110
Faculteit Rechtsgeleerdheid Universiteit Gent Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door Janick Van Daele studentennr. 01004154 Promotor Prof. dr. Jacques Bourgeois Co-promotor Jan Bocken

Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    4

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

Faculteit Rechtsgeleerdheid

Universiteit Gent

Academiejaar 2015-2016

Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II

Masterproef van de opleiding

‘Master in de rechten’

Ingediend door

Janick Van Daele

studentennr. 01004154

Promotor Prof. dr. Jacques Bourgeois

Co-promotor Jan Bocken

Page 2: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door
Page 3: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

3

Table of Contents

Acknowledgements .............................................................................................................. 1

Summary ..................................................................................................................... 2

Chapter: 1 INTRODUCTION....................................................................................... 3

1.1 Background ....................................................................................................... 3

1.2 Purpose .............................................................................................................. 3

1.3 Research Questions ........................................................................................... 5

1.4 Research Method .............................................................................................. 5

1.5 Structure ............................................................................................................ 6

Chapter: 2 HISTORICAL CONTEXT OF ART. 102 TFEU ...................................... 7

2.1 Overview ........................................................................................................... 7

2.2 Summary Conclusion ...................................................................................... 15

Chapter: 3 THE CONCEPT OF ABUSE UNDER ART. 102 TFEU ....................... 15

3.1 General ............................................................................................................ 15

3.2 Objective of Article 102 TFEU....................................................................... 18

3.3 Special responsibility ...................................................................................... 21

3.4 Exclusionairy vs. Exploitative Abuses ........................................................... 22

3.5 Summary conclusion ....................................................................................... 24

Chapter: 4 REBATE SCHEMES AS AN ABUSE OF DOMINANCE .................... 26

4.1 Per se illegal rebate schemes........................................................................... 27

4.1.1 Presumption of illegality of loyalty rebates or the by object

prohibition .................................................................................... 27

4.1.2 Anti-competitive vs. pro-competitive effects of loyalty

rebates .......................................................................................... 32

4.1.3 Residual category of rebates and Michelin I ................................ 35

4.2 Presumed legality of quantity rebates ............................................................. 38

4.2.1 Definition ..................................................................................... 38

4.2.2 Michelin II and the abandonment of the presumption ................. 39

4.2.3 British Airways ............................................................................ 42

4.3 Objective Justification .................................................................................... 45

4.3.1 Overview ...................................................................................... 45

4.3.2 Legitimate business interest ......................................................... 47

4.3.3 Legitimate public interest. ........................................................... 47

Page 4: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

4.3.4 Econocmic jusifcation. ................................................................. 48

4.4 Summary Conclusion. ..................................................................................... 49

Chapter: 5 MODERNIZATION OF ART 102 TFEU AND THE GUIDANCE

PAPER ................................................................................................................... 51

5.1 The As-efficient-competitor test ..................................................................... 54

5.2 The legal nature of the as-efficient-competitor test ........................................ 58

5.3 The As-efficient competitor test following the Post Danmark II

judgment .................................................................................................... 60

5.4 Summary conclusion ....................................................................................... 63

Chapter: 6 A BY EFFECT APPROACH OF REBATE SCHEMES UNDER

ARTICLE 102 TFEU ........................................................................................................ 65

6.1 A new legal framework for rebate schemes .................................................... 67

6.2 Summary conclusion ....................................................................................... 72

Chapter: 7 POST DANMARK II ................................................................................ 73

7.1 Facts ................................................................................................................ 73

7.2 Opinion AG Kokott......................................................................................... 77

7.3 The judgement of the Court ............................................................................ 82

7.4 Summary conclusion ....................................................................................... 91

Chapter: 8 CONCLUSION ......................................................................................... 93

Page 5: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

1-1

Page 6: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door
Page 7: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

1

Acknowledgements

To obtain the title of Master of Laws, the writing of a thesis is a required hurdle to pass. It is customary

to start off by acknowledging and thanking the people who had a positive impact in the coming about

of the paper. In my case, these are certainly due.

First of I would like to thank my mother for haven given me the opportunity to pursue a higher education.

These past five years have been a tremendous gift and I will accordingly forever be indebted.

I would also like to thank Prof. dr. Jochen Mohr of the Technische Universität Dresden. My interest in

EU competition law was sparked by his enthusiastic teachings during the lectures ‘Kartellrecht’.

Gratitude is also due to Prof. dr. Bourgeois and Jan Bocken for suggesting the topic of my thesis and

supporting me throughout the whole process. The discussions during the classes ‘EU Competition law’

have led me to many engaging insights. Overall the writing of this thesis has been an enriching

experience considering the interesting topic of the paper.

Lastly, I would like to thank my friends for the many coffee breaks at the law faculty and the general

collective support. Their words of encouragement and advice pushed me to continue writing when

writer’s block was looming.

Page 8: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

Summary

The main topic of this thesis will be the abuse of dominance under EU law. Abuse of dominance can

cover several topics, but this paper will limit itself to an assessment of the current state of rebate schemes

granted by dominant undertakings under EU law. On the 6th of October 2015 the Court of Justice of the

European Union issued its judgment in the Post Danmark II case. This case was seen by many1 as an

excellent opportunity for the Court to provide guidance on the state of rebate schemes under Article 102

TFEU.

The case law concerning this topic has been highly contested throughout the years as the framework put

forward by the EU courts was too focused on the ‘form’ of the rebates as opposed to the concrete

negative effect it had on the internal market. Contrary to this approach is a more ‘effects based’ approach

put forward by the Commission in the publication of its Guidance Paper. In order to assess the impact

of the Post Danmark II judgement on the abuse of dominance, the preceding relevant case-law by the

EU courts will be analyzed and put in the broad historical context of Article 102 TFEU.

1 L. PEEPERKORN., “Conditional pricing: Why the General Court is wrong in Intel and what the Court of Justice

can do to rebalance the assessment of rebates”, Concurrences Review 2015,43-63; COLOMO, P., “Intel and Article

102 TFEU Case Law: Making Sense of a Perpetual Controversy”, LSE Working Papers, 62.

Page 9: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

3

1.1 BACKGROUND

1. Article 102 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union2 prohibits the abuse of

dominance by a dominant undertaking. This Article is in line with the economic policy provisions

and principles listed in the founding Treaties of the European Union3. Protocol 27 of the TFEU

states the following:

“The High Contracting Parties, considering that the internal market as set out in article

3 of the treaty on European union includes a system ensuring that competition is not

distorted, have agreed that: to this end, the Union shall, if necessary, take action under

the provisions of the Treaties, including under Article 352 of the Treaty on the

Functioning of the European Union. This protocol shall be annexed to the Treaty on

European Union and to the Treaty on the functioning of the European Union.”

2. Dominant undertakings are ultimately the subject of this provision. Article 102 TFEU provides

limitations to the possible conduct of dominant undertakings. Non-dominant undertakings are not

subject to the rules of Article 102 TFEU and therefore do not need to fear prosecution by a

competition authority or private enforcement. Having found a violation of Article 102 TFEU can

have far reaching consequences for a dominant undertaking. In 2009, Intel, for example, was fined

€1.06 billion for the abuse of its dominant position on the market of CPU’s. It is therefore necessary

that, in line with the principle of legal certainty4, there is a clear set of rules by which dominant

undertakings can assess whether they are liable to violate Article 102 TFEU.

1.2 PURPOSE

3. The purpose of this paper is twofold. First, I will indicate that, as it stands now, Article 102 TFEU

lacks the necessary clarity for dominant undertakings to assess their conduct in advance under

Article 102 TFEU. Under Article 102 TFEU, a rough distinction is generally made between two

2 Consolidated version of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union, OJ C 326, 26.10.2012, p. 47–390.

(hereafter ‘TFEU’. 3 Being the TFEU and TEU. See to that extent Article 120 TFEU, 119 TFEU and Article 3 TEU. 4 A PORTUESE, O. GOUGH, J. TANEGA, “The Principle of Legal Certainty as a Principle of Economic

Efficiency”, Research Paper No. 13-13, University of Westminster School of Law, p. 3.

Page 10: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

categories of abusive conduct.5 On the one hand there is conduct that has an exclusionary6 effect

on the market and on the other there is conduct which can exploit7 certain actors in the relevant

market. The scope of this paper will be limited to one specific variant of conduct scrutinized by

Article 102, being price-based exclusionary conduct. More specifically, this thesis will limit itself

to rebates issued by dominant undertakings. Second, I will discuss the future and impact of abuse of

dominance under Article 102 TFEU after Post Danmark II judgement of the CJEU. The status of

the recently adopted ‘As efficient Competitor –test’ by the Commission in the context of rebates

will also be assessed.

4. In Post Danmark II a Danish court asked several questions concerning the assessment of rebates to

the European Court of Justice. The Post Danmark II case is a good example of the ails plaguing

Article 102 TFEU. It was also seen in the legal doctrine as an excellent opportunity for the Court to

clarify certain aspects of the case law concerning rebates, and more specifically standardized

rebates, under Article 102 TFEU. The Post Danmark II judgement is the product of a line of case

law that, at times, has been highly contested8. The main criticism of these judgements is that they

are not based on any sound economy reasoning or rather do not involve an assessment of the effects

the conduct has. In short, certain conduct by dominant undertakings, like loyalty rebates, are seen

to have a negative effect on the competitive structure of the market. Once the rebate scheme is seen

to have characteristics similar to other exclusive conduct it will be considered as being exclusionary.

The EU Courts assume that this is the case without performing any assessment of the effects.

