Active momentum trading versus passive ‘ naive diversification

  • Upload
    bboyvn

  • View
    224

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 7/27/2019 Active momentum trading versus passive naive diversification

    1/10

    This article was downloaded by: [Chi-Hsiou Hung]On: 30 April 2013, At: 00:22Publisher: RoutledgeInforma Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office: MortimerHouse, 37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK

    Quantitative FinancePublication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information:

    http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/rquf20

    Active momentum trading versus passive naive

    diversificationANURAG N. BANERJEE

    a& CHI-HSIOU D. HUNG

    b

    aDurham University, Durham Business School , Durham , UK

    bSchool of Business, University of Dundee, Division of Accounting & Finance , Dundee ,

    UK

    To cite this article: ANURAG N. BANERJEE & CHI-HSIOU D. HUNG (2013): Active momentum trading versus passive naivediversification, Quantitative Finance, 13:5, 655-663

    To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/14697688.2013.766760

    PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE

    Full terms and conditions of use: http://www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-and-conditions

    This article may be used for research, teaching, and private study purposes. Any substantial or systematicreproduction, redistribution, reselling, loan, sub-licensing, systematic supply, or distribution in any form to

    anyone is expressly forbidden.The publisher does not give any warranty express or implied or make any representation that the contentswill be complete or accurate or up to date. The accuracy of any instructions, formulae, and drug dosesshould be independently verified with primary sources. The publisher shall not be liable for any loss, actions,claims, proceedings, demand, or costs or damages whatsoever or howsoever caused arising directly orindirectly in connection with or arising out of the use of this material.

    http://www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-and-conditionshttp://www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-and-conditionshttp://dx.doi.org/10.1080/14697688.2013.766760http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/rquf20
  • 7/27/2019 Active momentum trading versus passive naive diversification

    2/10

  • 7/27/2019 Active momentum trading versus passive naive diversification

    3/10

    656 Feature

    use no information and weight risky assets randomly. Overall,

    they find that, over the long run, the rewards and penalties

    cancel out and that the momentum strategist is no better than

    a simple naive randomizer. One interesting outcome of the

    construction of this universe of naive investors is that the me-

    dian naive investor follows the naive diversification strategy

    or the 1/N allocation rule. Essentially, such a 1/N allocation

    rule is a passive strategy that tracks the equally weighted stock

    portfolio without using past information.

    In this paper, we aim to understand the merits and demerits

    of the active momentum trading and this passive 1/N strategy.

    For this purpose we examine their raw and risk-adjusted prof-

    its and idiosyncratic variances (in other words, the variance

    of returns due to stock selection Sharpe (1992)). We further

    investigate the relation between these strategies in terms of

    their correlation and the dimensions of risk exposures.

    We consider a naive diversification strategy (NDS) that is

    long in theequally weighted (1/N) portfolioof stocksand short

    in therisk-free asset at thebeginning of a period. This creates an

    initial zero-net-worth position as in the momentum strategies.The returns on the 1/N portfolio in excess of the risk-free rate,

    using the one-month Treasury bill rate as a proxy, are thus the

    profits of the zero-net-worth strategies of the NDS. At the end

    of the period the NDS re-balances the stock portfolio in order

    to remain equally weighted. The NDS then holds the portfolio

    for the next period and continues to be financed at the risk-free

    rate. This strategy can be implemented practically and tracked

    over time.

    The momentum strategies (MS) first form portfolios of the

    winner (top 10% past returns) and the loser (bottom 10% past

    returns) stocks and then hold a long position on the winner

    portfolio and a short position on the loser portfolio. The mo-mentum strategies further execute intensive trading in order to

    establish overlapping strategy positions.

    We use the monthly equity data of the NYSE, AMEX and

    NASDAQ over the sample period between 1926 and 2005,

    various sub-sample periods and 100 randomly selected 10-

    year periods. The set of sample stocks that we use to construct

    the equally weighted portfolio is the same as that for con-

    structing the momentum strategies. We find that the average

    profit of the NDS is around 1% per month, close to that of

    the MS, in our sample period and in the sub-sample periods

    ofJegadeesh and Titman (1993, 2001). The MS generates the

    same level of profits as the NDS during the period of bull

    markets such as the dot-com bubble and makes profits fromselling short the losers in the great depression period. Further,

    we divide the sample into two groups of large and small size

    stocks for the various sub-sample periods and find that, in each

    size group, the difference between the average profits of the

    NDS and the MS is close to zero and statistically insignificant.

    Moreover, the variance of the idiosyncratic component of

    the momentum profits is 20 times higher than the NDS profits.

