verr

ides

an

y ca

rry-

forw

ard

p

rovi

sion

If

the

pro

ject

is is

olat

ed a

nd

the

firm

is a

llow

ed to

car

ry o

ver

loss

es fr

om o

ne

per

iod

to

offs

et fu

ture

taxa

ble

inco

me,

then

the

‘Car

ry-O

ver

Loss

es’ p

aram

eter

is s

et to

‘1’ a

nd

th

e p

aram

eter

‘Fu

ll Lo

ss O

ffse

t’ is

set

to ‘0

’. If

on

ly a

cer

tain

per

cen

tage

of t

he

tax

loss

ca

n b

e ca

rrie

d fo

rwar

d, t

he

use

r en

ters

this

in th

e ce

ll ‘S

hr

Elig

ible

for

CO

L’. I

f un

use

d

loss

es a

re in

dex

ed w

hen

car

ried

forw

ard

the

par

amet

er ‘I

nd

ex C

OL’

is s

et to

‘1.’

Th

e d

efau

lt v

alu

e fo

r th

e ‘R

ate

of In

dex

atio

n’ i

s th

e in

flati

on r

ate

‘E

ligib

le Y

ears

’ is

the

nu

mb

er o

f yea

rs th

at th

e fa

cilit

y of

car

ryin

g fo

rwar

d lo

sses

is

allo

wed

. If t

his

is a

per

man

ent f

eatu

re o

f th

e ta

x sy

stem

, set

this

par

amet

er to

the

max

imu

m v

alu

e of

‘30’

. ‘Fo

rwar

d Y

ears

’ is

the

nu

mbe

r of

yea

rs th

at a

par

ticu

lar

loss

ca

n b

e ca

rrie

d fo

rwar

d. I

f th

is p

aram

eter

is s

et to

‘5’,

then

un

use

d lo

sses

can

be

carr

ied

fo

rwar

d fo

r n

o m

ore

than

5 y

ears

. If l

osse

s ca

n b

e ca

rrie

d fo

rwar

d in

def

init

ely,

en

ter

the

max

imu

m n

um

ber

of 3

0 h

ere.

‘Exe

mp

t Yea

rs’ i

s ap

plic

able

in th

e ca

se o

f Tax

H

olid

ays

and

ind

icat

es th

e n

um

ber

of y

ears

wh

en lo

sses

can

be

save

d a

nd

car

ried

fo

rwar

d o

nce

the

hol

iday

is c

omp

lete

d. A

fter

the

tax

hol

iday

, th

e lo

sses

can

be

carr

ied

fo

rwar

d in

the

nor

mal

man

ner

. Th

is c

ell i

s se

t eq

ual

to ‘0

’ if l

osse

s ca

n a

re c

arri

ed

forw

ard

du

rin

g a

tax

hol

iday

in th

e u

sual

man

ner

. Sim

ilar

spec

ific

atio

ns

app

ly to

the

carr

y fo

rwar

d o

f in

vest

men

t tax

cre

dit

s. A

lso,

if c

red

its

are

red

eem

able

for

cash

p

aym

ents

from

the

gove

rnm

ent,

the

‘Cre

dit

s R

edee

mab

le’ p

aram

eter

is s

et to

‘1’

SA ta

x co

de

allo

ws

full

loss

off

set f

or m

ult

iple

-act

ivit

y en

terp

rise

s

Cor

por

atio

ns

are

allo

wed

to c

arry

ove

r lo

sses

inte

r-te

mp

oral

ly

Init

ially

set

at C

arry

Ove

r Lo

sses

= 1

, Fu

ll Lo

ss O

ffse

t = 0

10

yea

rs

No

tax

hol

iday

s

Div

iden

ds.