5. Two lines of case-law run through the judgements of the EU Courts with regards to abuse of

dominance. On one hand there is a per se violation of Article 102 TFEU of certain conduct, much

like the ‘by object’ restriction of Article 101 TFEU, where the Courts will presume that the conduct

is abusive as such and therefore has a negative effect on the competitive structure of the market and

therefore ultimately the consumer. Whether there are, in fact, any negative effects on the relevant

market is not of relevance. The Court will accordingly not go in to an assessment of these anti-

competitive effects. This is commonly called the ‘form-based approach’ as an assessment of the

concrete or potential effects is not needed, an assessment of the form of the rebate scheme will

suffice. On the other hand, there are different types of conduct which are assessed under a standard

5 See to that extent paragraph on the distinction between exclusionary and exploitative conduct. 6 A dominant undertaking who sets its prices under average variable cost level would reasonably have no other

incentive to do so than to attract customers away from its main competitors. 7 By charging excessive prices to customers for example. 8P. COLOMO,“Intel and Article 102 TFEU Case Law: Making Sense of a Perpetual Controversy”, LSE Working

Papers, 2-31.

Page 11: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

5

instead of a rule. Again, with regards to this approach, similarities can be found with a ‘by effect’

violation of Article 101 TFEU. For these types of conduct the Courts will assess whether the conduct

has anti-competitive effects. In other words, the presumption of negative effects on the internal

market is not at play here.

6. As I will indicate, the EU Courts have traditionally upheld this per se violation approach to rebates

schemes applied by dominant undertakings. This presumption implies that certain rebates schemes

applied by dominant undertakings will always have negative effects. This presumption is however

not in line with economic assessments of rebate schemes. I will argue in further paragraphs that it

is possible for certain rebate schemes to have pro-competitive effects on the relevant market.

7. Pleas for a reform of this ‘orthodox’, form-based approach do not only stem from legal practitioners

and economists alike, but also from within the Commission. It is therefore not without reason that

the Commission published its Guidance Paper9 on its enforcement priorities in applying Article 102

TFEU in which it urged for a ‘more effects-based’ approach’ of Article 102, inter alia with regards

to rebates. In this Guidance Paper the Commission pushed for an effect-based framework through

the introduction of an ‘as-efficient-competitor’ test. The referring Court asked for clarity on the

legally binding nature of the AEC-test.

1.3 RESEARCH QUESTIONS

8. This thesis will be centered around the following research questions:

1. How are rebates assessed under current EU law?

2. Is there a need to reform the approach of rebates under Article 102 TFEU? If so, what would be

the preferred legal framework?

3. What is the relevance of the ‘As-efficient-competitor’ test after Post Danmark II?

4. What is the state of abuse of dominance in EU law after the Post Danmark II judgement?

1.4 RESEARCH METHOD

9. The main focal point of this thesis will be the state of rebates under EU law. The recent Post

Danmark II case will be used as a way to put the practices of the Commission and EU Courts into

perspective. The Post Danmark II judgement of the European Court of Justice was hailed with much

9 Guidance Paper on the Commission’s enforcement priorities in applying Article 82 of the EC Treaty to abusive

exclusionary conduct by dominant undertakings.

Page 12: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

anticipation as it offered an opportunity for the Court to adopt a different approach to standardized

rebates and to shed clarity on the status of the AEC . As the judgement is relatively new, not much

has been written as of yet on the case.

10. In my research I will apply a traditional dogmatic legal method. First, I will assess the relevant legal

sources of EU law on rebates, i.e. relevant case law and legislation. Article 102 TFEU is a relatively

ambiguous article in the sense that it does not contain any concrete definitions of key concepts10

relevant for the application of Article 102 TFEU. Ultimately, it is for the judicial branch of the

European Union to fill up these gaps in the law. Therefore a thorough assessment of the relevant

case-law of the EU Courts11 preceding Post Danmark II is justified. Next to legislation and

jurisprudence of the Courts I will also utilize the works of legal commentators who are authoritative

in the field of EU competition law.

1.5 STRUCTURE

11. In the chapter following this introduction I will first discus the historical context of Article 102

TFEU. I will argue that the issues concerning the decisional practices and judgements on Article

102 TFEU can be traced back to its inception. As the scope of this thesis is limited, I will however

not go into a detailed assessment of the history of Article 102 TFEU. By way of introduction to the

case-law, I will, in chapter 3, give an overview of the general concept of abuse of dominance under

Article 102 TFEU. I will however refrain to discussing abuse. Other concepts relevant for the

application of Article 102 TFEU like ‘dominance’ and ‘relevant market’ fall outside the scope of

this thesis and will therefore not be discussed.

12. Following chapter three, I will assess the case-law on abuse of dominance in the context of rebates

in chapter four. I will make a distinction between the on the one hand case-law where rebates have

been held to be a per se violation of Article 102 TFEU and on the other hand case-law where this

presumption was not applied. The main judgements discussed in this chapter will be the Hoffman

La Roche, Michelin I, Michelin II and British Airways cases.

13. In chapter five I will discuss the Guidance Paper released by the Commission and the therein

proposed as-efficient-competitor test. In this chapter I will also examine the AEC-test in the context

of the Post Danmark II judgement.

10 Concepts like ‘abuse’, ‘dominance’ are not defined in the article. See paragraph 40. 11 Being the General Court and the European Court of Justice.

Page 13: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

7

14. In chapter six I will consider chapters three to five to assess, from a normative point of view, whether

the legal framework concerning rebate schemes up until the Post Danmark II judgement is a

desirable one. I will also question whether there is a more effective approach open to the assessment

of rebate schemes under Article 102 TFEU.

15. In chapter seven the Post Danmark II case will be assessed and the concrete impact of the judgement

on the abuse of dominance in EU competition law will be discussed.

16. In the final chapter I will conclude this thesis by summarizing the research done throughout the

aforementioned chapters and answering the research questions mentioned above.

2.1 OVERVIEW

17. To have a better understanding of the interpretation and future of art. 102 TFEU it is important to

have a look at the historical context of art. 102 TFEU. To understand the future of a legal provision

it must be known, first and foremost, what the reason was why the provision was created in the first

place. In the case of art. 102 TFEU it has been stated numerous times in relevant literature that the

provision is founded in ‘ordoliberalism’.12 If this were the case, it would be possible to shine a light

on the, sometimes inconsistent, case law and the consequent policy of the Commission with regards

to art. 102 TFEU. Moreover, it would be able to provide the Commission with a teleological basis

for its ‘more effects-based approach’ policy. Seeing as the scope of this thesis is limited, I will, in

the following paragraphs, only refer to the essentials.

18. Gerber13 notes that, for the origins of abuse of dominance in the EU, and more specifically art. 102

TFEU, it is important to have a look at the origins of German competition law.14 The first ‘modern’

set of competition rules were enacted in post-war Germany15 with the German Law Against

12 K. PATEL, AND H., SCHWEITZER, The Historical Foundations of EU Competition Law, Oxford, Oxford

University Press, 19-20. 13 David. J. Gerber is a professor of law at the Chicago-Kent College of Law, most outspoken for correlating abuse

of dominance in the EU with the ordoliberal school. 14 D. GERBER, “ Constituionalizing the Economy: German Neoliberalism, Competition Law and the “New

Europe”, Americian Journal of Comparative law 1994. 25-84. 15 D. GERBER,, “The Future of Article 82: Dissecting the Conflict”, European Competition Law Annual 2007,

39-54.

Page 14: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

Restraints on Competition16. The authors of this act were predominantly influenced by the

ordoliberal school (also known as the ‘Freiburg School’).17 This refers to a group of legal and

economic thinkers, originating from Germany, who started, in the 1930’s, to develop a way of

structuring the German market in such a way that it could not be distorted by either public or private

influences.18 In essence, they wanted to protect the competitive process from public or private

actors.19

19. Seeing as ordoliberals were mostly concerned with outside interferences on the competitive process,

they saw competition policy and competition law as an excellent tool to protect the market.20 From

an ordoliberal point of view, competition policy serves to protect ‘economic freedom’ and therefore

not consumer welfare, which is only a desirable consequence of competition.21 The market and,

more specifically, the competitive process has to be protected from excessive economic power

which could impede on the economic freedom of other actors in the market.22 Ordoliberals therefore

strife to decentralize economic power, be it private or public.23 Important to note for the further

following paragraphs is that ordoliberals did not consider efficiency24 as a goal of competition policy

but rather a desirable consequence.

20. When assuming that the ordoliberal school had a significant impact on the implementation of Article

102 TFEU in the original treaties, the question is then in what way it impacted that article. The first

implication would be that maximizing welfare would not be a determining goal of Article 102

TFEU.25 Consequently, by striving for economic freedom certain authors have argued that an

ordoliberal competition policy could actually cause consumer harm.26

16 Geszetz gegen Wettbewerbsbeschränkungen. 17 Gerber (n15) 39. 18 P. AKMAN, The Concept of Abuse in EU Competition Law, Oxford, Hart Publishing, 2015, 55. 19 Gerber (n15) 40. 20 Ibid. 21 Akman (n18) 49. 22 A. PEACOCK, Germany's Social Market Economy: Origins and Evolution, Basingstoke, Palgrave Macmillan,

1989, 149. 23 Ibid. 68. 24 Which can be understood as productive efficiency, dynamic efficiency or allocative efficiency. 25P. AKMAN, “Searching for the Long-lost Soul of Article 82 EC”, Oxford Journal of Legal Studies 2009, 271. 26 C. AHLBORN, C and GRAVE, “Walter Eucken and Ordoliberalism: An Introduction from a Consumer Welfare

Perspective, Competition Policy International 2006, 214.