    Importantly, the risk-adjusted alpha of the difference in profits

    between the momentum and the NDS is virtually zero and

    statistically insignificant. The NDS and the momentum strate-

    gies are orthogonal, i.e. their profits have zero correlation. The

    momentum profitsshowa positive marketbeta anda significantloading of nearly 1 on the momentum factor. In contrast, the

    NDS has a significantly positive market beta, but does not have

    significant exposure on the momentum factor.

    On a risk-adjusted basis,the winners outperform theNDS by

    14 basis points per month, while the losers under-perform the

    NDS by 18 basis points per month. The results, taken together,

    suggest that asset managers might be able to earn higher risk-

    adjusted excess returns than the NDS by either taking a long

    position in the winner portfolio, or by taking a short position in

    theloser portfolio. TheMS, however,are notbetter off pursuing

    the combined longshort trading because a simple strategy

    that equally weights the feasible set of stocks can achieve the

    same level of average profit, either raw or risk-adjusted, as the

    momentum strategies, but with lower idiosyncratic variance.

    Our findings are robust with respect to sampling and period-

    specific effects as we simulate the distributions of the aver-

    age returns of the winner and the loser portfolios as well as

    the momentum profits by re-sampling with replacements. In

    each of the 100 randomly chosen 10-year periods we use all

    stocks feasible for trading in the sample during that period,

    and then construct the empirical distribution of the average

    profits. At the 5% level, all of the 100 samples accept the

    null hypothesis that the momentum profits are equivalent tothe profits of the NDS. We further consider the momentum

    strategies based on 12-month formation and 12-month holding

    periods as in Jegadeesh and Titman (1993). Overall, our results

    still hold, showing that adopting naive 1/N diversification is

    a good investment policy relative to the 12-month momentum

    strategies.

    Our findings are important for practitioners and investors.

    The results illustrate that the MS requires the analysis of past

    return information and then takes both sides of the extreme

    return positions, thereby taking up the risk from the tails of the

    return distribution. By doing so, they significantly reduce the

    exposure to the market risk but face large dispersions in theprofits.

    The NDS, by contrast, simply weights stocks equally and

    performs as well as the MS, and even has lower idiosyncratic

    variance. From a practical point of view, pursuing the active

    momentum strategies would not be beneficial once further tak-

    ing into account the costs of the intensive longshort trading,

    the risks and regulation restrictions on short sales of stocks.

    The rest of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2

    defines the naive diversification strategy and the momentum

    strategies. In section 3 we examine the profitability of these

    strategies over the whole sample period, some interesting sub-

    sample periods, and 100 randomly selected 10-year periods.

    Section 4 analyses the theoretical and empirical relations be-tween the momentum and the 1/N naive diversification strate-

    gies, risk factor exposures and idiosyncratic variance. Section

    5 concludes.

    2. The naive 1/N diversification strategy and the momen-

    tum strategies

    We define N stocks that are feasible for trading at a given

    month as in Jegadeesh and Titman (1993). The set ofN stocks

    we use for forming the NDS strategies is in fact the same

    Jones and Lamont (2002), for example, describe the difficultiesof short sales, including the risks, costs, legal and institutionalrestrictions, and the need of sufficient stock supply from investorswho are willing to lend.

    http://-/?-http://-/?-
  • 7/27/2019 Active momentum trading versus passive naive diversification

    4/10

    Feature 657

    as the set of stocks for forming the momentum strategies.

    Specifically, we use all the monthly equity data of the New

    York Stock Exchange (NYSE), the American Stock Exchange

    (AMEX) and NASDAQ files from the Center for Research in

    Security Price (CRSP)for theperiod between January 1926 and

    December 2005. We includes all stocks classified as ordinary

    common shares (CRSP share codes 10 and 11) with exchange

    codes of 1, 2 and 3 as of the end of the previous year. We thus

    exclude all non-common equities such as American deposit

    receipts, companies incorporated outside of the U.S., shares of

    beneficial interests, certificates, real estate investment trusts,

    close-end funds, etc. A stock must meet the following criteria

    in order to be included for analysis: first, a stock must have

    observations on returns for the current month and over the past

    6 or 12 months (depending on the respective analysis period),

    stock price, and shares outstanding. Second, a stock must have

    a price equal to or higher than $5 at portfolio formation.

    Our tests focus on the representative overlapping momen-

    tum strategies that form portfolios by sorting stocks on their

    past 6-month compounded returns and hold portfolios for6 months. At the end of each month, the stocks within the

    top 10% of past returns comprise the winner portfolio FW,

    and stocks within the bottom 10% of past returns comprise the

    loser portfolio FL. Portfolios are equally weighted at formation

    and are held for six months without re-balancing during the

    holding period. The momentum strategy is then defined as

    FP = (FW FL).Denote r = [r1, r2, . . . , rN] as the vector of returns on the

    feasible stocks in excess of the risk-free rate rf. We compute

    monthly excess portfolio returns (rW = rFW and rL = rFL)and the profits, rP = rFP, for the momentum strategies using

    single-period returns as in Liu and Strong (2008). The momen-tum strategies have six overlapping strategy positions, each

    starting one month apart. The monthly portfolio returns from

    the overlapping strategies are averages of the six strategies as

    in Jegadeesh and Titman (1993).

