71
Advanced International Finance Part 1 Nicolas Coeurdacier - [email protected] PhD - Spring 2011

Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    1

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Advanced International Finance

Part 1

Nicolas Coeurdacier - [email protected]

PhD - Spring 2011

Page 2: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Practical Information

• email : [email protected]

• Course website: Link PhD course at

http://econ.sciences-po.fr/nicolas-coeurdacier/nicolas-coeurdacier

• References: reading list for articles. Obstfeld and Rogoff "Foundations

of International Macroeconomics".

• Assignment: Mid-term take home exam (handed out at lecture 3 due to

lecture 5); Students presentations; End-of-term exam.

Page 3: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Road-map for the course

Three main topics

• International Real Business Cycles and the Transmission of Shocks

• International Portfolios and Risk-Sharing

• Global Imbalances and the Valuation Channel of External Adjustment

Page 4: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Part 1- International Real business Cycles and the Transmission of Shocks

- A simple two-country/two-good/two period endowment economy

Complete markets and Financial Autarky

International transmission of output shocks / Backus-Smith Puzzle

- Two country/two good RBC model with complete markets

Backus, Kehoe, Kydland, AER 1994;

Page 5: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Quick reminder about the one good IRBC model

Facts and anomalies:

- ’The quantity Puzzle’: in the data, cross-country correlation of output is

larger than cross-country correlation of consumption.

Most models predict the opposite: with complete markets (perfect risk-sharing),

consumption is perfectly correlated across countries (if utility separable between

consumption and leisure), output is not = ’Quantity Puzzle’.

Very difficult to solve. Market incompleteness helps if strong wealth effects (for

instance, very persistent technology shocks; see Kollmann (1996), Baxter and

Crucini (1995)).

Page 6: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

’The quantity puzzle’

Page 7: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Quick reminder about the one good IRBC model

Facts and anomalies:

- Very high cross-country correlation of investment in the data but not in the

models where capital moves to the most productive location.

- Similarly, high cross country correlation of employment in the data but not in

the model.

- Countercyclical trade balance in the data: key role for investment. Intuition?

Page 8: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Relaxing the assumption of a single perfectly tradable good?

One good model has nothing to say about real exchange rate and relative prices.

Main price in international macro!

What do we expect in terms of risk sharing implications from a two-good model?

Real exchange rate will introduce a wedge between marginal utilities of con-

sumption in the risk sharing condition - hence, one may expect that this model

predicts lower cross-country consumption correlation

International transmission through relative prices might reduce the negative

correlation of investment/hours/output across countries

Page 9: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Risk-sharing in a two country/two good endowment economy with com-

plete markets

- Two countries Home (H) and Foreign (F ) perfectly symmetric ex-ante.

- Two periods t = 0; 1.

Output in i at t = 0 is y0,i. Uncertainty in period t = 1. Finite number of

states s (proba π(s)). Output y1,i(s).

- Each country produces one differentiated good.

- Complete markets implemented with AD securities: AD security s pays 1

in state s at t = 1; price at t = 0 is pb(s)

I abstract from time indices for simplicity.

Page 10: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Aggregate consumption index

CH =[a1/φ (cHH)(φ−1)/φ + (1− a)1/φ (cHF )

(φ−1)/φ]φ/(φ−1)

CF =[a1/φ (cFF )

(φ−1)/φ + (1− a)1/φ (cFH)(φ−1)/φ]φ/(φ−1)

with φ elasticity of substitution between the two goods, and cij = consumptionof good j by country i, i = H,F

Home bias in preferences a ≥ 12. With a = 1

2, identical preferences ⇒ ahomogenous to goods market integration. With “Cobb-Douglas” preferences,(φ = 1), a = share of consumption spending devoted to local good

Price indices

PH =[a (pH)1−φ + (1− a) (pF )

1−φ]1/(1−φ)

PF =[(1− a) (pH)1−φ + a (pF )

1−φ]1/(1−φ)

Page 11: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Terms of trade: q = relative price of Home goods over Foreign goods

q ≡pHpF

Real Exchange Rate

RER =PHPF

=

(aq1−φ + (1− a)

(1− a)q1−φ + a

)1/(1−φ)

Intertemporal Utility

Ui = u(C0,i) + βE0u(C1,i) = C0,i + β∑

sπ(s)u(C1,i(s))

Ct,i=aggegate consumption at date t in country i et β=discount factor; u(c) =c1−σ