Page 15: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

9

21. Recent research27 however states that Article 102 TFEU was historically not based on ordoliberal

thoughts.28 In her research, Pinar Akman refers to the fact that this assumption is not based on a

study of the travaux préparatoires of the Treaties.29 Instead it is based on events that took place

after the Treaties were signed into law.30 31

22. Akman has put forward several convincing arguments that refute the notion of Article 102 TFEU

being rooted in ordoliberalism.32 In the following paragraphs I will summarize her main arguments

and conclude with the implications of these insights. These include the different positions of the

parties responsible with drafting the first EU competition law, most notably the drafting procedure

of the treaties of the European Coal and Steel Community and the Treaty of Rome.

23. A study of these positions is relevant when one tries to understand art. 101 and 102 TFEU. Akman

justifies this as follows:

“The positions of the delegations negotiating the Treaty establishing the European Coal

and Steel Community (ESCS Treaty) and the competition rules in that Treaty are directly

relevant for putting Articles 101 and 102 in the appropriate context also because the

former set or rules can be seen as the beginning of a tradition of competition in Europe

that is continued by the latter.”33

24. After the Second World War, American delegations pushed for anti-cartel legislation in post-war

Europe.34 It was clear for the heads of government that in order to rebuild Europe, the coal and steel

had to be integrated at the European level.35 It was Jean Monet who was the main personality

responsible for the drafting procedure.36 Therefore, it were not German ordoliberals who were

27 Akman (n25) 271. 28 Akman (n18) 50. 29 Ibid. 30 Akman, (n25) 270. 31 Most notably, in his work Law and Competition in Twentieth Centruy Europe, Gerber acknowledges that he did

not have access to the travaux préparatoires. D. GERBER, Law and Competition in Twentieth-Century Europe:

Protecting Prometheus, Oxford University Press, Oxford,1990, 270. 32 Akman, (n18) 50. 33 Akman, (n18) 69. 34 D. GERBER, Law and Competition in Twentieth-Century Europe: Protecting Prometheus, Oxford University

Press, Oxford,1990, 270. 35 Ibid, 336. 36 Ibid, 270.

Page 16: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

responsible for the drafting procedure but rather the French, who held a different opinion on

competition policy.3738 Moreover, Jean Monet and his delegation were directly supported by a group

of Americans at the American embassy, obviously influenced by an American perspective of

competition law and policy.39 The main worry of the French delegation was to cull the power of the

German coal and steel industry.40

25. Several commentators have actually noted that it were the Germans that strongly opposed the

adaption of article 6641 in the ESCS, which would prevent dominant concentrations.42 This is

important to point out as an ordoliberal competition policy would not allow a dominant undertaking

on the market. 43 The German delegation were only persuaded to accept the drafts with the prospect

of the US imposing their competition legislation. 44

26. A further level of European integration was reached with the Rome Treaty of 1 January 1958.45 A

major step in the drafting of the Rome Treaty was the coming about of the Spaak Report.46 The

discussions for the Spaak Report (named after Paul-Henri Spaak) took place in Messina on 29 and

30 May 1955 with the attendance of delegations of the original ‘six founding fathers’ of Europe,

meaning France, Italy, Germany and the Benelex countries. 47

37 Akman, (n18) 71. 38 Akman, (n25) 285. 39 Akman (n18) 71; GILLINGHAM, J. Coal, steel and the Rebirth of Europe, 1945 – 1955, Cambridge, Cambridge

University Press, 397p. 40 Akman (n18) 71. 41 This provision would have allowed the High Authority “to address to public or private enterprises, which, in

law or in fact, have or acquire on the market for of the product subject to the treaty… a dominant position which

protects them from effective competition in a substantial part of the common market, any recommendations

required to prevent the use of such position for purposes contrary to those of the present Treaty. 42Y. KARAGIANNIS, Preference Heteregeneity and Equilibrium Institutions: The Case of European Compeititon

Policy, Florence, European University Institute, 2007, not published. 43 Gerber (n34) 341. 44 Akman, (n18) 71. 45 Gerber (n34) 343. 46 Akman,(n18) 74. 47 Gerber (n34) 343.

Page 17: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

11

27. D. G Goyder notes:

“The Spaak Report is a seminal document of great importance, which comprises the most

important of the various preparatory works (travaux préparatoires) upon which the

subsequent Treaty of Rome is based” 48

28. The delegations of the original six realized that Europe needed a united front if it wanted to still play

a role on the international level. The creation of a common market was seen as a key element in

stabilizing continental Europe and avoiding future conflicts. Integral for this common market was a

common competition policy. Paragraph 55 of the Spaak Report reads as follows:

“In the final period, the elimination of trade barriers will lead to the disappearance of

the opportunities for discrimination by competing enterprises. The problem only remains

because there are enterprises which, owing to their size or specialization or the

agreements they have concluded, enjoy a monopoly position. The action against

discrimination, therefore, links up with the action that will be necessary to counteract the

formation of monopolies within the Common Market. The Treaty will have to lay down

basic rules on these points…More generally, the Treaty will have to provide means of

ensuring that monopoly situations or practices do not stand in the way of the fundamental

objectives of the Common Market. To this end, it will be necessary to prevent-

A division of markets by agreement between enterprises, since this would be tantamount

to re-establishing the compartmentalization of the market

Agreements to limit production or curb technical progress because they would run

counter to progress and productivity.

The absorption or domination of the market for a product by a single enterprise since this

would eliminate one of the essential advantages of a vast market, namely that it reconciles

the use of mass production techniques with the maintenance of competition.”

29. The first paragraph of the Spaak Report reads as follows49:

48D.G. GOYDER, EC Competition Law, Oxford, Oxford University Press, 2003, 23. 49 Intergovernmental Committee of the Messina Conference, ‘Report by the Heads of Delegations to the Foreign

Ministers’ (Spaak Report’) 21 April 1956, paragraph 1.

Page 18: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

« L’objet d’un marché commun européen doit être de créer une vaste zone de politique

économique, constituant une puissante unité de production, et permettant une expansion

continue, une stabilité accrue, un relèvement accéléré du niveau de vie, et le développement de

relations harmonieuses entre les Etats qu’il réunit.

Pour atteindre ces objectifs, une fusion des marches sépares est une nécessité absolue. C' est

elle qui permet, par la division accrue du travail, d'éliminer un gaspillage des ressources, et,

par une sécurité accrue d'approvisionnement, de renoncer à des productions poursuivies sans

considération de coût. Dans une économie en expansion, cette division du travail s’exprime

moins par un déplacement des productions existantes que par un développement d'autant plus

rapide, dans intérêt commun, des productions les plus économiques. «

30. Akman notes that from the aforementioned wording it can be deduced that the drafters were

preoccupied by the efficiency, more specifically product efficiency50 of the European

undertakings.51 The drafters were concerned about the state of producing at high prices and low

wages.52 She clarifies that this cannot follow from an ordoliberal philosophy as this

«…does not totally reflect the ordoliberal approach since the ordoliberals contemplated

the instance of workers having ‘just as strong an in the monopoly.. as the entrepreneur’

and possibly agreeing to higher prices so long as wages were increased. Thus,

ordoliberals did not see the interests of consumers as identical or always in conformity

with the interests of workers. »53

31. At the start of the negotiations, there was a provision in the Spaak report on competition that did not

allow undertakings to have a dominant position, i.e. there was a per se prohibition.54 It was actually

Müller-Armack, a German ordoliberal, who fought against having this provision in the Treaty.55 For

the German delegation, only the abuse of a dominant position was an issue, not the dominant

position in itself. 56

50 Akman (n25) 279. 51 Akman (n18) 76. 52 Ibid., 77. 53 Ibid. 54 Ibid., 81. 55 Ibid., 82. 56 Ibid., 83.

Page 19: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

13

32. Based on the foregoing, it is possible to rebut the assumption that art. 102 TFEU was founded in

ordoliberalism. In the end, the wording of art. 102 TFEU57 and the case law do not prohibit a

undertaking of having a dominant position, as it will only be an abuse of that dominant position that

would be contrary to art. 102 TFEU.58 Moreover, there was a clear absence of merger control in the

original treaties, which indicates that the drafters were not contrary to the idea of dominance per

se.59 Pinar Akman also refers to the importance of efficiency for the drafters of the original Treaties:

“This signifies the most important difference between the intent behind Article 102 and

ordoliberalism: whereas efficiency was only a derived result of competition for

ordoliberals, it was an aim for the drafters of the Treaty. Article 102 TFEU departs from

classic ordoliberalism significantly by not prohibiting a dominant position itself, but only

its abuse.”60

33. As stated earlier, the drafters did not prohibit an undertaking to hold a dominant position, only the

abuse of a dominant position was seen as contrary to the competitive structure of the market. 61

Harming competitors was not seen as a major threat to the competitive process by the drafters.62

They were more worried, however, about the harm done to customers. 63 The Court amended this,

however, in their Continental Can case.64 The fact that article 102 TFEU originally did not prohibit

exclusionary abuse has also been confirmed by early commentators of Article 86 EC (now Article

102 TFEU.65

34. Based on the foregoing, it is clear that there is validity with regards to the statement that Article 102

TFEU is, in fact not, based on an ordoliberal philosophy. This is mostly based on the concern of the

drafters for efficient undertakings, whether they are dominant or not.66 Also, they were more

57 See also the french and german text which speak of missbrauchverbot e.g. 58 Ibid., 96. 59 Akman (n25), 271. 60 Akman (n18), 96. 61 Paragraph 68. 62 Akman (n18), 97. 63 Akman (n25), 271. 64 See paragraph 61 and following. 65 R. JOLLIET, Monopolization and Abuse of Dominant Position: A Comparative Study of the American and

European Approaches to the Control of Economic Power, Michigan, Faculté de droit, 1970, 250. 66 Akman (n25), 294.