    We construct the 1/N naive diversification strategy over

    these N feasible stocks. The excess portfolio returns from the

    strategy,

    1

    N1 =

    1

    N,

    1

    N, . . . ,

    1

    N

    ,

    are then given by r = (1/N)Ni=1 ri., where r is effectivelythe profit of the 1/N naive diversification strategy.

    Banerjee and Hung (2011) demonstrate that this strategy doesnot involve information costs and is the cross-sectional mean

    and the projection median of their uniformly distributed

    random strategies.

    3. Profitability of the strategies

    The top panel of figure 1 plots the time-series of profit

    differences between the momentum and the NDS strategies.

    The profit differences mainly center around zero and exhibit

    sporadic deviations from zero most of the time. During the

    In the case where a stock is delisted during the holding period, theliquidating proceeds are reinvested in the remaining stocks in theportfolio.

    periods from 1929 through 1933 and in the late 1990s, how-

    ever, there exist large positive and negative deviations. These

    periods correspond, respectively, to the great depression and

    the dot-com bubble. We thus carefully examine these sub-

    sample periods.

    Panel A of table 1 presents the average excess returns of

    the winner and the loser portfolios, the average momentum

    profits as well as the average differences in excess returns

    between these portfolios and the NDS. The winner and the

    loser portfolios have average excess returns of 1.78% and

    0.70% per month, respectively. The momentum strategies gen-

    erate a statistically significant average profit of 1.08% per

    month. Strikingly, the average profit of the NDS is as high as

    1.06% permonthand is highlysignificant.The winnerportfolio

    outperforms the NDS by a statistically significant 0.72% per

    month, while the loser portfolio under-performs the NDS by a

    statistically significant 0.36% per month. Importantly, the av-

    erage difference between the profits of the momentum and the

    zero-net-worth NDS strategies is virtually zero and statistically

    insignificant.We next look into the question of whether size matters in

    our analysis. For this purpose, we divide the sample, each

    month, into two groups of large and small size stocks using

    the median of the market value of all sample stocks at the

    end of the previous month as the cut-off point. We then form

    the momentum and the zero-net-worth NDS strategies within

    each of the groups. Panel A of table 2 shows that, in each

    size group, the difference between the average profits of the

    momentum and the NDS strategies is close to zero and statisti-

    cally insignificant. Within the sample of small size stocks, the

    average monthly momentum profit is five basis points lower

    (but statistically insignificant) than that of the NDS; within thesample of large size stocks, the average momentum profit is 11

    basis points higher (but statistically insignificant) than that of

    the NDS.

    3.1. Over sub-sample periods

    Next, we examine the profitability of the momentum and the

    1/N naive diversification strategies over the sample periods

    ofJegadeesh and Titman (1993, 2001) from 1965 to 1989 and

    from 1990 to 1998, respectively. Panel B of table 1 shows that,

    over the former sub-period, the momentum strategies generate

    a statistically significant average profit of around 1.1% per

    month.The NDS hasa statistically significant average monthlyprofit of 0.9%. The average difference in profits between the

    momentum and the NDS strategies is 0.18%, but statistically

    insignificant. Compared with the NDS, the winner portfolio

    significantly over-performs by 0.72%, while the loser portfolio

    significantly under-performs by 0.36% per month. The results

    in panel C of table 1 for the latter subperiod are similar. Again,

    there is virtually no difference in profits between the momen-

    tum and the NDS strategies. The middle panels of figure 1 plot

    the differences in profits between the momentum and the NDS

    strategies over the sample periods of Jegadeesh and Titman

    (1993, 2001). The profit differences mainly center around zero

    and only exhibit sporadic deviations from zero.As discussed above, we observe large profit differences be-

    tween the momentum and the NDS strategies in the early and

    later periods of our sample. We therefore further examine the

    http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-
  • 7/27/2019 Active momentum trading versus passive naive diversification

    5/10

    658 Feature

    Figure 1. Distributions of the differences in profits between the momentum strategy and the NDS for the various sample periods.