1−σ with σ = CRRA coefficient. Finite number of states s

Page 12: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Budget constraints:

P0,iC0,i = p0,iy0,i −∑

spb(s)bi(s) λi0

P1,iC1,i(s) = p1,iy1,i(s) + bi(s) βλi1(s)

Ressource constraints (at both dates and in all states at t=1)

cHH + cFH = yH ; cFF + cHF = yF

with yi endowment of country i

Asset market clearing condition∑

i

bi(s) = 0

Page 13: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Euler equation for Arrow-Debreu Securities

u′(C0,i) = λi0P0,i π(s)u′(C1,i(s)) = λ

i1(s)P1,i

⇒ pb(s)u′(C0,i)P0,i

= βπ(s)u′(C1,i(s))

P1,i⇒ pb(s) = βπ(s)

u′(C1,i)/P1,i

u′(C0,i)/P0,i

This is again true for both countries (abstracting from indices s); this leads

to the fundamental risk-sharing condition in presence of real exchange rate

fluctuations

u′(C1,H)/P1,H

u′(C0,H)/P0,H=u′(C1,F )/P1,F

u′(C0,F )/P0,F⇒

(C1,H

C0,H

)−σ

=P1,H/P1,F

P0,H/P0,F

(C1,F

C0,F

)−σ

Consumption growth rates are no more equal across countries. But changes in

consumption are linked to changes in the real exchange rate.

Page 14: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

The wedge introduced by the real exchange rate might potentially help address-ing the problem of (too) high cross-country consumption correlations (’QuantityPuzzle’)

Is it good news? Not really: this is the consumption-real exchange rate anomaly(see Kollmann (1995) and Backus and Smith (1993))

Note that this equation shows up in any complete markets model with realexchange rate fluctuations, CRRA preferences & separability between leisureand consumption.

Remark 1: If countries are symmetric ex-ante (q0 = 1):(C1,H

C1,F

)−σ

=P1,H

P1,F= RER

Remark 2: extension to a multi-period model?

Page 15: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

"The consumption-real exchange rate anomaly"

Note: in the table real exchange rate is 1/RERt compared to our definition. Source: Corsetti et al.

Page 16: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Intratemporal allocation across goods (abstracting from time/state indices)

cii = a

(piPi

)−φ

Ci cij = (1− a)

(pj

Pi

)−φ

Ci

Demand of Home over Foreign goods (with market clearing conditions)

q−φΩa

[(PFPH

)φCF

CH

]=yHyF

Ωu(x) is a continuous function of (u, x) with Ωu(x) =1+x(1−u

u)

x+(1−uu

)

Remark: if a = 1/2, then Ω1/2(x) = 1 for all x and yHyF

= q−φ. Terms oftrade decreases with an elasticity 1/φ with respect to increase in output atHome relative to Foreign.

Page 17: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Log-linearization of the model

To have analytical expression and shed light on the transmission mechanism

of endowment (productivity) shocks, we log linearize the model around the

symmetric equilibrium (assuming that ex-ante at t=0 countries are symmetric;

assuming small shocks).

We write y ≡ yHyF

to denote relative outputs in both countries.

We log-linearize the model around the symmetric equilibrium where y equal

unity, and use Jonesian hats (x ≡ log(x/x)) to denote the log deviation of a

variable x from its mean value x.in a given state

Page 18: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

The international transmission mechanism

Terms-of-trade and relative output

Asssume symmetric countries:(CH

CF

)−σ

=PHPF

⇒yHyF

= q−φΩa

[(PFPH

)φ−1/σ

](1)

Home country’s real exchange rate RER ≡ PHPF

:

RER =PHPF

= (2a− 1)q. (2)

Page 19: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Log-linearizing (1) and using (2) implies:

y = −φq + (2a− 1)(φ−

1

σ

)RER = −λq

where λ ≡ φ(1− (2a− 1)2

)+

(2a−1)2

σ . Note that λ > 0 as 1/2 < a < 1.

A relative increase in the supply of the home good (y > 0) is always associatedwith a worsening of the terms of trade (q < 0) with an elasticity −1/λ. Note

that without home bias in preferences (a = 12), λ is simply the elasticity of

substitution between Home and Foreign goods φ

=⇒ With complete markets, the international transmission of supply (produc-

tivity) shocks is always positive : a positive supply shock at Home unambigu-

ously worsens Home terms-of-trade.