Page 20: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

preoccupied with protecting the customer of the dominant undertaking rather than the competitors.67

This had to lead to the improvement of living of all European citizens, consumers and producers

alike. This could imply that a ‘total welfare’ standard instead of a ‘consumer welfare’ standard is in

order.68 According to Pinar Akman, the main argument in support of this is the fact that Article 102

TFEU does not have a similar provision as Article 101 (3) TFEU. Namely, there is no provision in

Article 102 TFEU that allows a dominant undertaking guilty of abusive conduct to escape

prosecution when it can prove that benefits are being passed on to consumers.69

35. This understanding is of importance for the interpretation of Article 102 TFEU and of the subsequent

policy of the Commission.70 The concrete implication would be that the Commission and the Court

can take efficiencies into account when assessing abuse under Article 102 TFEU.71

36. In the case law of Article 102 TFEU, however, the Court has been reluctant to take efficiencies into

account with regards to rebate schemes. It is clear that the main worry of the Court is to protect the

access of the competitors to the market and their economic freedom.72 In their assessment there is

little to no attention being given to efficiencies, so therefore it can be concluded that the Court does

not hold efficiency as an object or value in itself.73

37. Rousseva therefore notes that the Court is, contrary to the drafters of the Treaties, to a large extent

influenced by the ordoliberal school in its judgements concerning Article 102 TFEU. A good

example of this is the reoccurring notion74 of ‘special responsibility’ of dominant undertakings in

the market, which was also referred to in the Post Danmark II75 case.

67 Ibid., 296. 68 Ibid., 300. 69 Akman (n18), 100. 70 Akman (n25), 294. 71 Akman (n18), 97. 72 E. ROUSSEVA, Rethinking Exclusionary Abuses in EU Competition Law, Oxford, Hart Publishing, 173. 73 Ibid. 74 Michelin I, C-322/81, ECLI:EU:C:1983:313, paragraph 71 (hereafter ‘Michelin I’); Irish Sugar, T-228/97,

ECLI:EU:T:1999:246, paragraph 111. 75 Post Danmark II, C-23/14, ECLI:EU:C:2015:651, paragraph 71, (hereafter ‘Post Danmark II).

Page 21: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

15

2.2 SUMMARY CONCLUSION

38. In this chapter I have tried to put Article 102 TFEU into its historical context. This is necessary as

there is a gap between the origins and intent of Article 102 TFEU and how it is applied by the EU

institutions in the present day legal practice. I have argued, based on recent research, that Article

102 TFEU is not based on an ordoliberal philosophy. The fact that dominance of undertakings as

such is not illegal under the EU treaties and the preoccupation of the drafters with efficiencies serve

as the main arguments.76 These insights lead to a basis for further reform of Article 102 by the

European Commission and the EU Courts, which as I will indicate in the following chapters is sorely

needed.

3.1 GENERAL

39. Article 102 TFEU states the following:

Any abuse by one or more undertakings of a dominant position within the internal market

or in a substantial part of it shall be prohibited as incompatible with the internal market

in so far as it may affect trade between Member States. Such abuse may, in particular,

consist in:

(a) directly or indirectly imposing unfair purchase or selling prices or other unfair

trading conditions;

(b) limiting production, markets or technical development to the prejudice of consumers;

(c) applying dissimilar conditions to equivalent transactions with other trading parties,

thereby placing them at a competitive disadvantage;

(d) making the conclusion of contracts subject to acceptance by the other parties of

supplementary obligations which, by their nature or according to commercial usage,

have no connection with the subject of such contracts.

76 Akman (n18), 103.

Page 22: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

40. Whereas Article 101 TFEU targets agreements between undertakings that can or could affect the

competitive structure of the the internal market, Article 102 focuses on undertakings which hold a

dominant position on a certain relevant market. As I have mentioned in the introduction77, one of

the goals of the European Union is to establish an internal market. A workable competition policy

forms an integral part of the means to achieve this goal. Dominant undertakings have the means to

disturb competition on the internal market by abusing their dominance.

41. Article 102 TFEU thus requires five criteria for its application, being78:

one or more undertaking;

that has/have a dominant position;

in the internal market;

an abuse of the dominant position;

in a relevant market.

42. In EU competition law the dominant position of an undertaking as such is not illegal. 79 Relevant

for the application of Article 102 TFEU therefore is the abuse of that dominant position. Article 102

TFEU fails however to provide the reader with a definition of abuse. 80

43. Due to the lack of a workable definition, it can be difficult for undertakings to estimate when its

conduct will be abusive. Bellamy and Child note81 several factors that the undertaking can take into

account, such as:

“how far the conduct in issue is of a kind that is plainly restrictive of competition or unfair;

how far the conduct is normal industry practice;

how far competition on the market is already weakened by the dominance;

the effect, direct and indirect, of the conduct on competitors or customer;

77 See paragraph 1 and following. 78 Michelin I (n75), paragraph 30. 79 Ibid, paragraph 57; Merci convenzionali porto di Genova SpA v Siderurgica Gabrielli SpA., Case C-179/90,

ECLI:EU:C:1991:464, para 16; GlaxoSmithKline Services and Others v Commission and Others, C-501/06,

ECLI:EU:C:2009:610, paragraph 35.

para 35. 80 R. O’DONOGHUE and J. PADILLA, The Law and Economics of Article 102 TFEU, Oxford, Hart Publishing,

2013, 214. 81 V. ROSE, and D. BAILEY, European Union Law of Competition, Oxford, Oxford University Press, 717.

Page 23: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

17

whether the intention of the dominant firm is exclusionary or constitute a legitimate

response to competition;

whether the conduct in issue is “proportional” to any legitimate interest which is being

pursued;

the connection between the conduct and the general principle of the Treaty, especially the

elimination of national boundaries and the absence of discrimination between nationals of

different Member States.”

44. In paragraph 91 of the Hoffmann-La Roche82 case the Court defined the concept of abuse as follows:

“The concept of abuse is an objective concept relating to the behavior of an undertaking

in a dominant position which I such a to influence the structure of a market where, as a

result of the very presence of the undertaking in question, the degree of competition is

weakened and which, through recourse to methods different from those which condition

normal competition in products or services on the basis of the transactions of commercial

operators, has the effect of hindering the maintenance of the degree of competition still

existing in the market or the growth of that competition.”

45. The fact that abuse is an ‘objective concept’ does not, according to Advocate General Kirschner83,

imply that “the use of the economic power bestowed by the dominant position is the means whereby

abuse has been brought about”.84

82 Hoffman/La Roche, C-85/76, ECLI:EU:C:1979:36. (hereafter ‘Hoffmann La Roche’). 83 Tetra Pak International SA v Commission of the European Communities, Case T-83/91 ECLI:EU:T:1994:246,

Opinion of Advocate Kirschner. 84 Tetra Pak International SA v Commission of the European Communities, Case T-83/91 ECLI:EU:T:1994:246,

Opinion of Advocate Kirschner, paragraph 64.

Page 24: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

3.2 OBJECTIVE OF ARTICLE 102 TFEU

46. In the Post Danmark85 case the Court added a consumer dimension to this definition86, namely:

“In that regard, it is also to be borne in mind that Article 102 applies, in particular, to

the conduct of a dominant undertaking that, through recourse to methods different from

those governing normal competition on the basis of the performance of commercial

operators, has the effect, to the detriment of consumers, of hindering the maintenance of

the degree of competition existing in the market or the growth of that competition (see to

that effect, AKZO v Commission, paragraph 69; France Télécom v

Commission…paragraphs 104 and 105; and Case-280/08 P Deutsche Telekom v

Commission…paras 174, 176 and 180 and case-law cited).”87

With the aforementioned paragraph, the Court affirmed that consumer welfare is

ultimately the goal of abuse of dominance under Article 102 TFEU. This is also said

explicitly by the Court in paragraph 20:

“ It is apparent from case-law that Article 82 EC covers not only those practices that

directly cause harm to consumers but also practices that cause consumers harm through

their impact on competition (see Case C-52/09 TeliaSonera Sverige [2011] ECR I-527,

paragraph 24 and case-law cited). It is in the latter sense that the expression

‘exclusionary abuse’ appearing in the questions referred is to be understood.”88

47. With this paragraph the Court seemed to have corrected the Intel judgment by the General Court

with regards to the goal of Article 102 TFEU. In paragraph 77 the General Court stated the

following:

Such exclusivity rebates, when applied by an undertaking in a dominant position, are

incompatible with the objective of undistorted competition within the common market,

because they are not based — save in exceptional circumstances — on an economic

transaction which justifies this burden or benefit but are designed to remove or restrict

85 Post Danmark I, C-209/10, ECLI:EU:C:2012:172. (hereafter ‘Post Danmark I). 86 A. JONES and B. SUFRIN, EU Competition Law, Oxford, Oxford University Press, 2014, 373. 87 Post Danmark I (n86), paragraph 24. 88 Ibid., paragraph 20.