    Table 1. Profitability of the six-month momentum and the 1/N naive diversification strategies. This table presents mean excess returns ofthe momentum strategies and the 1/N naive diversification strategies (NDS) for the whole sample period (panel A), the sub-sample periodsof Jagadeesh and Titman (1993, 2001) (panels B and C), the periods during the great depression (panel D) and the dot-com bubble (panelE). We use the one-month T-bill rate as a proxy for the risk-free rate. Winner and Loser are, respectively, the returns on the winner andthe loser portfolios in excess of the one-month T-bill rate. WinnerNDS and LoserNDS are, respectively, the return differences betweenWinner, Loser and the NDS. Momentum profit-NDSis the difference between the profits of the momentum and the NDS. t-Statistics are

    in parentheses. , and denote statistical significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level, respectively.

    Winner Loser Momentum profits NDS WinnerNDS LoserNDS Momentum profit- NDS

    Panel A: The whole sample: 01-1927 to 07-2005Mean return (%) 1.78 0.70 1.08 1.06 0.72 0.36 0.02

    (6.97) (2.4) (5.86) (4.96) (6.10) (2.99) (0.06)Panel B: JagadeeshTitman (1993): 01-1965 to 12-1989Mean return (%) 1.62 0.54 1.13 0.90 0.72 0.36 0.18

    (3.90) (1.33) (4.68) (2.64) (4.40) (2.87) (0.43)Panel C: JagadeeshTitman (2001): 01-1990 to 12-1998Mean return (%) 2.22 0.79 1.60 1.34 0.88 0.54 0.09

    (3.41) (1.32) (4.36) (3.02) (3.21) (2.17) (0.18)Panel D: Great depression: 08-1929 to 03-1933Mean return (%) 1.69 2.41 0.72 2.02 0.33 0.39 2.74

    (1.02) (0.76) (0.34) (0.98) (0.42) (0.27) (0.72)Panel E: Dot-com bubble: 01-1995 to 02-2000Mean return (%) 3.96 1.11 2.86 1.59 2.37

    0.48 1.27

    (3.13) (1.21) (3.37) (2.49) (2.81) (-1.27) (1.31)

    sub-sample periods between August 1929 and March 1933

    during the great depression as designated by the NBER and

    between January 1995 andMarch2000 for thedot-com bubble.

    Interestingly, we find that during the great depression period,

    asshown inpanel D of table 1, thewinner portfolio loses 1.69%

    per month, but the loser portfolio incurs an even larger aver-

    age monthly loss of2.41%. The average momentum profitof 0.72%, although statistically insignificant, mainly comes

    from the short position on the loser portfolio. The NDS also

    suffers an average monthly loss of

    2.02%. The average of the

    excess returns on the winner portfolio is only 33 basis points

    higher than the average profit of the NDS, but statistically

    insignificant. The average difference in profits between the

    momentum and the NDS strategies, although as high as 2.74%,

    is statistically insignificant because of the greater volatility in

    this period. The right-hand panel of the lower part of figure 1

    shows that the profit differences over this period display a few

    very large negative outliers.

    Panel E of table 1 shows that, during the dot-com bubble

    period, the winner portfolio has an average monthly excess

    return of 3.96%, which is 2.37% higher than that of the NDS.

    The average excess return on the loser portfolio is 48 basis

    points lower than the NDS, albeit statistically insignificant.

    The average difference between the profits of the momentum

    and the NDS strategies is 1.27%, but statistically insignificant.

    The left-hand panel of the lower part of figure 1 shows that the

  • 7/27/2019 Active momentum trading versus passive naive diversification

    6/10

  • 7/27/2019 Active momentum trading versus passive naive diversification

    7/10

    660 Feature

    where t = [1t, . . . , it, . . . , Ntt], Bt = [1ti t, . . . , N t]is the vector of factor loadings, xt are common risk factors,2t is the idiosyncratic variance at time t and Nt is the total

    number of assets at time t.

    The idiosyncratic variance of NDS is simply Var(rt | xt) =2t (1/Nt). Also note that Cov(rj t, r

    1(1/Nt) | xt) = 2t Fj t1(1/N

    t)

    =2

    t(1/N

    t),

    j= W,L. Therefore, it is easy to see thatthe conditional mean of the excess returns on the winner and

    loser portfolios can be given by

    E(rjt | xt, rt) = (t+Btxt)Fjt +

    rt (t + Btxt)11

    Nt

    .

    Since Fji t = 10/Nt, if the i th asset is in the winner portfolio,we obtain the idiosyncratic variance as

    Var(rjt | x, r) = 2Fj tFj t = 2t10

    Nt.

    Therefore, it immediately follows that the conditional mean

    and idiosyncratic variance of the momentum profits are

    E[rPt (t + Btx)FP | xt, rt] = 0, (2)Var[rPt | xt] = 2t

    20

    Nt. (3)

    The above results suggest the theoretical relations that: (1) the

    momentum strategies and NDS are orthogonal to each other,

    and (2) the idiosyncratic variance of profits is 20 times higher

    than the idiosyncratic variance of the NDS. We test these pre-

    dictions below.