Page 20: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

The international transmission mechanism

Relative consumption and relative output

CH − CF = −1

σ

PHPF

= −(2a− 1)

σq ⇒ CH − CF =

(2a− 1)

σλy

With Home Bias, the coefficient above is always positive. In response to a

Home supply shock, consumption grows more at Home than abroad. Even if

the Home terms of trade fall, it will never be the case that their adverse move-

ments cause ‘immiserizing growth’. In response to a positive supply shocks,

domestic consumption will never fall either in absolute level, or relative to For-

eign Consumption. The consumption growth difference tends to fall with the

elasticity of substitution among goods (φ) (as φ increases, we approach the

one good model).

Page 21: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Net exports and relative output

Log-linearization of Net Exports as a share of GDP (NXH). Use foreign good

as a numeraire: pF = 1 ;q = pH

NXH = pHyH − PHCH = −NXF ; NXF = pFyF − PFCF

NXH =1

2

[qy −

(PHCH − PFCF

)]=q

2

[(1− λ)− (2a− 1)(1−

1

σ)]

NXH = q(1− a)[1− φ+ (2a− 1) (

1

σ− φ)

]

NXH =y

λ(1− a)

[φ− 1 + (2a− 1) (φ−

1

σ)]

Net exports are procyclical unless the elasticity of substitution (φ) between

Home and Foreign goods is very low. What does it mean? Is it realistic?

[recall that we do not have investment]

Page 22: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Terms-of-trade volatility and Net exports volatility

- When goods are highly substitutable (high φ), the elasticity of prices to

quantities is small - small price changes and large quantity changes

- When goods are poor substitutes (low φ), the elasticity of prices to quantities

is large - large price changes for small quantity changes

This price-quantity relationship turns out to be a problem... in the data, terms-

of-trade are very volatile around 2 times more volatile than output (low φ?)...but

so are quantities traded (at least more than what is predicted by simple two

goods model for low values of φ)

- Relative price adjustment tells us that Home terms-of-trade should depreciate

following an increase in productivity at Home (due to the relative scarcity of

Foreign goods). Data?

Page 23: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Terms-of-trade volatility and Net exports volatility

Volatility of Net Exports and terms of trade (% of volatility of output)

0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

1.2

1.4

1.6

1.8

0.8

1 1.2

1.4

1.6

1.8

2 2.2

2.4

2.6

2.8

3 3.2

3.4

3.6

3.8

4 4.2

4.4

4.6

4.8

5 5.2

0

0.05

0.1

0.15

0.2

0.25

0.3

0.35

0.4

0.45

Volatility of Terms of Trade (left-axis) Volatility of Net exports (right-axis)

Page 24: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics
Page 25: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

A benchmark two-country/two good IRBC model with production

Reference: Backus, Kehoe and Kydland, American Economic Review, 1994[slightly modified version]

What do we expect compared to the one good BKK model?

Real exchange rate introduces wedge between marginal utilities of consumptionin the risk sharing condition - hence, one may expect that this model predictslower cross-country consumption correlation

International transmission through relative prices might reduce the negativecorrelation of investment/hours/output across countries.

Page 26: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

A benchmark two-country/two good IRBC model with production

Two symmetric countries, Home (H) and Foreign (F ), each with a represen-tative household.

Each country i produces one good using labor and capital.

Markets are complete.

There is trade in goods and in Arrow-Debreu securities

All markets are perfectly competitive

Page 27: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Preferences

Country i is inhabited by a representative household who lives in periods

t = 0, 1, 2, .... The household has the following life-time utility function:

Ui = E0

∞∑

t=0

βtu(Cit, lit) =∞∑

t=0

stπ(st)βtu(Cit, lit)

where Ci,t is i’s aggregate consumption and lit is labor supplied by the repre-

sentative household in country i

Page 28: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Consumption and price index

CH,t =[a1/φ

(cHH,t

)(φ−1)/φ+ (1− a)1/φ

(cHF,t

)(φ−1)/φ]φ/(φ−1)

CF,t =[a1/φ

(cFF,t

)(φ−1)/φ+ (1− a)1/φ

(cFH,t

)(φ−1)/φ]φ/(φ−1)

where cij,t is country i′s consumption of the good produced by j; 12 < a < 1.