Page 25: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

19

the purchaser’s freedom to choose his sources of supply and to deny other producers

access to the market (see, to that effect, Hoffmann-La Roche, paragraph 71 above,

paragraph 90, and Case T-155/06 Tomra, paragraph 72 above, paragraph 209). Such

rebates are designed, through the grant of a financial advantage, to prevent customers

from obtaining their supplies from competing producers (Hoffmann-La Roche,

paragraph 71 above, paragraph 90, and Case T-155/06 Tomra, paragraph 72 above,

paragraph 210).89

This was followed up by paragraph 105:

“Lastly, the Court would point out that, a fortiori, the Commission is not required to

prove either direct damage to consumers or a causal link between such damage and the

practices at issue in the contested decision. It is apparent from the case-law that

Article 82 EC is aimed not only at practices which may cause damage to consumers

directly, but also at those which are detrimental to them through their impact on an

effective competition structure (Case C-95/04 P British Airways, paragraph 74 above,

paragraph 106).”90

48. This correction done by the Court, sitting in Grand Chamber, was welcoming as this brought the

goal of Article 102 closer to the objective of Article 101 TFEU. Seeing as Article 101(3) TFEU

allows for efficiencies to be passed onto consumers through otherwise anti-competitive practices, it

is clear that consumer welfare is the objective of Article 101 TFEU. The competitive structure is

affected but ultimately the consumer benefits from the practice, therefore the agreement or practice

in question will be allowed.91

49. A de facto Article 102(3) TFEU provision was introduced in the Post Danmark I judgment by the

Court. This is clear from paragraphs 40 to 42 of the judgment. Paragraph 41 states:

“In particular, such an undertaking may demonstrate, for that purpose, either that its

conduct is objectively necessary (see, to that effect, Case 311/84 CBEM [1985]

89 Ibid., paragraph 77. 90 Ibid., paragraph 105. 91 L. PEEPERKORN., “Conditional pricing: Why the General Court is wrong in Intel and what the Court of Justice

can do to rebalance the assessment of rebates”, Concurrences Review 2015, 47.

Page 26: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

ECR 3261, paragraph 27), or that the exclusionary effect produced may be

counterbalanced, outweighed even, by advantages in terms of efficiency that also benefit

consumers (Case C-95/04 P British Airways v. Commission [2007] ECR I-2331,

paragraph 86, and TeliaSonera Sverige, paragraph 76). “92

50. Peeperkorn argues that this is a positive development as it gives orientation to competition policy.93

This cannot be expected from the goal of preserving the competitive structure of the market as it

lacks a certain benchmark. This insight is important for later chapters as this also justifies a

modernized approach of Article 102 involving an effects based framework.

51. In its Guidance Paper the Commission also confirmed that consumer welfare is the ultimate goal of

Article 102 TFEU:

“The aim of the Commission's enforcement activity in relation to exclusionary conduct is

to ensure that dominant undertakings do not impair effective competition by foreclosing

their competitors in an anti-competitive way, thus having an adverse impact on consumer

welfare..”94

52. As a side-remark I would like to end this part with a reference to the stance of Advocate General

Juliane Kokott. Her stance on this point is not without relevance as she was also appointed as

Advocate General to deliver the opinion in the Post Danmark II case. In her opinion in the British

Airways case she stated:

“The starting-point here must be the protective purpose of Article 82 EC. The provision

forms part of a system designed to protect competition within the internal market from

distortions (Article 3(1)(g) EC). Accordingly, Article 82 EC, like the other competition

rules of the Treaty, is not designed only or primarily to protect the immediate interests of

individual competitors or consumers, but to protect the structure of the market and thus

competition as such (as an institution), which has already been weakened by the presence

of the dominant undertaking on the market. 71 In this way, consumers are also indirectly

92 Post Danmark I (n86), paragraph 41. 93 Peeperkorn (n92) 48. 94 Guidance on the Commission’s Enforcement Priorities in Applying Article 82 of the EC Treaty to Abusive

Exclusionary Conduct by Dominant Undertakings, 2009, OJ C45/2, paragraph 19. (hereafter ‘Guidance Paper’).

Page 27: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

21

protected. 72 Because where competition as such is damaged, disadvantages for

consumers are also to be feared.”95

53. This paragraph is a good example of how ordoliberalism still has its adherents in the ranks of the

EU Courts. The Advocate-General is clearly influenced by this philosophy with regards to EU

competition law. This consideration will provide some context when her opinion in the Post

Danmark II case is discussed in later chapters.

3.3 SPECIAL RESPONSIBILITY

54. In its case-law concerning Article 102 TFEU, the Court has developed the concept of ‘special

responsibility’.

55. This concept was first clarified by the Court in the Michelin I96 case. In paragraph 57 the Court

stated that:

“A finding that an undertaking has a dominant position is not in itself a recrimination

but simply means that, irrespective of the reasons for which it has such a position, the

undertaking concerned has a special responsibility not to allow its conduct to impair

genuine undistorted competition on the internal market.”97

56. This concepts states that seeing as dominant undertakings have a big hold on the market they are in,

they are not allowed to behave in the same way as a non-dominant undertaking. It is as if the Court

wants to chastise the dominant position in itself, even though it has held several times in its case law

that dominance is not contrary to Article 102 TFEU98. Rousseva notes that it has to be seen as ‘an

axiomatic rule, enabling prohibition on the basis of dominance’.99

95 British Airways, C-95/04, ECLI:EU:C:2007:166, Opinion of Advocate-General Kokott. 96 Michelin I (n75). 97 Ibid, paragraph 57. 98 Vereist verwijzing. 99 E, ROUSSEVA “Modernizing By Eradicating: How the Commission's New Approach to Article 81 Ec

Dispenses with the Need to Apply Article 82 EC to Vertical Restraints”, Common Market Law Review 2005, 59

Page 28: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

57. Nazzini notes that this concept does not further add to the Hoffmann-La Roche concept of abuse.100

Instead, it adds to the notion that only dominant undertakings are liable to be prosecuted under

Article 102 TFEU. It is for this reason not possible, based on the concept of ‘special responsibility’,

to distill further legal implications for dominant undertakings.101 The Court was consequently not

trying to lay down a test for abuse.102

58. In several cases following the Michelin I case, including Post Danmark II103, the Court has affirmed

this concept in its case law.104 Rather than being a legal doctrine, it is a concept whereby the Court

wants to clarify that the extent of the application of Article 102 is dependent on the facts of each

case.105106 The concrete implications of this ‘special responsibility’ for dominant undertakings thus

remain vague at best.

3.4 EXCLUSIONAIRY VS. EXPLOITATIVE ABUSES

59. The Conintental Can107 case was a pioneering case for the development and interpretation of abuse

under Article 102 TFEU.108 First, in paragraph 26109 of the Contintental Can case, the Court stated

that Article 102 TFEU does not entail an exhaustive list of illicit conduct by a dominant

undertaking.110 In the case law there are several examples of this.111 Secondly, the Court clarified

that not only is exploitative conduct contrary to art. 102 TFEU, exclusionary conduct is also

prohibited. Since the Continental Can case, an abuse can be categorized as either one of two illegal

100 NAZINNI, R., The Foundations of European Union Competition Law, Oxford, Oxford University Press, 2011,

175. 101 Ibid. 102 Ibid., 174. 103 See paragraph 123. 104 Irish Sugar, T-228/97, ECLI:EU:T:1999:246, paragraph 112. , Compagnie Maritime Belge, C-95/04,

ECLI:EU:C:2007:166, paragraph 37. 105 Nazinni (n101) 175. 106 Compagnie Maritime Belge, C-95/04, ECLI:EU:C:2007:166, paragraph 114: “the actual scope of the special

responsibility imposed on a dominant undertaking must be considered in the light of the specific circumstances of

each case which show that competition has been weakened. “ 107 Continental Can, Case 6-72, ECLI:EU:C:1973:22. (hereafter ‘Continental Can’). 108 Jones and Suffrin (n87) 370. 109 Continental Can (n111) paragraph 26. 110 Ibid. 26-27. 111 British Airways, C-95/04, ECLI:EU:C:2007:166 paragraph 57 – 58, Deutsche Telekom AG v European

Commission. C-280/08, ECLI:EU:C:2010:603. paragraph 173.

Page 29: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

23

conducts. They are not mutually exclusive so it is possible that certain conduct can be seen as both

exclusionary and exploitative in nature.112

60. A dominant undertaking cannot only affect the consumers due to direct exploitative conduct but it

could also affect consumers indirectly by affecting the normal workings of the market. The Court

stated113:

“As may further be seen from letters (c) and (d) of Article 86 (now article 102 TFEU) (2), the

provision is not only aimed at practices which may cause damage to consumers directly, but

also at those which are detrimental to them through their impact on an effective competition

structure, such as is mentioned in Article 3 (f) of the Treaty (now article 3 (b) TFEU). Abuse

may therefore occur if an undertaking in a dominant position strengthen such position in such

a way that the degree of dominance reached substantially fetters competition, i.e., that only

undertakings remain in the market whose behavior depends on the dominant one.”

The Court thus accepted exclusionary abuse to fall under Article 102 because of the implications

for consumers.114

61. O’Donoghue and Padilla define exploitative abuse as: “pricing and other practices that result in a

direct loss of consumer welfare”.115 Predatory pricing, as mentioned in Article 102 (a) TFEU,

implemented by a dominant undertaking is, inter alia, a good example of an exclusionary abuse.116

Exclusionary abuse117 can be defined118 as ‘anti-competitive’ abuses as they are abuses that harm

the competitive structure of the market.119 Exclusionary abuses generally fall under Article 102 (b)

TFEU.120

112 Jones and Suffrin (n87) 372. 113 Continental Can (n111) paragraph 30. 114 Jones and Suffrin (n87) 370. 115 O’Donoghue & Padilla (n81) 241. 116 V. ROSE, and, D. BAILEY, European Union Law of Competition, Oxford, Oxford University Press, 721. 117 E.g. loyalty rebates. 118 The extent of this definition is still highly debated amongst some commentators, see for example, A EZRACHI,

Article 82 EC: Reflections on its Recent Evolution, Oxford, Hart Pubishing, 2009,232p.;I. VAN BAEL and J.F.

BELLIS,, Competition Law of the European of the European Community, Alphen aan Den Rijn, Kluwer Law

International, 717. 119I. VAN BAEL and J.F. BELLIS,, Competition Law of the European of the European Community, Alphen aan

Den Rijn, Kluwer Law International, 904. 120 O’Donoghue & Padilla (n81) 293.