    4.1. Orthogonality

    Under the assumptions made for the factor model (1) and

    from (2), the profits of the momentum strategies are orthogonal

    to the profits of the 1/N naive diversification strategies. We

    examine this prediction by plotting the excess returns on the

    winner portfolio, the loser portfolio and the momentum profits

    against the 1/N naive diversification strategies (r) in figure 3.

    The scatter plot shows that the slope coefficients for both rWand rL seem to be close to one and that the momentum profits

    are randomly scattered against r.

    Formally, we run a weighted (by

    2t /Nt ) linear regression(WLS) of the momentum profits on the profits of the NDS.

    Specifically, we examine the following time-series model to

    test the null H0 : P = 0:rj t = j + j rt + u jt, t = 1, . . . , T, j {W,L,P},

    Var(ujt) 2t

    Nt,

    where 2t is the variance oft in (1), and Nt is the total number

    of assets at time t.

    The WLS results show a P of0.04 (t = 0.43), which is inline with thepredictionsof(2) andsuggeststhat themomentum

    profits are orthogonal to the profits of the NDS. We also test

    whether the sensitivities of the winner and the loser portfolios

    on the NDS are statistically different from one. We run WLS

    regressions of excessportfolio returns on theprofits of theNDS

    to test the null of H0 : W = L = 1. The results show thatW = 0.85 and L = 0.81 are both smaller than one witht = 1.91 and t = 2.52, respectively.

    Figure 2. Distributions of the average profits of the NDS andthe excess returns of the winner and the loser portfolios and themomentum profits over 100 random sample periods. The differencein profits between the momentum strategy and the NDS is denoted byprofitNDS. Foreach runof thesimulation, we select an experimentalperiod of 120 months with the starting month randomly chosenbetween July 1926 and December 1995.

    Figure3. Scatterplots of the excessreturns on thewinner (blue line)and the loser (green line) portfolios and the momentum profits (redline) versus the profits of the NDS.

    4.2. Risk-adjusted profits and risk exposure

    We examine the risk-adjusted profits and risk factor exposuresof the momentum and the 1/N naive diversification strategies.

    Specifically, we run the time-series regression

    rj t =j + jMKTt + sj SMBt + hjHMLt+ m jMOMt + vjt, j {W,L,P,NDS}, (4)

    where rj t is the excess portfolio return or profit for strategy j

    at time t, and MKT is the return on the CRSP value-weighted

    market index at time t in excess of the one-month T-bill rate.

    The Fama and French (1993) size factor, SMB, is defined as

    the monthly return difference between two portfolios that con-

    sist of large and small stocks. The FamaFrench value factor,

    HML, is defined as the monthly return difference betweentwo portfolios with high and low book-to-market equity ratio.

    The momentum factor,MOM, is the monthly return difference

    between two portfolios with high and low returns over the past

  • 7/27/2019 Active momentum trading versus passive naive diversification

    8/10

    Feature 661

    Table 3. Risk exposures of the six-month momentum and the 1/N naive diversification strategies. Panel A reports the factor loadings of theexcess returns on the winner (Winner) and the loser (Loser) portfolios, the momentum profits and the NDS for the period from January1927 to December 2005. Momentum profit is for the strategies that are long in the winner and short in the loser portfolios. Panel B reportsthe factor loadings of WinnerNDS, LoserNDS and Momentum profit-NDS, which are the differences between the excess returns of thewinner and loser portfolios, the momentum profits and the profits of the NDS, respectively. MKTis the return on the CRSP value-weightedmarket index in excess of the one-month T-bill rate. SMB is the monthly return difference between two portfolios that consist of large andsmall size stocks. HML is the monthly return difference between two portfolios with high and low book-to-market equity ratios. MOM isthe monthly return difference between two portfolios with high and low returns over the past 2 to 12 months. The t-statistics in parentheses

    are calculated by applying the Newey-West heteroskedasticity-and-autocorrelation-consistent standard errors. , and denote statisticalsignificance at the 10level, respectively.

    Constant MKT SMB HML MOM

    Panel A: Excess returns of the momentum strategy and the NDSWinner 0.0039 1.2230 0.8001 0.0484 0.5495

    (4.85) (44.14) (10.70) (1.18) (15.17)Loser 0.0007 1.1580 0.7992 0.0635 0.4471

    (0.74) (35.89) (16.85) (1.29) (12.45)Momentum profit 0.0032 0.0649 0.0010 0.1119 0.9966

    (2.49) (1.72) (0.01) (1.64) (21.51)NDS 0.0025 1.0502 0.4251 0.0888 0.0186

    (7.10) (96.80) (14.50) (4.48) (0.88)Panel B: Return differences between the momentum strategy and the NDS

    WinnerNDS 0.0014 0.1728 0.3751 0.1372 0.5680(1.72) (6.66) (4.67) (2.93) (13.46)

    LoserNDS 0.0018 0.1079 0.3741 0.0253 0.4286(1.93) (3.20) (6.59) (0.45) (11.51)

    Momentum profitNDS 0.0007 0.9852 0.4241 0.2007 1.0151(0.50) (26.85) (3.93) (2.89) (18.63)

    2 to 12 months. The coefficients sj , hj and mj arethe loadings

    on the size, value and the momentum factors, respectively.