Th

e d

ivid

end

sp

ecif

icat

ion

has

sev

eral

op

tion

s. T

he

use

r ca

n a

llow

for

ded

uct

ion

of d

ivid

end

pay

men

ts b

y se

ttin

g ‘D

edu

ct D

ivid

end

s’ e

qual

to ‘1

’. If

ther

e is

a

fin

al ta

x on

div

iden

d p

aym

ents

, th

e ra

te g

oes

in ‘D

ivd

Tax

/Cre

d (

+/-)

.’ If

the

syst

em

pro

vid

es fo

r cr

edit

s on

div

iden

ds

(to

avoi

d d

oub

le ta

x), t

he

per

cen

tage

is e

nte

red

her

e w

ith

a n

egat

ive

sign

. If t

ax is

wit

hh

eld

by

the

com

pan

y, b

ut f

inal

tax

is p

aid

by

the

inve

stor

as

per

son

al in

com

e ta

x, th

en th

is p

aram

eter

sh

ould

rem

ain

at ‘

0%’

If th

e ta

x sy

stem

allo

ws

for

cred

its

in th

e h

and

s of

the

shar

ehol

der

s of

cor

por

ate

tax

pai

d b

y th

e co

mp

any,

then

the

shar

e of

taxe

s p

aid

by

the

com

pan

y el

igib

le fo

r cr

edit

is

ente

red

in th

e p

aram

eter

‘Cor

p In

c T

ax C

red

it’.

On

the

oth

er h

and

, if t

he

tax

syst

em

mak

es th

e fir

m li

able

for

pay

ing

corp

orat

e in

com

e ta

x as

wel

l as

a w

ith

hol

din

g ta

x on

d

ivid

end

s th

at is

cre

dit

ed to

the

tax

liab

ility

of t

he

shar

ehol

der

, th

e ap

pro

pri

ate

shar

e of

the

corp

orat

e in

com

e ta

x sh

ould

be

ente

red

in th

e p

aram

eter

‘Cor

p In

c T

ax O

ffse

t’

Ben

chm

ark

= 1

STC

on

div

iden

ds

on 1

2.5%

N

o su

ch p

rovi

sion

exi

sts

in th

e SA

tax

cod

e

Page 64: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

56P

aram

eter

SA

Ben

chm

ark

Div

iden

ds

(con

t.).

Th

is c

red

its

the

shar

ehol

der

for

taxe

s p

aid

by

the

com

pan

y, u

p to

th

e am

oun

t of w

ith

hol

din

g ta

x. In

this

cas

e th

e u

ser

mu

st a

lso

spec

ify

the

limit

of t

he

offs

et b

y se

ttin

g th

e ‘L

imit

(%

of D

ivd

)’ p

aram

eter

wh

ich

is u

sual

ly e

qu

al to

the

wit

hh

old

ing

tax

rate

. If t

he

corp

orat

e ta

x p

aid

exc

eed

s th

is li

mit

, th

e fir

m c

an c

arry

the

exce

ss fo

rwar

d fo

r fu

ture

off

sets

. (Y

es, t

his

mod

ule

can

be

com

plic

ated

)

Ret

ain

ed E

arn

ings

. Som

e ta

x sy

stem

s al

low

for

a d

edu

ctio

n o

f ret

ain

ed e

arn

ings

if th

ey

are

com

pu

lsor

ily in

vest

ed in

a fu

nd

. Wit

hd

raw

als

are

then

ad

ded

bac

k to

taxa

ble

in

com

e. If

this

is th

e ca

se, ‘

Ded

uct

RE

’ is

set e

qu

al to

‘1’.

If r

etai

ned

ear

nin

gs a

re ta

xed

, th

e ta

x ra

te is

en

tere

d fo

r th

e ‘R

E T

ax/C

red

(+/

-)’ p

aram

eter

. Th

e m

odel

allo

ws

for

reta

ined

ear

nin

gs to

ear

n in

tere

st. T

he

inte

rest

rat

e is

en

tere

d fo

r th

e p

aram

eter

‘I

nte

rest

Rat

e on

RE

’. If

the

inte

rest

ear

ned

on

ret

ain

ed e

arn

ings

is ta

xed

an

d/o

r in

dex

ed, t

he

app

rop

riat

e va

lues

can

als

o b

e en

tere

d in

this

sec

tion

Th

is is

not

allo

wed

in th

e SA

tax

cod

e

RE

s ea

rn in

tere

st a

t 7.2

%. I

nte

rest

is ta

xed

, bu

t not

ind

exed

Imp

ort T

axes

. In

this

blo

ck th

e u

ser

can

sp

ecif

y th

e sh

are

of e

ach

ass

et th

at is

im

por

ted

, an

d th

e ap

plic

able

imp

ort d

uty

rat

e. If

imp

orte

d c

apit

al g

ood

s ar

e ex

emp

t fo

r a

nu

mb

er o

f yea

rs, t

he

‘Exe

mp

tion

Rat

e’ a

nd

‘Exe

mp

tion

Per

iod

’ can

be

spec

ifie

d

for

each

ass

et

Maj

orit

y (9

0%)