PH,t =[a(pH,t

)1−φ+ (1− a)

(pF,t

)1−φ]1/(1−φ)

PF,t =[(1− a)

(pH,t

)1−φ+ a

(pF,t

)1−φ]1/(1−φ)

where pH,t and pF,t are the prices of goods H and F , respectively.

Page 29: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Technologies

In period t, country i produces yi,t units of good i according to the production

function

yi,t = zi,t(li,t)1−θ(ki,t)

θ

with 0 < θ < 1. li,t is the labor supply in country i at date t. ki,t is the

country’s stock of capital. Total factor productivity zi,t > 0 is an exogenous

random variable.

Capital is derived from physical investment in previous periods:

ki,t+1 = (1− δ)ki,t + Ii,t

where 0 < δ < 1 is the depreciation rate of capital. Ii,t is gross investment in

country i at date t.

Page 30: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Aggregate Investment

In both countries, investment goods are generated using Home and Foreign

inputs:

IH,t =[a1/φ

(iHH,t

)(φ−1)/φ+ (1− a)1/φ

(iHF,t

)(φ−1)/φI]φ/(φ−1)

IF,t =[a1/φ

(iFF,t

)(φ−1)/φ+ (1− a)1/φ

(iFH,t

)(φ−1)/φ]φ/(φ−1)

where iij,t is the quantity of the good produced by country j used for investment

in country i. The associated (ideal) price indices of investment goods are the

same than for consumption

P IH,t = PH,t ; P I

F,t = PF,t

Page 31: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Household decisions

E0

∞∑

t=0

βtu(Cit, lit) =∞∑

t=0

stπ(st)βtu(Cit, lit)

The country i household maximizes life-time utility (selects Cit and lit, and

buy Arrow-Debreu securities) subject to the following BC for t ≥ 0 :

Pi,t(Ci,t + Iit) +∑

st+1

Q(st, st+1)BH(st, st+1)

= wi,tli,t + ri,tki,t +BH(st−1, st)

where wi,t = wage in country i, ri,t = return to capital in country i and

Q(st, st+1) = price of the Arrow-Debreu securities in state st (at date t) that

pays one unit of the numeraire in state st+1

Page 32: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Household decisions

Intra-temporal allocation across goods:

cHH,t = a

(pH,t

PH,t

)−φ

CH,t, cHF,t = (1− a)

(pF,t

PH,t

)−φ

CH,t

Aggregate consumption (with λH,t =Lagrange-multiplier of BC):

uc(Cit, lit) = λH,tPit

Labor supply decision:

−ul(Cit, lit)

uc(Cit, lit)= (wH,t

PH,t)

Page 33: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Household decisions

Euler equations for Arrow-Debreu securities:

λH,tQ(st, st+1) = βπ(s

t)λH,t+1

⇒uc(Cit, lit)

PitQ(st, st+1) = βπ(s

t)uc(Cit+1, lit+1)

Pit+1

Symmetric expressions hold for the country F household

Page 34: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Risk-sharing condition

Last equation for countryH and F gives the fundamental risk sharing condition

(assuming that countries are ex-ante symmetric : λH,0 = λF,0)

λH,t = λF,t for all t⇒uc(CHt, lHt)

uc(CFt, lFt)=PH,t

PF,t= RERt

Remark: With separable utility:(CH,t

CF,t

)−σ

=PH,t

PF,t= RERt

Page 35: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Market clearing conditions

Market-clearing in goods market:

cHH,t + cFH,t + i

HH,t + i

FH,t = yH,t , cFF,t + c

HF,t + i

FF,t + i

HF,t = yF,t ,

Asset market-clearing condition

BH(st, st+1) +BF (st, st+1) = 0

Page 36: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Firms’ decisions

Firms maximize profits, taking goods and factor prices as given. Due to the

Cobb-Douglas technology, a share (1− θ) of output is paid to workers.

Thus, labor income in country i is given by:

wi,tli,t = (1− θ)pi,tyi,t,

where pi,t is the price of the country i good and wi,t is the wage in country i.

A share θ of country i output is paid a capital

ri,tki,t = θpi,tyi,t

Page 37: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Firms’ decisions

Investment decisions have two dimensions: firms choose aggregate invest-

ment spending Pi,tIi,t, and they decide how to allocate that spending over

Home and Foreign inputs.