    Table 3 shows the regression results for the entire sample

    period. The NeweyWest standard errors are applied to correct

    for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation of residuals. Panel A

    shows that both thewinner andloser portfolios aresignificantly

    exposed to the market, SMB and momentum factors. The mo-mentum strategies have an average risk-adjusted profit of 0.3%

    per month and are marginally exposed to the market factor and

    with a highly significant loading of nearly 1 on the momentum

    factor, but with insignificant loadings on the SMB and HML

    factors. The NDS has a highly significant alpha of 0.25% per

    month with statistically significant loadings of 1.05, 0.42 and

    0.09, respectively, on the market, SMB and HML factors. The

    NDS does not have significant exposure on the MOM factor.

    Thus the momentum and the NDS bear different sources of

    risk. After accounting for the factor exposures, the magnitude

    of the risk-adjusted momentum profit is close to that of the

    NDS.

    Panel B of table 3 shows that the differences between theexcess returns of the winner portfolio and the profits of the

    NDS have a positive and marginally significant alpha with

    positive and highly significant exposures to the market, SMB

    andMOM, but witha negativeexposureto theHML factor. The

    differences between the excess returns of the loser portfolio

    and the profits of the NDS have a negative and marginally

    significant alpha with positive and highly significantexposures

    to the market and the SMB factor, but with a negative and

    highly significant exposure to the MOM factor. Importantly,

    the difference in profits between the momentum and the NDS

    has a very small and statistically insignificant alpha of seven

    basis points per month.

    The returns on these factors are obtained from Ken Frenchs datalibrary.

    4.3. Idiosyncratic variance ratio

    We test the null hypothesis that the ratio of idiosyncratic vari-

    ance (CVR = Var[rPt|xt]/Var(rt|xt)) between the momentumprofits and the NDS profits are equal to 20 as is the prediction

    of (3). Specifically, we test the null hypothesis:

    H0 : Var[rPt | xt]Var(rt | xt)

    = 20.

    Since the idiosyncratic variance (2t ) and the number of assets

    (Nt) vary over time, we cannot usethe traditional variance ratio

    test. We test this hypothesis by constructing a moment-based

    estimator for the CVR,

    CVR = 1T

    Tt=1

    CVRt, where CVRt =v2Ptv2NDSt ,

    where

    vPt and

    vNDSt are the residuals from the regressions

    in (4). Note that

    E(CVRt) = Ev2Ptv2NDSt =

    Ev2PtEv2NDSt =

    Var[rPt | xt]Var(rt | xt)

    .

    The second equality follows from Heijmans (1999). Finally,

    using (3) we obtain the expected variance ratio. Therefore,

    under the null hypothesis by the central limit theorem, the

    standardized statistic is

    ZCVR =

    T(CVR E(CVR))

    stdev(CVR)

    D N(0, 1). (5)

    Under the null hypothesis E(CVR) = 20. We obtain a calcu-latedZCVR of 1.005 over the whole sample period, and, hence,accept the hypothesis that the idiosyncratic variance of the

    momentum portfolio is 20 times higher than the idiosyncratic

    variance of the NDS.

    http://-/?-http://-/?-
  • 7/27/2019 Active momentum trading versus passive naive diversification

    9/10

    662 Feature

    Table 4. Profitability of the 12-month momentum and the 1/N naive diversification strategies. This table presents mean excess returns ofthe momentum strategies (12 month by 12 month) and the 1/N naive diversification strategies (NDS) for the whole sample period (panelA), the sub-sample periods of JagadeeshTitman (1993, 2001) (panels B and C), the periods during the great depression (panel D) and thedot-com bubble (panel E). We use the one-month T-bill rate as a proxy for the risk-free rate. Winner and Loser are, respectively, the returnson the winner and the loser portfolios in excess of the one-month T-bill rate. WinnerNDS and LoserNDS are, respectively, the returndifferences between Winner, Loser and the NDS. Momentum profitNDS is the difference between the profits of the momentum and the

    NDS. t-Statistics are in parentheses. , and denote statistical significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level, respectively.