Page 30: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

3.5 SUMMARY CONCLUSION

62. The aim of this chapter was to flesh out the concept of abuse under Article 102 TFEU. When an

undertaking has acted contrary to Article 102 TFEU this can have far reaching consequences, as

indicated in the introduction121. It is therefore unfortunate that the article in question is at times

ambiguous. The EU courts have had to clarify the extent of the article in numerous seminal

judgements. One of these essential judgements was the Hoffmann La Roche judgement where the

Court of Justice gave guidance on the concept of abuse of dominance in paragraphs 90122 and 91123.

It has to be seen as an objective concept which leaves no room for intent or fault. In the Continental

Can case the Court made the rough distinction between two types of categories of abusive conduct.

The one being exploitative conduct, the other exclusionary conduct. These distinctions have no real

practical implications as a certain type of conduct can be both exploitative and exclusionary at the

same time. Since the Post Danmark I judgement, the Court has affirmed that the main goal of Article

102 TFEU is to protect consumers from harm and thus to increase consumer welfare. This is

important as this approach is similar to the one applied in Article 101(3) TFEU. Since the Michelin

I judgement the Court has added that dominant undertakings have a ‘special responsibilty’ when

interacting with other actors of the market. This concept is at best vague and thus not add any legal

implications for dominant undertakings.

121 Verwijzing naar introduction. 122 Hoffmann La Roche (n83) paragraph 90. 123 Ibid. paragraph 91.

Page 31: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

25

Page 32: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

63. To conclude, within the factual context of the Hoffmann La Roche case, the reasoning of the Court

might have been justified. Applying the same reasoning in subsequent cases, however, was not.

64. The presumed legality of quantity rebates and the per se illegality of loyalty rebates could have

caused dominant undertakings in following cases to mask their rebates as a quantity rebate. One

way to accomplish this would have been to estimate the total sales of a dominant undertakings

product by a customer and to grant a rebate when the estimated sales have been reached. 124 In the

Deutsche Post125 case the Commission said that this would not pass the Hoffmann La Roche test as:

“In Hoffmann-La Roche, the Court of justice drew the following distinction between ‘fidelity

rebates’ and quantity rebates’:

- The quantity rebate is linked exclusively to the volume of purchases form the producer

concerned. It is calculated on the basis of quantities fixed objectively and applicable to all

possible purchasers,

- The fidelity rebate is linked, not to a specific quantity, but to the customer’s requirements or a

large proportion thereof. The reduction is granted ‘in return’ for the exclusivity in satisfying

the demand. “126

In the Deutsche Post case the Commission stated that the conduct of the dominant undertaking could

be seen as a loyalty rebate, and therefore illegal.127

65. In paragraph 90 of its judgement, the Court distinguished loyalty rebates from quantity rebates based

on the assumption that the only incentive for offering loyalty rebates to ones customers would be

the exclusion of its competitors (much like exclusive dealing obligations). Quantity rebates,

124 Jones & Suffrin (n87) 458. 125 Deutsche Post, C-399/08, ECLI:EU:C:2010:48. 126 Deutsche Post (I) [2001] OJ L 125/27. Decision Commission. 127 Verwijzing in die commission decision.

Page 33: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

27

however, could serve legitimate business interests if they were solely based on the volume of

purchases.128

66. The Post Danmark II case is another step in the evolution of settled case law on art. 102 TFEU with

regards to rebates. Seeing as the Court has reaffirmed earlier case law in its Post Danmark II

judgement, it will be necessary to have a closer look at the relevant cases preceding the Post

Danmark II judgement. From this overview I will try to indicate that there are two lines of case law

in the judgements of the Court with regards to art. 102 TFEU. One the one hand you have cases

where the conduct is presumed to be illegal per se as a qualified rule, while on the other hand there

are practices that have to pass a certain standard in order to be found contrary to Article 102

TFEU.129 Colomo notes that predatory pricing and loyalty rebates are a good example of the former,

whereas margin squeezing is an example of the latter.130 De facto they introduce an abuse by object

and an abuse by effect approach to Article 102 TFEU.

67. With regards to the per se illegal conduct, anti-competitive effects are assumed.131 Whereas conduct

under Article 102 TFEU that is not per se illegal, anti-competitive effects will have to be shown in

order for the conduct to be illegal. 132

4.1 PER SE ILLEGAL REBATE SCHEMES

4.1.1 Presumption of illegality of loyalty rebates or the by object prohibition

68. The term loyalty rebates or exclusivity rebates was first used in the seminal Hoffmann La Roche133

case where the Court defined term as follows:

128 P. COLOMO, “Intel and Article 102 TFEU Case Law: Making Sense of a Perpetual Controversy”, LSE Working

Papers 28. 129 Colomo (n133) 4. 130 Ibid., 13. 131 See paragraph 78 and following. 132 Ibid. 133 Hoffmann La Roche (n83).

Page 34: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

“…discounts conditional on the customer’s obtaining all or most of its require

requirements – whether the quantity of its purchases be large or small – from the

undertaking in a dominant position”134

69. Another definition was given in the OECD Report of 4 February 2003135 where it was defined as:

“pricing structures offering lower prices in return for a buyer’s agreed or de facto

commitment to source a large and/or increasing share of his requirements with the

discounter”.

According to this definition, a loyalty rebate does not necessarily have to be concluded in a contract.

70. The Hoffmann La Roche judgement forms the basis for following case law where the Court held

that loyalty rebates are per se illegal. This line of case law was confirmed in later judgements, which

will be discussed in later paragraphs.

71. The Suiker Unie136 case formed the legal groundwork for the Hoffmann La Roche case. In the Suiker

Unie judgement the Court had to assess the legality of exclusive dealing arrangements under Article

102. The Court found these to be illegal as they ‘were likely to limit markets to the prejudice of

consumers within the meaning of Article 86 (now Article 102 TFEU)¸ because it gave other

producers and especially those having their places of business in other Member States no chance

or restricted their opportunities of competing with sugar sold by SZV (being the dominant

undertaking in the Suiker Unie case).”137

72. With regards to loyalty rebates the Court stated, in the Hoffmann La Roche case, the following in

paragraph 89138:

“An undertaking which is in a dominant position on a market and ties purchasers, even

if it does so at their request, by an obligation or promise on their part to obtain all or

most of their requirements exclusively from the said undertaking abuses its dominant

134 Ibid., paragraph 89. 135 Loyalty and fidelity discounts and rebates, OECD report of 4 February 2003, DAFEE COMP (2002) 21), p. 7. 136 Suiker Unie, C-40/73, ECLI:EU:C:1975:174. 137 Suiker Unie, C-40/73, ECLI:EU:C:1975:174, paragraph 526. 138 Hoffmann La Roche (n83) paragraph 89.

Page 35: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

29

position within the meaning of Article 86 of the Treaty (now art. 102 TFEU), whether the

obligation in question is stipulated without further qualification or whether it is

undertaking in consideration of the grant of a rebate.

The same applies if the said undertaking, without tying the purchases by a formal

obligation, applies, either under terms of agreements concluded with these purchasers or

unilaterally, a system of fidelity rebates, that is to say discounts conditional on the

customer’s obtaining all or most of its requirements - whether the quantity of its

purchases be large or small – from the undertaking in a dominant position”139

73. It is important to see the cases involving loyalty rebates in their respective factual context, seeing as

several commentators have noted that a too formal approach of loyalty rebates under Article 102

TFEU originated from Courts applying case-law without considering the relevant facts of those

cases and applying previous case law in factually different contexts.140

74. For a full and in depth overview of the facts in the Hoffmann La Roche case, I refer to the decision

of the Commission.141 The Hoffmann La Roche case concerned a dominant producer of vitamins

(Hoffmann La Roche, hereafter ‘HLR’) which had concluded exclusivity contracts with several of

its largest customers. At the time when the facts took place, HLR was one of the biggest vitamin

producers in the world.

75. The contracts between HLR and its customers held the following features142:

Purchasers were to obtain most or all of their vitamin requirements in the form of vitamins

from HLR;

HLR paid a rebate each year or every six months that was calculated on total purchases to

those customers who have obtained all or most of their requirements form HLR. This

involved a rebate which varied between 1% and 5% ;

139 Hoffmann La Roche (n83) paragraph 89. 140 Jones & Suffrin (n87) 458. 141 Vitamins, OJ 1976 L223/27. 142 Hoffmann La Roche (n87) paragraph 1.

Page 36: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

in the contracts there was a so called ‘English clause’, which provided that customers were

to inform Roche if any ‘reputable ‘manufacturer charged a price lower than was charged by

HLR. If HLR did not lower its price to that level, customers were free to obtain supplies

from the other manufacturer without losing the fidelity rebate on their purchases from HLR.

Most of these contracts were concluded for an indefinite period of time, with some contracts

including a tacit renewal of the contracts after the agreed upon time had expired.143 The Court noted

that this indicated that HLR had the intention of building a long lasting trade relationship with its

customers. 144

76. Paragraph 90145of the judgement is one of the more important paragraphs of the judgement as it

differentiates loyalty rebates from quantity rebates. This paragraph was also repeated in several

other cases.146 Following the Hoffman La Roche case, the Court has systematically held147 that

quantity rebates, are by a way of a qualified rule, allowed under Article 102 TFEU.

Paragraph 90 states the following:

“Obligations of this kind to obtain supplies exclusively from a particular undertaking,

whether or not they are in consideration of rebates or of the granting of fidelity rebates

intended to give the purchaser an incentive to obtain his supplies exclusively from the

undertaking in a dominant position, are incompatible with the objective of undistorted

competition within the Common Market, because – unless there are exceptional

circumstances which may make an agreement between undertakings in the context of

Article 85 and in particular of paragraph (3) of that article, permissible, they are not

based on an economic transaction which justifies this burden or benefit but are designed

to deprive the purchaser of or restrict his possible choices of sources of supply and to

deny other producers access to the market.