of b

uild

ing

mat

eria

ls a

re s

ourc

ed lo

cally

. Im

por

ted

m

ater

ials

hav

e a

du

ty o

f 0-3

0%. A

vera

ge o

f 15%

Fo

r M

&E

, per

cen

tage

imp

orte

d w

ill v

ary

by

sect

or. B

ench

mar

k 50

% to

st

art.

Rat

e u

sed

is 1

0% (a

vera

ge im

por

t tar

iff)

V

ehic

les.

Per

cen

tage

of v

ehic

les

imp

orte

d w

ill v

ary

by

sect

or.

Ben

chm

ark

50%

to s

tart

. Du

ty r

ange

s fr

om 0

to 3

6%. R

ate

use

d in

itia

lly

is th

us

18%

. Exc

ise

du

ty o

f 20%

, bri

ngs

tota

l to

38%

(V

AT

at 1

4% c

har

ged

on

all

imp

orts

, bu

t ign

ored

her

e as

mos

t b

usi

nes

ses

can

cla

im V

AT

bac

k as

an

inp

ut t

ax)

O

ther

Tax

es. T

he

use

r ca

n s

pec

ify

seve

ral o

ther

taxe

s th

at m

ay b

e p

art o

f th

e sy

stem

. Fo

r an

exc

ess

pro

fits

tax,

the

‘nor

mal

’ rat

e of

pro

fit c

an b

e sp

ecif

ied

as

a p

erce

nta

ge o

f as

sets

. In

the

case

of a

Wea

lth

Tax

, th

e u

ser

can

sp

ecif

y if

this

pay

men

t is

ded

uct

ible

fr

om th

e ta

xab

le in

com

e

Non

e

Tre

atm

ent o

f In

vest

ors.

Th

is s

ecti

on a

llow

s th

e u

ser

to a

nal

yse

the

com

bin

ed e

ffec

t of

the

Cor

por

ate

and

Per

son

al In

com

e T

ax (

PIT

). T

he

use

r ca

n s

pec

ify

the

tax

on

div

iden

ds

and

cap

ital

gai

ns

in th

e h

and

s of

the

inve

stor

. On

e ca

n a

lso

ind

icat

e w

het

her

the

cap

ital

gai

ns

base

is in

dex

ed, a

nd

wh

eth

er c

apit

al lo

sses

can

be

use

d to

of

fset

oth

er p

erso

nal

tax

liab

iliti

es

Set a

t hig

hes

t mar

gin

al P

IT r

ate:

40%

D

ivid

end

s ar

e fu

lly d

edu

ctib

le fo

r in

div

idu

als

and

mu

tual

fun

ds

Ind

ivid

ual

pay

s C

GT

at a

max

imu

m e

ffec

tive

rat

e of

10.

5% (

42%

on

an

el

igib

le 2

5% o

f CG

) C

G lo

sses

can

on

ly b

e u

sed

to o

ffse

t fu

ture

cap

ital

gai

ns

taxe

s –

not

ot

her

PIT

. (T

hu

s, s

et a

t 0)

Dep

reci

atio

n. H

ere

the

use

r sp

ecif

ies

the

rate

s of

Tax

Dep

reci

atio

n a

nd

Eco

nom

ic

Dep

reci

atio

n. T

he

valu

es fo

r th

e ec

onom

ic d

epre

ciat

ion

are

init

ially

set

at

stan

dar

dis

ed v

alu

es o

f 3.6

%, 1

2.25

% a

nd

30%

for

Bu

ildin

gs, M

ach

iner

y &

Eq

uip

men

t an

d V

ehic

les

resp

ecti

vely

. Th

e T

ax D

epre

ciat

ion

rat

es a

re e

nte

red

un

der

the

par

amet

er ‘D

epr

Rat

e’

Ben

chm

ark

econ

omic

dep

reci

atio

n r

ates

init

ially

set

at t

hos

e u

sed

by

the

Sou

th A

fric

an R

eser

ve B

ank:

M&

E (

8 ye

ars:

12.