    Winner Loser Momentum profits NDS WinnerNDS LoserNDS Momentum profitsNDS

    Panel A: The whole sample: 01-1928 to 01-2005Mean return (%) 1.38 1.11 0.28 1.04 0.35 0.07 0.76

    (5.29) (3.76) (1.55) (4.79) (2.70) (0.56) (2.42)Panel B: JagadeeshTitman (1993): 01-1965 to 12-1989Mean return (%) 1.28 0.64 0.63 0.83 0.45 0.19 0.20

    (2.75) (1.50) (2.45) (2.33) (2.22) (1.34) (0.46)Panel C: JagadeeshTitman (2001): 01-1990 to 12-1998Mean return (%) 2.36 1.96 0.40 1.71 0.66 0.26 1.31

    (3.14) (3.42) (0.96) (4.02) (1.70) (1.07) (2.85)Panel D: Great depression: 08-1929 to 03-1933Mean return (%) 1.40 1.28 0.12 1.12 0.28 0.17 -1.00

    (1.15) (1.09) (0.21) (1.34) (0.53) (0.33) (1.04)Panel E: Dot-com bubble: 01-1995 to 02-2000

    Mean return (%) 3.93 5.08 1.15 5.11 1.19 0.04 6.26(1.03) (0.72) (0.33) (0.90) (0.60) (0.02) (0.70)

    Table 5. Risk exposures of the 12-month momentum and the 1/N naive diversification strategies. Panel A reports the factor loadings of theexcess returns on the (12 month by 12 month) winner (Winner) and the (12 month by 12 month) loser (Loser) portfolios, the momentumprofits and the NDS for the period from January 1927 to December 2005. Momentum profitis for the (12 month by 12 month) strategies thatare long in the winner and short in the loser portfolios. Panel B reports the factor loadings of Winner-NDS, Loser-NDS and Momentumprofit-NDS, which are the differences between the excess returns of the winner and loser portfolios, the momentum profits and the profitsof the NDS, respectively. M K T is the return on the CRSP value-weighted market index in excess of the one-month T-bill rate. S M B is themonthly return difference between two portfolios that consist of large and small size stocks. H M L is the monthly return difference betweentwo portfolios with high and low book-to-market equity ratios. M O M is the monthly return difference between two portfolios with high andlow returns over the past 2 to 12 months. The t-statistics in parentheses are calculated by applying the NeweyWest heteroskedasticity-and-

    autocorrelation-consistent standard errors. , and denote statistical significance at the 10level, respectively.

    Constant M K T S M B H M L M O M

    Panel A: Excess returns of the momentum strategy and the NDS Winner0.0010 1.2493 0.7377 0.1945 0.5280(1.07) (42.23) (9.04) (3.43) (12.28)

    Loser 0.0013 1.1573 0.9209 0.2894 0.1302(1.01) (27.14) (14.19) (4.69) (2.43)

    Momentum profit 0.0002 0.0920 0.1832 0.4839 0.6582(0.14) (2.26) (1.56) (5.59) (11.13)

    NDS 0.0025 1.0498 0.4251 0.0894 0.0183(7.03) (95.76) (14.37) (4.46) (0.86)

    Panel B: Return differences between the momentum strategy and the NDSWinnerNDS 0.0015 0.1994 0.3126 0.2839 0.5463

    (1.55) (6.42) (4.08) (4.41) (11.47)LoserNDS

    0.0013 0.1075 0.4958 0.2000

    0.1119

    (1.03) (2.68) (6.02) (3.33) (2.32)Momentum profitNDS 0.0028 0.9579 0.6084 0.5734 0.6765

    (1.68) (21.03) (5.71) (6.04) (9.64)

    4.4. Twelve-month momentum

    For a robustness check, we further consider the momentum

    strategies based on 12-month formation and 12-month holding

    periods as in Jegadeesh and Titman (1993). Using exactly the

    same criteria for theselection of thestockset, thestocks that are

    feasible for trading exclude those whose prices are below $5

    at portfolio formation. Consistent with Jegadeesh and Titman

    (1993), panel B of table 4 reports the average (12-by-12) mo-mentum profit as 0.63% per month and statistically significant.

    Panel A for the entire sample period shows that the winner

    and the loser portfolios have average excess returns of 1.38%

    and 1.11% per month, respectively. The average momentum

    profit is 0.28% per month, but statistically insignificant. The

    average profit of the NDS remains statistically significant at

    1.04% per month. The momentum strategies under-perform

    the zero-net-worth NDS strategies by 0.76% per month. The

    overall pattern of the results presented in table 4 shows that

    momentum strategies do not outperform the NDS strategies.Table 5 shows, for the entire sample period, the regression

    results and the t-statistics using the NeweyWest standard

    errors. In contrast to the results in table 3, panel A of table 5

  • 7/27/2019 Active momentum trading versus passive naive diversification

    10/10

    Feature 663

    shows that theHML factor becomes statistically significant for

    the winner portfolio, the loser portfolio and the momentum

    profit. Further, the average risk-adjusted return on the winner

    portfolio is essentially zero and statistically insignificant, while

    the alpha of the NDS remains statistically significant at 0.25%

    per month.