For country H firms, the allocation over the two inputs must satisfy the fol-

lowing first-order conditions:

iHH,t

IH,t= a

(pH,t

PH,t

)−φ

iHF,t

IH,t= (1− a)

(pF,t

PH,t

)−φ

The symmetric applies to the Foreign country

Page 38: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Investment decisions (intertemporal)

Investment spending at date t must equalize the expected future marginal gain

of investment to the marginal cost at date t. So at time time t, the first-order

condition for investment in country i is:

Pi,t = Etit,t+1[pi,t+1θzi,t+1(li,t+1)

1−θ(ki,t+1)θ−1 + (1− δ)Pi,t+1] (3)

where it,t+1 is a pricing kernel (SDF) used by the firm at date t to value date

t + 1 payoffs (that are expressed in units of the country i final consumption

good) [note that the pricing kernel is the same in both countries due to perfect

risk-sharing; using Home and Foreign pricing kernel does not affect investment

decisions.

Future TFP zi,t+1 induces higher investment, while a higher price of investment

goods Pi,t discourages investment.

Page 39: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Backus, Kehoe and Kydland, American Economic Review, 1994

Calibration (based on quarterly data, as in BKK 1992):

Two symmetric countries (Europe and US)

Instantaneous utility: u(Cit, lit) =(Cµ

it(1−lit)1−µ)

1−σ

1−σ

c/y = 0.75; β = 0.99; δ = 0.025; θ = 0.36; σ = 2; µ = 0.34

New parameters compared BKK 1992: Import share: 15% - this matches US

but not Europe. This calibrates the home bias in preferences a = 0.85.

Elasticity of substitution between Home and Foreign goods = φ = 1.5

Page 40: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Backus, Kehoe and Kydland, American Economic Review, 1994

Calibration (based on quarterly data, as in BKK 1992):

Productivity shocks:

(ln(zHt+1)ln(zFt+1)

)=

(0.906 0.0880.088 0.906

)(ln(zHt)ln(zFt)

)+

(εHtεFt

)

Correl (εHt; εFt) = 0.25; var(εHt) = 0.008522

No adjustment costs.

Page 41: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Note: Terms-of-trade are defined as p = pF/pH

Page 42: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Main findings...

Following a postive Home productivity shock, Home terms-of-trade depreciate.

The depreciation of the real exchange rate coincides with a deficit of the balance

trade as the domestic investment increases. [if adjustment costs not too large

and productivity shocks sufficiently persistent]. Investment is still key for a

countercyclical trade balance unless φ is very small (roughly smaller than 1).

Implies a positive (contemporaneous) correlation between Home terms-of-trade

and (Home) net exports as in the data. After the shock, both terms-of-trade

and net exports improve (the J-curve?)

Page 43: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Main findings...

Compared to the one good model, because domestic and foreign goods are im-perfect substitutes, less tendency for strong negative cross-country correlationof investment (see (3)). International transmission through relative prices alsoreduces the volatility of investment within a country. These are good newscompared to the one good model.

Some international transmission through international trade - Home productiv-ity shock increases both Home and Foreign output (as Foreign TOT improves).Goes in the right direction for the "Quantity Puzzle" but effects are moderate.Risk sharing still implies strong cross-country consumption correlation (higherthan the correlation of output).

Of course, the new mechanisms rely on elasticities of substitution that are nottoo high.

Page 44: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

New anomalies...

- ’Consumption Real Exchange Rate Anomaly’

- Terms-of-trade and real exchange rate are not volatile enough. In particular,TOT are 6 times more volatile in the data than in the benchmark calibration(unless φ is very low; but in that case quantities traded and net exports are notvolatile enough).

- International transmission relies on countercyclical terms-of-trade: weak evi-dence in the data. But need to condition for productivity shocks

Corsetti, Dedola, Leduc (2007) argues that for the US, US productivityshocks appreciates the US terms-of-trade. See also Kollmann (2007)

Acemoglu and Ventura (2002) provide evidence that higher productivitydepreciates the terms-of-trade in the long term

Page 45: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Robustness checks

Large spill-overs - higher direct transmission through shocks

Low elasticity of substitution between domestic and foreign goods: should make

trade link more important

High elasticity of substitution between domestic and foreign goods: should

make trade link less important

Government spending shocks: should lead to stronger output comovements

Page 46: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics
Page 47: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics
Page 48: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics
Page 49: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

The role of incomplete markets. Does it help?

In two good model, still cross-country correlation of consumption to high and’consumption real exchange rate anomaly’.