143 Ibid., paragraph 86. 144 Ibid. 145 Hoffmann La Roche (n87) paragraph 90. 146 Irish Sugar, T-228/97, ECLI:EU:T:1999:246. 7, paragraph 114, Michelin I, C-322/81, ECLI:EU:C:1983:313.,

paragraph 73. 147 British Airways, C-95/04, ECLI:EU:C:2007:166., paragraph 84, BPB Industries, T-65/89 ,

ECLI:EU:T:1993:31, paragraph 68.

Page 37: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

31

The fidelity rebate, unlike quantity rebates exclusively linked with the volume of

purchases from the producer concerned, is designed through the grant of a financial

advantage to prevent customers from obtaining their supplies from competing producers.

Furthermore the effect of fidelity rebates is to apply dissimilar conditions to equivalent

transactions with other trading parties in that two purchasers pay a different price for

the same quantity of the same product depending on whether they obtain their supplies

exclusively from the undertaking in a dominant position or have several sources of supply.

Finally these practices by an undertaking in a dominant potion and especially on an

expanding market tend to consolidate this position by means of a form of competition

which is not based on the transactions effected and is therefore distorted.”148

77. To conclude, within the factual context of the Hoffmann La Roche case, the reasoning of the Court

might have been justified.149 Applying the same reasoning in subsequent cases, however, was not.

78. The presumed legality of quantity rebates and the per se illegality of loyalty rebates could have

caused dominant undertakings in following cases to mask their rebates as a quantity rebate. One

way to accomplish this would have been to estimate the total sales of a dominant undertakings

product by a customer and to grant a rebate when the estimated sales have been reached. 150 In the

Deutsche Post151 case the Commission said that this would not pass the Hoffmann La Roche test as:

“In Hoffmann-La Roche, the Court of justice drew the following distinction between

‘fidelity rebates’ and quantity rebates’:

The quantity rebate is linked exclusively to the volume of purchases form the producer

concerned. It is calculated on the basis of quantities fixed objectively and applicable to

all possible purchasers,

The fidelity rebate is linked, not to a specific quantity, but to the customer’s requirements

or a large proportion thereof. The reduction is granted ‘in return’ for the exclusivity in

satisfying the demand. “152

148 Hoffmann La Roche (n83) paragraph 90. 149 Cololmo (n133) 21. 150 Jones& Suffrin (n87) 458. 151 Deutsche Post, C-399/08, ECLI:EU:C:2010:48. 152 Deutsche Post, C-399/08, ECLI:EU:C:2010:48, OJ 2002 L 247, p. 27, paragraph 33.

Page 38: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

In the Deutsche Post case the Commission stated that the conduct of the dominant undertaking could

be seen as a loyalty rebate, and therefore illegal.153

79. In paragraph 90 of its Hoffmann La Roche judgement, the Court distinguished loyalty rebates from

quantity rebates based on the assumption that the only incentive for offering loyalty rebates to ones

customers would be the exclusion of its competitors (much like exclusive dealing obligations).

Quantity rebates, however, could serve legitimate business interests if they were solely based on the

volume of purchases.154

4.1.2 Anti-competitive vs. pro-competitive effects of loyalty rebates

80. The assumed negative effects of fidelity rebates are the following155:

they deprive the purchasers of the ability to freely choose sources of supply;

they bar competitors from accessing the market;

they strengthen the dominant position of the supplier.

81. The Court treats loyalty rebates in the same manner as exclusive purchasing obligations as it is

assumed that they will have the same negative effects on competitors.156 Therefore once a rebate

has the characteristics of a loyalty rebate and can be defined as such, they “will be past

redemption”.157

82. What is clear from the facts in the Hoffmann La Roche case, is that the dominant undertaking, being

HLR, had set up a system that was comparable to exclusive buying contracts. As I have mentioned

earlier, it is unfortunate that the Court has repeated the Hoffmann La Roche reasoning in subsequent

cases158 where it did not involve rebates linked to exclusive dealing requirements. The Court has

153 Verwijzing in die commission decision. 154 Cololmo (n133) 28 155 Rousseva (n73) 177. 156 Jones& Suffrin (n87) 458. 157 Rousseva (n73) 175. 158BPB Industries, T-65/89 ,ECLI:EU:T:1993:31; Irish Sugar, T-228/97, ECLI:EU:T:1999:246.; Michelin I,

C-322/81, ECLI:EU:C:1983:313.

Page 39: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

33

since then always held in its case law159 that exclusive purchasing contracts in return for loyalty

rebates are illegal. This was also the case in the Suiker Unie judgement.160

83. With regards to loyalty rebates, the Court and the Commission have, for a long time, upheld a

formalistic approach in their assessment of rebates under Article 102 TFEU. This approach has been

widely criticized161 in legal doctrine as it is not based on a convincing economic argumentation.

84. What is thus unfortunate, is that the Court stated that the loyalty rebates were not based on a so

called ‘economic transaction’ even though it refused to even analyze the possible effects of such a

rebate on, not only competitors, but also on consumers.162

85. In the BPB Industries163 case the General Court had to deliver a judgement on a Commission

decision prohibiting a system implemented by BPB Industries Inc. rewarding the loyalty of several

large customers who acquired most their purchases from BPB Industries Inc. BPB Industries

rewarded its customers with promotional expenses and contributed to advertising. In its judgement

the General Court refrained from analyzing the possible effects of the acclaimed abuse by stating

that:

“…those considerations, which apply in a normal competitive market situation, cannot

be unreservedly accepted in the case of a market where, precisely because of the

dominant position of one of the economic operators, competition is already restricted. An

undertaking in a dominant position has a special responsibility no to allow its conduct to

impair genuine undistorted competition in the common market.“164

159 Irish Sugar, T-228/97, ECLI:EU:T:1999:246, paragraph198. BPB Industries, T-65/89

,ECLI:EU:T:1993:31, paragraph 67. 160 Suiker Unie, C-40/73, ECLI:EU:C:1975:174. 161 E. ROUSSEVA, “Modernizing By Eradicating: How the Commission's New Approach to Article 81 Ec

Dispenses with the Need to Apply Article 82 Ec to Vertical Restraints”, Common Market Law Review 2005, 1 L.

GORMSEN, “Article 82 EC: Where Are We Coming From and Where Are We Going To?”, The Competition

Law Review 2006, 4-26.

J. TEMPLE LANG,, “How Can The Problems of Exclusionary Abuses under Article 102 TFEU be

Resolved?”, ELRev 2012, 141-142; Jones& Suffrin (n87) 382. 162 Jones& Suffrin (n87) 458. 163 BPB Industries, T-65/89 ,ECLI:EU:T:1993:31. 164 BPB Industries, T-65/89 ,ECLI:EU:T:1993:31, paragraph 67.

Page 40: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

Accordingly, the General Court referred to this notion of ‘special responsibility’165 to avoid

assessing the effects of the actual conduct.166 BPB had a dominant position on the relevant market

and therefore the competitive structure was already affected. The fact that BPB concluded the

aforementioned agreements with its customers was enough to from an obstacle for ‘market entry’.

167

86. Several economists have actually proven that loyalty rebates can in fact entail procompetitive

effects.168169The main procompetitive effects being170171:

more efficient recovery of fixed costs;

providing better incentives to retailers;

reducing double marginalization;

resolving “hold up” problems.

87. The Court has not recognized these procompetitive effects in its case law. A good illustration of this

is paragraph 16 in the British Airways case172:

“BA can have no interest in applying its reward schemes other than ousting rival airlines

and thereby hindering maintenance of the existing level of competition or the development

of that competition on the United Kingdom market for air travel agency services.”173

88. In the Solvay case Advocate General Kokott (who also wrote the opinion in the Post Danmark II

case) rebutted the notion that the case law on loyalty rebates had no economic basis. She stated in

paragraph 80174:

165 See paragraph 74. 166 Rousseva (n73) 176. 167 BPB Industries (n172) paragraph 68. 168 D. RIDYARD, “Exclusionary Pricing and Price Discrimination Abuses Under Article 82 An Economic

Analysis”, European Competition Law Review 2003, 286-303. 169 Peeperkorn (n92) 51. 170 Padilla pagina 465-467. 171 SPECTOR, D., “Loyalty Rebates: An Assessment of Competition concerns and a Proposed Rule of Reason”,

Competition Policty International 2005, 89-114. 172 O’Donoghue & Padilla (n81) 464. 173 British Airways plc v. commission arrest T219/99 verwijzing, zie ook Padilla pagina 464. 174 BPB Industries (n172) paragraph 80.

Page 41: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

35

“I would add merely for the sake of completeness that Solvay’s (ill-substantiated)

complaint to the effect that the case-law of the Court of Justice concerning fidelity rebates

is formalistic and has no economic basis is also unfounded. As has already been said,

when assessing rebate schemes, the Court of Justice takes into account all the

circumstances of the individual case and expressly recognizes the possibility of an

objective economic justification…This is anything but formalistic”

4.1.3 Residual category of rebates and Michelin I

89. The concept of loyalty rebates being illegal was expanded, for the first time, to target rebates in the

Michelin I175 case.176 As is the case for the other case law involving rebates, it is important to first

discuss the factual context of the case. These rebates can be seen as a residual category as they do

not seem to fit within the definition of neither a quantity or loyalty rebate.