    Panel B of table 5 shows that the model alpha of the differ-

    ence between the excess return on the winner portfolio and the

    NDS profit is now negative, reflecting the insignificant model

    alpha of the winner portfolio as shown in panel A, while the

    pattern of risk exposures is similar to that of the 6-month-by-6-

    month momentum. The model alpha of the difference between

    the loser portfolio and the NDS profit is close to zero and

    statistically insignificant. The model alpha of the difference

    in profits between the momentum and the NDS is a negative

    28 basis points per month and statistically significant. Overall,

    the 12-month momentum strategies under-perform the NDS

    strategies.

    Overall, our results still hold, and, in fact, the 12-month mo-

    mentum strategies under-perform the NDS strategies, showingthat the use of adopting the naive 1/N diversification is a

    good investment policy relative to the 12-month momentum

    strategies.

    5. Conclusions

    In this paper we examine the merits and demerits of the active

    momentum strategies that use stocks of the top and bottom

    10% returns and the passive 1/N naive diversification strategy

    which is long in the equally weighted portfolio of stocks and

    short in the risk-free asset. The momentum and the NDS strate-

    gies areorthogonal.The NDSgenerates an average profit of 1%per month, close to that of the momentum strategies over the

    sample periodbetween 1926 and2005, andvarious sub-sample

    periods, including those examined by Jegadeesh and Titman

    (1993,2001). The evidence shows that the differences in the

    average profits between the momentum and the NDS strate-

    gies are economically and statistically insignificant. The find-

    ings are robust with respect to market capitalization effects as

    well as sampling and period-specific effects in our simulations,

    where we randomly select 10 years for 100 times. From the

    viewpoint of investment, our findings suggest that pursuing

    the active momentum trading would not be beneficial relative

    to the passive 1/N naive diversification strategy.

    References

    Avramov, D. and Chordia, T., Asset pricing models and financialmarket anomalies. Rev. Financ. Stud., 2006, 19, 10011040.

    Banerjee, A. and Hung, C-H., Informed momentum trading versusuninformed naive investors strategies. J. Bank. Finance, 2011,35, 30773089.

    Benartzi, S. and Thaler, R.H., Naive diversification strategies indefined contribution saving plans.Am. Econ. Rev., 2001, 91, 7998.

    Benartzi, S. and Thaler, R.H., Heuristics and biases in retirementsavings behavior. J. Econ. Perspect., 2007, 21, 81104.

    DeMiguel, V., Garlappi, L. and Uppal, R., Optimal versus naivediversification: how inefficient is the 1/N portfolio strategy? Rev.Financ. Stud., 2009, 22, 19151953.

    Fama, E.F. and French, K.R., Common risk factors in the returns on

    stocks and bonds. J. Financ. Econ., 1993, 33, 356.Fama, E.F. and French, K.R., Multifactor explanations of asset pricinganomalies. J. Finance, 1996, 51, 5584.

    Heijmans, R., When does the expectation of a ratio equal the ratio ofexpectations? Statist. Pap., 1999, 40(1), 107115.

    Huberman, G. and Jiang, W., Offering vs. choice in 401(k) plans:equity exposure and number of funds. J. Finance, 2006, 61, 763801.

    Jegadeesh, N. and Titman, S., Returns to buying winners and sellinglosers: implications for stock market efficiency. J. Finance, 1993,48, 6591.

    Jegadeesh, N. and Titman, S., Profitability of momentum strategies:an evaluation of alternative explanations. J. Finance, 2001, 56,699720.

    Jones, C. and Lamont, O., Short-sale constraints and stock returns. J.

    Financ. Econ., 2002, 66, 207239.Korajczyk, R.A. and Sadka, R., Are momentum profits robust totrading costs? J. Finance, 2004, 59, 10391082.

    Liu, L.X. and Zhang, L., Momentum profits, factor pricing, andmacroeconomic risk. Rev. Financ. Stud., 2008, 21, 24172448.

    Liu, W. and Strong, N., Biases in decomposing holding periodportfolio returns. Rev. Financ. Stud., 2008, 21, 22432274.

    Sagi, J.S. and Seasholes, M.S., Firm-specific attributes and the crosssection of momentum. J. Financ. Econ., 2007, 84, 389434.

    Sharpe, W., Asset allocation: management style and performancemeasurement. J. Portfol. Mgmt, 1992, 719.