Incomplete markets help in some dimensions but overall does not makes a bigdifference in many models....

Unless:

- Highly persistent shocks that generate strong wealth effects (Kollmann (1996),Baxter and Crucini (1995, IER) in one-good models, Corsetti, Dedola, Leduc(2007) in a two good model).

- Assumptions quite extreme about the frictions on financial markets but even inthat case terms-of-trade adjustment is a substitute for risk-sharing on financialmarkets (Cole and Obstfeld (1991)).

Page 50: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Corsetti, Dedola, Leduc (2007) [CDL]

Starting point = the consumption-real exchange rate anomaly ("Backus-Smith

puzzle")

Complete markets models predict (assuming symmetric countries):

uHc,t =PH,t

PF,tuFc,t

with CRRA:

(CH,t

CF,t

)−σ

=PH,t

PF,t= RERt

This is at odds with the data. For the US, CDL argues that changes in con-

sumption (relative to ROW) are positively related with a US real exchange rate

appreciation.

Page 51: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Key idea

Incomplete markets set-up (either bond economy as above or financial autarky)

that implies large enough wealth effect to inverse the standard international

transmission mechanism.

Wealth effects can generate an appreciation of the TOT following a Home

productivity shock. Will generate increase in Home consumption together with

an appreciation of the Home RER.

Page 52: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

How does it work?

Suppose high productivity shock at Home. If output increases faster than

demand for Home goods (holding prices constant), then the Home terms-of-

trade will depreciate as in standard complete markets model. But suppose

that wealth effects are strong: higher Home productivity at Home increases a

lot the wealth of Home households; Aggregate Home consumption (demand)

will increase much faster than Foreign consumption. As Home consumption is

biased towards local goods, this increase more the demand for Home goods.

If this increase in demand is large enough compared to the increase in Home

output (the reason why wealth effects must be very large), excess demand for

Home goods and the Home TOT will appreciate (despite larger supply of Home

goods). This in turn reinforces the wealth effect.

Page 53: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

When is such a mechanism possible?

Two cases:

1) either low elasticity of substitution between Home and Foreign tradable

goods. In this case, following a productivity increase, the Home terms of

trade and the RER appreciate, hurting foreign consumers. With a low price

elasticity, a terms-of-trade depreciation that reduces domestic wealth relative

to the rest of the world would actually result in a drop of the world demand for

domestic goods (because of Home bias in consumption domestic tradables are

mainly demanded by domestic households). For the world markets to clear, a

larger supply of domestic tradables must be matched by an appreciation of the

country’s terms of trade, driving up domestic wealth and demand.

Page 54: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

2) high elasticity but highly persistent shocks (almost unit root) such that apositive Home productivity shock raises faster in the short-run demand for Homegoods (than supply) which results also in an appreciation of the Home terms-of-trade. Equivalently, because shocks are highly persistent, higher output todaymeans even more output later on (due to K accumulation). Home consumerswants to smooth this increase in consumption over time and raise consumptionnow. If this effect is sufficently large, in the SR demand for Home goods (drivenby investment and Home consumption) increase faster than Home output. TOTappreciates on impact (and depreciates in the the LR).

Note that in the middle range of elasticities of substitution, we are too closefrom the Cole and Obstfeld case: terms-of-trade act as a substitute for risk-sharing and market incompleteness does not imply wealth effects large enough.

For simplicity I will consider only the first case in a simple endowment economyunder financial autarky (see CDL, part 3.1).

Page 55: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

A two country/two good endowment economy under financial autarky

- Same simple set-up with two periods as earlier

- Two countries Home (H) and Foreign (F ).

- Countries perfectly symmetric ex-ante

- But relax complete markets and assume financial autarky

I abstract from time indices for simplicity

Page 56: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Intratemporal allocation across goods (abstracting from time/state indices)

cii = a

(piPi

)−φ

Ci cij = (1− a)

(pj

Pi

)−φ

Ci

Demand of Home over Foreign goods (with market clearing conditions)

q−φΩa

[(PFPH

)φ−1PFCF

PHCH

]=yHyF

Ωu(x) is a continuous function of (u, x) with Ωu(x) =1+x(1−u

u)

x+(1−uu

)

We log-linearize the model around the symmetric equilibrium where y equalunity, and use Jonesian hats (x ≡ log(x/x)) to denote the log deviation of avariable x from its mean value x.