5%),

Bu

ildin

gs (5

0 ye

ars:

2%

), a

nd

Veh

icle

s (8

yea

rs: 1

2.5%

). L

and

doe

s n

ot d

epre

ciat

e

Page 65: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

57P

aram

eter

SA

Ben

chm

ark

Dep

reci

atio

n (

con

t.). T

he

par

amet

er ‘D

epr

Met

h?’

is s

et to

‘0’ f

or s

trai

ght l

ine

and

‘1’

for

dec

linin

g b

alan

ce. T

he

‘Dep

r R

ate’

an

d ‘D

epr

Life

’ are

set

to a

pp

rop

riat

e va

lues

for

each

ass

et c

ateg

ory.

Wit

h d

eclin

ing

bal

ance

dep

reci

atio

n, s

et th

e ‘D

epr

Life

’ to

the

max

imu

m n

um

ber

i.e.

30

year

s. If

the

tax

syst

em a

llow

s fo

r a

swit

ch-o

ver

from

d

eclin

ing

bal

ance

to a

str

aigh

t lin

e d

epre

ciat

ion

aft

er a

cer

tain

nu

mb

er o

f yea

rs, ‘

Dep

r M

eth

’ is

set t

o ‘1

’ an

d th

e ap

pro

pri

ate

rate

is e

nte

red

for

‘Dep

r R

ate’

, ju

st a

s in

the

case

of

dec

linin

g ba

lan

ce m

eth

od. B

ut i

n th

is c

ase

the

‘Dep

r Li

fe’ i

s se

t to

the

fin

ite

dep

reci

able

life

inst

ead

of ‘

30’ a

nd

the

‘Sw

itch

over

’ par

amet

er is

set

equ

al to

‘1’.

Th

e m

odel

au

tom

atic

ally

cal

cula

tes

the

tim

e fo

r sw

itch

-ove

r to

str

aigh

t-lin

e d

epre

ciat

ion

, i.e

. wh

en it

bec

omes

ben

efic

ial t

o th

e fir

m

If th

e ta

x sy

stem

pro

vid

es fo

r an

init

ial a

llow

ance

in th

e fir

st y

ear

of th

e as

set’

s d

epre

ciab

le li

fe, t

he

rele

van

t per

cen

tage

s ar

e en

tere

d u

nd

er ‘I

nit

ial A

llow

’ par

amet

er.

If th

e in

itia

l allo

wan

ce is

a p

erm

anen

t fea

ture

of t

he

tax

syst

em, i

.e. i

f rep

lace

men

t in

vest

men

ts a

s w

ell a

s or

igin

al in

vest

men

ts a

re e

ligib

le fo

r th

e al

low

ance

, th

e ‘I

nit

ial

Yr’

an

d ‘F

inal

Yr’

are

set

to ‘0

’ an

d ‘3

0’. I

f th

is is

a te

mp

orar

y fe

atu

re, t

he

rele

van

t yea

rs

of p

roje

ct li

fe a

re e

nte

red

. Pro

vid

ing

an in

itia

l allo

wan

ce c

an a

lso

affe

ct h

ow th

e b

asis

is

det

erm

ined

to c

alcu

late

the

ann

ual

dep

reci

atio

n a

llow

ance

. If t

he

init

ial a

llow

ance

re

du

ces

the

basi

s fo

r ca

lcu

lati

ng

dep

reci

atio

n, s

et th

e ‘A

dj B

ase?

’ to

‘1’.

In th

is c

ase

the

init

ial a

llow

ance

ser

ves

as a

met

hod

for

acce

lera

ted

dep

reci

atio

n. I

f th

e b

asis

is n

ot

adju

sted

--

imp

lyin

g th

at th

e in

itia

l allo

wan

ce is

gra

nte

d in

ad

dit

ion

to fu

ll d

epre

ciat

ion

– s

et th

e ‘A

dj B

ase?