Page 57: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

The international transmission mechanism (financial autarky)

Terms-of-trade and relative output

Home country’s real exchange rate RER ≡ PHPF

: RER = PHPF

= (2a− 1)q.

Assume symmetric countries, relative demand of Home over Foreign goods

becomes:

yHyF

= q−φΩa

[(PFPH

)φ−1PFCF

PHCH

]

⇒ y = −φq + (2a− 1) (φ− 1)RER+ (2a− 1) PC

⇒ y = −[φ(1− (2a− 1)2 + (2a− 1)2

]q + (2a− 1) PC

where PC = PHCH − PFCF denotes relative consumption expenditures.

Page 58: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Terms-of-trade and relative output

Under financial autarky, consumption expenditures = incomes: PiCi = piyi ⇒

PC = q + y

y = −[φ(1− (2a− 1)2) + (2a− 1)2

]q

︸ ︷︷ ︸substitution effect

+ (2a− 1) PC︸ ︷︷ ︸income effect

(1− (2a− 1))y = −(1− (2a− 1))[φ(1 + (2a− 1))− (2a− 1)]q

y = − [2aφ− (2a− 1)] q ⇒ q = −y

1− 2a(1− φ)

=⇒ With φ high enough (think close to unity), the international transmission

of supply (productivity) shocks is positive : a positive supply shock at Home

worsens the Home terms-of-trade and transfers income to the other country.

Terms-of-trade fluctuations provide risk-sharing.

Page 59: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Cole and Obstfeld (1991): an equivalence result

PC = PHCH − PFCF = q + y =2a(φ− 1)

1− 2a(1− φ)y

⇒ CH − CF =2aφ− 1

1− 2a(1− φ)y

Remind that under complete markets, we had:

(CH − CF

)CM=

(2a− 1)

σλy =

(2a− 1)

σφ(1− (2a− 1)2

)+ (2a− 1)2

y

Note that allocations coincide when a = 1/2 (no consumption Home bias) and

φ = 1 (also true for φ = σ = 1 and any a)

Page 60: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Cole and Obstfeld (1991): an equivalence result

=⇒ Hence despite financial autarky, the allocation is efficient (identical to the

complete markets one). At the heart of Cole and Obstfeld (1991): terms-of-

trade provide automatic insurance to supply shocks. Financial markets do not

matter

An important negative result (Cole and Obstfeld (1991)): in a two-country/two-

good model, terms-of-trade movements act as substitute for risk-sharing: the

adjustment of relative prices transmit shock from one country to the other:

countries with lower productivity enjoy higher value of output (improved terms-

of-trade). Dampens the wealth effect associated to productivity shocks (damp-

ens the mechanism through which market incompleteness matters)

Page 61: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Does incomplete markets matter in a two good model?

If the asset structure matters, we have to move away from the Cole and Ob-

stfeld world with terms-of-trade adjustment that exactly offsets the impact of

productivity shocks.

1) Either terms-of-trade effects are small (because goods are close substitutes)

and in that case, we are close to the one good model. Can reconcile the

"quantity puzzle" with highly persistent shocks

2) Or terms-of-trade movement are destabilizing = negative transmission

of productivity shocks: Home terms-of-trade appreciate following a positive

Home productivity shock. This might happen with a combination of the fol-

lowing ingredients: incomplete financial markets and sufficiently low elasticity

of substitution between Home and Foreign goods

Page 62: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Terms-of-trade and relative output

Under financial autarky, as shown earlier:

q = −y

1− 2a(1− φ)

=⇒ With incomplete markets (here financial autarky), the international trans-

mission of supply (productivity) shocks can be negative : a positive supply

shock at Home can appreciate Home terms-of-trade. This happens for a suffi-

ciently low elasticity of substitution: φ < 1− 1/2a. Intuition?

Page 63: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Terms-of-trade and relative output

With φ < 1 − 1/2a, holding expenditures constant(PC

), relative demand

responds very little to fall in the relative price of Home goods as it is hard

to substitute Home for Foreign goods. Income effects dominate in driving the

relative price: following a positive Home productivity shock, Home consumers

have higher income that is spent mostly on Home goods; this increases the

demand for these goods, increasing their price. TOT appreciates. In other

words, the relative demand for Home goods is upward-sloping with respect to

the relative price: as the income effect dominates, for a positive supply shock

at Home to be matched by an increase in world demand, the Home terms of

trade needs to appreciate.