’ par

amet

er to

‘0’

Ben

chm

ark

dep

reci

atio

n r

ates

for

acco

un

tin

g p

urp

oses

init

ially

def

ined

b

y gu

idel

ines

in th

e SA

Tax

Cod

e M

&E

(6

year

s: 1

6.67

%)

Bu

ildin

gs (2

0 ye

ars

for

man

ufa

ctu

rin

g: 5

%)

Veh

icle

s (4

yea

rs: 2

5%)

Lan

d d

oes

not

dep

reci

ate

Th

e d

iffe

ren

ce b

etw

een

thes

e tw

o ra

tes

of d

epre

ciat

ion

cre

ates

an

au

tom

atic

tax

ince

nti

ve

Stra

igh

t-lin

e d

epre

ciat

ion

is u

sed

by

all S

A c

omp

anie

s

Th

is is

incl

ud

ed u

nd

er S

IP p

rogr

am a

nd

the

effe

ct is

mod

elle

d v

ia a

sp

ecif

ic ta

x in

cen

tive

Page 66: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

58

Annex 4: Bell Equipment Ltd.

Bell Equipment Ltd. was established in 1954 in Natal, South Africa. The company makes, distributes and supports a wide range of heavy-duty vehicles and equipment for the mining, construction and sugar cane and forestry sectors. Bell employs 2,176 people directly in two plants, one in Richards Bay (KwaZulu-Natal Province) and the other in Germany. The Richards Bay plant is one of the largest employers in the KwaZulu-Natal Province. The years 1997-9 were especially difficult for the company which suffered contagion, along with much of the South African economy, from the East Asian economic crisis. A joint venture with the John Deere Construction and Forestry Company in 1999 (which now holds 32% of the equity) helped re-capitalise the company, which has emerged successfully from that difficult period. Bell Equipment has a highly capital-intensive balance sheet. A majority of its physical components are sourced from Europe where Bell is not able to obtain good financing terms. Long manufacturing lead times mean that inventory stocks are high, and the net result is working capital at 83% of total assets in 2003. The return on net assets was around 20% over the period 1999-2003. In 2003, Bell Equipment had R1.3 billion of assets and generated sales of R2.78 billion, which resulted in a profit of R36m. after taxation. The company sells locally and internationally, with 52% of sales revenue coming from exports. It has benefited substantially from South African export incentives over the years, initially under the General Export Incentive Scheme (GEIS, now defunct) and currently under the MIDP. Since 1995, GEIS or MIDP ‘revenues’ have accounted for an average 40% of income before tax (see Table A1). Historically, the company has not made investment decisions based on whether or not it has access to incentive schemes. The most recent significant investment it made was in 2003, with the establishment of a new plant at Eisenach, 10 km inside former East Germany. This is geared to produce up to 650 units a year and will be the focal point from which Bell supplies its markets in the northern hemisphere, in Europe and North America (though the exact mix of production in each location will depend on the strength of the Rand). The strategic reasoning behind the decision to invest abroad rather than to expand production in South Africa was based upon global market positioning and exchange-rate risk, rather than on government incentives. Having a manufacturing facility near the European market frees up a considerable amount of working capital by avoiding the necessity of having to import major components from Europe to South Africa, fit these to production at the Richards Bay factory and then ship the completed products back to Europe. It also helps reduce transportation costs. Finally, the company acknowledges that the ‘branding’ opportunity of being able to use ‘made in Germany’ provides for greater price margins. The primary drivers of investment decisions for this firm are thus not tax incentives but currency values, currency volatility, proximity to markets and branding. But Bell Equipment argues strongly that its ability to continue to benefit from the MIDP is very important for its continued success in South Africa. Table A1 presents basic financial models for Bell Equipment with and without the export subsidies the company has received since 1999. These show that the company would still have generated positive net income without export incentives every year that it had incentives, although its growth would have been substantially slower, with an impact on exports and

Page 67: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

59

employment. The effect on cash flow is more substantial. Taking 1999 as a base year,38 average cash flow would have been 110% down without export incentives. The company faces fierce competition from Caterpillar and Volvo and is a price taker in the market. It has been unable to pass on to consumers the price effects of the Rand’s revaluation since early 2003 and would not be able to pass on price increases associated with the removal of export subsidies. It is difficult to assess whether the MIDP programme is changing the invest/not invest decisions for Bell. It would appear that the company would have survived without investment incentives, but would not have grown or invested as much as it has. The MIDP effectively helps to counter some of the more fundamental threats to the investment environment within South Africa – an open trade regime, distance from primary suppliers and major markets, and a volatile currency. Bell Equipment also makes the point that investment incentives are available to its competitors.