Page 64: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Terms-of-trade and relative output

For φ > 1− 1/2a, terms-of-trade depreciate following a positive productivity

shock: as shown below, if φ < 1/2a, the fall in Home terms-of-trade is so large

that a positive Home productivity shock benefit more to Foreign consumers.

When φ > 1/2a, qualitatively similar responses as in the complete market case

(but might be different with K accumulation).

Page 65: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Relative consumption and RER

PC = PHCH − PFCF = q + y = 2a(1− φ)q =2a(1− φ)

2a− 1RER

⇒ CH − CF =1− 2aφ

2a− 1RER

Remind that under complete markets:

(CH − CF

)CM= −

1

σRER

Under financial autarky, if φ < 1/2a, Home real exchange rate and Home

relative consumption moves in the same direction = solution to the consumption

real exchange rate anomaly

Page 66: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Contrary to CM, with Home Bias, the response of relative consumption to

relative output is not always positive. In response to a positive Home supply

shock, consumption can grow less at Home than abroad: this happens when

1− 1/2a < φ < 1/2a. In that case, the adverse movement of Home terms of

trade cause ‘immiserizing growth’.

Brief summary: 3 cases

High elasticity case:

*φ > 1/2a: a positive Home output shock depreciates the Home terms of

trade, to the benefit of Foreign consumers (positive transmission). Relative

consumption and the real exchange rate are positively correlated. Both this

correlation, and international price movements, have the same sign as under

complete markets. This is the conventional view of transmission.

Page 67: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Low elasticity cases:

* φ < 1− 1/2a: the international transmission is negative. A positive Home

output shocks appreciates the Home terms of trade, and the real exchange rate.

Home consumption rises relative to Foreign consumption. Relative consumption

- RER correlation has the opposite sign with respect to the case of complete

markets.

*1−1/2a < φ < 1/2a: transmission is positive: actually, the fall in the Home

terms of trade is so large, that Foreign consumers benefit from a Home supply

shocks more than domestic consumers. Foreign consumption rises relative to

domestic consumption, as the Home real exchange rate depreciates.

Page 68: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Discussion of the quantitative model and key implications

CDL then set-up a dynamic model with incomplete markets (bond economy)

that incorporates the features presented above.

They use distribution services to generate a low trade elasticity. Needs η units of

non-tradable goods (distribution sector) to sell output. Drives a wedge between

producer and consumer prices (but still needs a low preference parameter φ to

generate appreciation of terms-of-trade following a productivity shock).

If pH = producer price of tradables, then consumer price of tradables from

country i = pi = pi+ηpN where pN =price of one unit of distrbution service

(non-tradable)

Page 69: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

Then, intratemporal allocation across goods in country H:

cHH = a

(pHPH

)−φ

Ci cHF = (1− a)

(pFPH

)−φ

CH

(cHH

cHF

)=

(a

1− a

)(pHpF

)−φ

=(a

1− a

)(pH + ηpNpF + ηpN

)−φ

Then denoting µ = ηpNpH

, the distribution margin in setady-stade, the log-

linearization of the previous equation gives:

cHH − cHF = −φ(1− µ)(pH − pF

)= −φ(1− µ) TOT

with φ ≈ 0.8 and µ ≈ 0.5, then φ(1 − µ) ≈ 0.4. Equivalent ot a low

pass-through of exchange rates fluctuations.

Page 70: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

According to CDL, a low trade elasticity:

1) helps to solve the "consumption-real exchange rate anomaly" and to generate

high volatility of relative prices (but low volatility of quantities traded cf. last

week).

2) Can generate appreciation of Home terms-of-trade in response to innovations

in Home productivity [here done under financial autarky but still holds in the

bond (dynamic) economy]

But...

* Large debate on the value of this elasticity: micro evidence versus macro

evidence (see also Imbs and Mejean (2008)).

Page 71: Advanced International Finance Part 1 - Department of Economics

* Is the appreciation of Home terms of trade following improvement in produc-

tivity a robust stylized fact? Relies on very strong wealth effects, strong home

bias in preferences (fairly closed economy) and large economy (account for a

large share of world demand).

About 2) see in particular discussions by Basu and Kollmann of "Productivity,

External Balance and Exchange Rates: Evidence on the Transmission Mecha-

nism Among G7 Countries" by CDL. Might be true for the US, hard to believe

that is a general mechanism (not that CDL focus on the US).