Table A1 Bell Equipment financial statements: with and without MIDP and GEIS Incentives

WITH SUBSIDIES

R '000 FY Dec 1999

FY Dec 2000

FY Dec 2001

FY Dec 2002

FY Dec 2003

Revenue 1,163,526 1,438,507 1,658,096 2,386,356 2,778,279

(From GEIS or MIDP) 29,465 35,900 23,912 41,236 30,267

COGS 840,670 1,032,289 1,228,425 1,768,707 2,173,237

Gross profit 322,856 406,218 429,671 617,649 605,042

SG&A 233,948 288,289 296,696 386,423 452,333

Operating profit before financing (EBIT)

88,908 117,929 135,204 231,226 152,709

Adjustments for depreciation

8,321 9,411 13,706 19,904 24,162

Increase in warranty provision

- 25,407 -2,099 15,486 38,736

Loss on disposal of PP&E -2,717 96 -425 -320 54

Forex exchange differences for subsidiaries

3,250 20,114 74,840 -54,888 -28,424

Operating profit before working capital changes

97,762 172,957 221,226 211,408 187,237

Change in inventory 26,620 -180,272 -122,200 -208,156 -11,797

Change in receivables -46,317 -71,971 -90,783 43,773 55,643

Change in trade and other receivables

16,138 87,383 90,773 133,466 -139,202

Total cash generated from operations

94,203 8,097 99,016 180,491 91,881

Net finance costs paid -32,477 -14,079 -3,530 -57,718 -80,492

Taxation paid -1,358 -4,955 -41,268 -64,402 -62,599

Net cash flow from operating 60,368 -10,937 54,218 58,371 -51,210

Net cash flow from investing -46,724 -28,091 -58,015 -45,155 -40,975

Free cash flow 13,644 -39,028 -3,797 13,216 -92,185

38 This is a suitable base year because Bell Equipment was recapitalised this year following the take-up of a sizeable minority equity stake by John Deere & Co.

Page 68: An Assessment of South Africa’s Investment Incentive ... · The paper concludes with some recommendations for the reform of South Africa’s investment incentive regime. First,

60

WITHOUT SUBSIDIES

R '000 FY Dec 1999

FY Dec 2000

FY Dec 2001

FY Dec 2002

FY Dec 2003

Revenue 1,163,526 1,438,507 1,658,096 2,386,356 2,778,279

(From GEIS or MIDP) 29,465 35,900 23,912 41,236 30,267

COGS 840,670 1,032,289 1,228,425 1,768,707 2,173,237

Gross profit 322,856 406,218 429,671 617,649 605,042

SG&A 233,948 288,289 296,696 386,423 452,333

Operating profit before financing (EBIT)

59,443 82,029 111,292 189,990 122,442

Adjustments for depreciation

8,321 9,411 13,706 19,904 24,162

Increase in warranty provision

- 25,407 -2,099 15,486 38,736

Loss on disposal of PP&E -2,717 96 -425 -320 54

Forex exchange differences for subsidiaries

3,250 20,114 74,840 -54,888 -28,424

Operating profit before working capital changes

68,297 137,057 197,314 170,172 156,970

Change in inventory 26,620 -180,272 -122,200 -208,156 -11,797

Change in receivables -46,317 -71,971 -90,783 43,773 55,643

Change in trade and other receivables

16,138 87,383 90,773 133,466 -139,202

Total cash generated from operations

64,738 -27,803 75,104 139,255 61,614

Net finance costs paid -32,477 -14,079 -3,530 -57,718 -80,492

Taxation paid -1,358 -4,955 -41,268 -64,402 -62,599

Net cash flow from operating 30,903 -46,837 30,306 17,135 -81,477

Net cash flow from investing -46,724 -28,091 -58,015 -45,155 -40,975

Free cash flow -15,821 -74,928 -27,709 -28,020 -122,452

Source: Bell Equipment <www.bell.co.za>; information provide by Bell Manufacturing; interviews with Bell Equipment staff.