90. In the Michelin I case, Michelin, a dominant undertaking in the tire market, offered rebates to its

customers upon reaching a certain target. These targets were personalized for each customer

individually. Michelin took several factors into account when deciding on the sales target, including

the estimated sales of the customer of that reference year and the amount Michelin tires that were

represented in the total amount of sold tires by the customer. These criteria were however not known

or, at least, unclear for the customer. 177

91. From the facts of the case it is clear that there was no explicit exclusivity concluded between

Michelin and its customers.178 It was therefore hard for the Court, in the light of previous case law,

to categorize the rebate operated by Michelin as a loyalty rebate. If it was not a loyalty rebate, could

the rebate scheme then be seen as a quantity rebate? The Court answered this negatively in paragraph

72 of its judgement:

“As regards the system at issue in this case, which is characterized by the use of sales

targets, it must be observed that this system does not amount to a mere quantity discount

175 Michelin I (n75). 176 Jones & Suffrin (n87) 460. 177 J. TEMPLE LANG and R. O’ DONOGHUE Defining Legitimate Competition: How to Clarify Pricing Abuses

Under Article 82 EC, Fordham Int Lt. 2002, 98. 178 Michelin I (n75) page 3472.

Page 42: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

linked solely to the volume of goods purchased since the progressive scale of the previous

year’s turnover indicates only the limits within which the system applies.

...On the other hand the system in question did not require dealers to enter into any

exclusive dealing agreements or to obtain a specific proportion of their supplies form

Michelin NV, and that this point distinguishes it from loyalty rebates of the type which

the Court had to consider in its judgement of 13 February 1979 in Hoffmann-La

Roche.”179

92. The Court therefore could not rely on its sole formal distinction between loyalty rebates and quantity

rebates to hold the rebate scheme applied by Michelin NV as abusive. Instead it stated that it was

necessary to:

“..consider all the circumstances, particularly the criteria and rules for the grant of the

discount, and to investigate whether, in providing an advantage not based on any

economic service justifying it, the discount tends to remove or restrict the buyer’s freedom

to choose his sources of supply, to bar competitors from access to the market, to apply

dissimilar conditions to equivalent transactions with other trading parties or to

strengthen the dominant position by distorting competition.“180

93. To conclude whether the rebate scheme was abusive, the Court thus posited that it would investigate

if the rebate scheme had similar negative effects as a loyalty rebate181. However it is clear that the

Court, rather disappointingly182, did no such thing. Instead it referred to the inherent effect183 of a

discount system with a long reference period. In paragraph 81 the Court notes:

“The discount system in question was based on an annual reference period. However,

any system under which discount are granted according to the quantities sold during a

relatively long reference period has the inherent effect, at the end of that period, of

increasing pressure on the buyer to reach the purchase figure needed to obtain the

discount or to avoid suffering the expected loss for the entire period In this case the

179 Michelin I (n75) paragraph 72. 180 Michelin I (n75) paragraph 73. 181 Ibid. paragraph 91. 182 Rousseva (n73) 178. 183 Ibid.

Page 43: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

37

variations in the rate of discount over a year as a result of one last order, even a small

one, affected the dealer’s margin of profit on the whole year’s sales of Michelin heavy-

vehicle tires. In such circumstances, even quite slight variations might put dealers under

appreciable pressure.”184

94. Therefore the Court assumed that there was considerable pressure on customers that was “further

accentuated” by following factors:

wide divergence between Michelin NV’s market share and those of its main competitors185;

lack of transparency of the rebate scheme186;

95. This led the Court to conclude that the rebate scheme had similar negative effects on the relevant

market as loyalty rebates, and was therefore abusive under art. 102 TFEU. 187

96. As Rousseva notes188, Michelin NV was to a certain extent punished for holding a dominant position

as the accentuating factors189 followed from the dominant position that Michelin NV held at the

time.190 The loyalty-inducing effect191 and dominant position of Michelin NV were sufficient to

conclude that the rebate scheme operated by Michelin NV was abusive. 192

97. In the Michelin I case the Court holds that once a rebate cannot be seen as a quantity rebate, which

is presumed to be legal, it will consider all the relevant circumstances193 in order to determine the

abusive nature of the rebate scheme. The purpose or function of this ‘all the relevant circumstances’

reasoning is to investigate whether the rebate scheme in question has a similar working as rebates

that are conditional upon exclusivity.194 The aim of it is not to provide the anticompetitive effect of

the conduct but rather the vacancy of a justification based on pro-competitive reasons.195 The

184 Michelin I (n75) paragraph 81. 185 Ibid. paragraph 82. 186 Ibid. paragraph 83. 187 Ibid. paragraph 86. 188 Rousseva (n73) 178. 189 e.g. the discrepancy between the smaller competitors and Michelin NV; the fact that smaller competitors could

not match the rebate offered by Michelin NV. 190 This further proves the ordoliberal influence in the case law of the Court. 191 The term ‘loyalty-inducing’ was not explicitly used in the Michelin I case, but rather implied. It was first used

in the Michelin II case with regards to quantity rebates, see paragraph 103 and following. 192 Rousseva (n73) 179. 193 Michelin I (n75) paragraph 73; BPB Industries, T-65/89 ,ECLI:EU:T:1993:31. 194 Colomo (n133) 29. 195 Ibid.

Page 44: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

Michelin I case learns us that target rebate as the ones applied by Michelin NV will be contrary to

Article 102 TFEU, without assessing any economic justification.

4.2 PRESUMED LEGALITY OF QUANTITY REBATES

4.2.1 Definition

“Quantity rebate systems linked solely to the volume of purchases made from an

undertaking occupying a dominant position are generally considered not to have the

foreclosure effect prohibited by Article 82 EC (see Michelin v Commission, cited at

paragraph 54 above, paragraph 71, and Case C-163/99 Portugal v Commission [2001]

ECR I-2613, paragraph 50). If increasing the quantity supplied results in lower costs for

the supplier, the latter is entitled to pass on that reduction to the customer in the form of

a more favorable tariff (Opinion of Advocate General Mischo in Portugal v Commission,

cited above, at ECR I-2618, point 106). Quantity rebates are therefore deemed to reflect

gains in efficiency and economies of scale made by the undertaking in a dominant

position.”196

98. Zenger qualified quantity rebates as follows:

“The only form of rebate the Court has not categorically marked as unlawful is therefore

the very limited class of discounts that are at once incremental, standardized, and

volume-based.”197

99. Since the Hoffmann La Roche case the Court has systematically held that quantity rebates applied

by dominant undertakings are not per se illegal under Article 102 TFEU. This case-law was turned

on its head in the Michelin II198 case where the General Court stated199 that quantity rebates can be

abusive under Article 102 TFEU if they are ‘loyalty-inducing’. To come to this conclusion the Court

would “consider all the circumstances” of the rebate scheme at hand.

196 Michelin II (n75) paragraph 58. 197 H. ZENGER,, “Loyalty Rebates and The Competitive Process”, Journal of Competition Law & Economics

2012, 6. 198 Michelin II (n75). 199 Michelin II (n75) paragraph 58 – 60.

Page 45: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

39

4.2.2 Michelin II and the abandonment of the presumption

100. In its Decision200 2002 the Commission held that the quantity rebate scheme applied by Michelin

NV was abusive under Article 102 TFEU. This was later confirmed by the General Court in its

judgement of 30 September 2003. This is an interesting case with respects to the legality of quantity

rebates as this was the first time the Commission had found a quantity rebate to be abusive under

Article 102 TFEU. 201 Another reason why this case is of relevance is because the rebate scheme

applied by Michelin NV shows a lot of similarities with the one at hand in the Post Danmark II

judgment.202 Namely, both cases involved retroactive standardized rebate schemes.

101. Michelin NV was found to be a dominant undertaking in the French market for replacement tires

for trucks and buses as well as retreated tires. Michelin had set up a marketing scheme which

involved bonuses, rebates and a ‘service bonus system’203; it was also possible for customers to join

the ‘Michelin Friends Club’. Of particular importance for this thesis is the rebate scheme applied by

Michelin NV.

102. Michelin NV operated a retroactive standardized quantity rebate based on a uniform scale, which

it applied to all of its customers.204 The rebate scheme had several particular characteristics whereby

the Commission was of the opinion that the scheme was abusive in the sense of Article 102 TFEU.

The Court of First Instance later followed the Commission’s decision. Even though it was a quantity

rebate, the fact that it had a reference period of a year (a long period in the eyes of the Court of First

Instance) and that the rebate was applicable to the total turnover.205 The rebate scheme had several

different ‘levels’, with each level (individual sales target for the customer) correlating with another

rebate. The rebate was subsequently based on the annual turnover of the customers.

103. In paragraph 58 and 59 the Court sheds some light on the legality of quantity rebates, as opposed to

loyalty rebates, under Article 102 TFEU:

200 Commission decision 2002/405 relating to a proceeding pursuant to Article 82 of the EC Treaty,

COMP/E-2/36.041/PO Michelin, OJ L143/1, 31.05.2002. 201 Jones & Suffrin (n87) 463. 202 P. COLOMO, “Post Danmark II, or the Quest for Administrability and Coherence in Article 102

TFEU”, LSE Working Papers 2015/15. 203 D. WAELBROECK, “Michelin II: A per se Rule Against Rebates by Dominant Companies?”, Journal of

Competition Law and Economics 2005, 150. 204 Van Bael & Bellis (n124) 925. 205 Ibid.

Page 46: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

“Quantity rebate systems linked solely to the volume of purchases made from an

undertaking occupying a dominant position are generally considered not to have the

foreclosure effect prohibited by Article 82 EC (see Michelin v Commission, cited at

paragraph 54 above, paragraph 71, and Case C-163/99 Portugal v Commission [2001]

ECR I-2613, paragraph 50). If increasing the quantity supplied results in lower costs for

the supplier, the latter is entitled to pass on that reduction to the customer in the form of

a more favorable tariff (Opinion of Advocate General Mischo in Portugal v Commission,

cited above, at ECR I-2618, point 106). Quantity rebates are therefore deemed to reflect

gains in efficiency and economies of scale made by the undertaking in a dominant

position.”

“It follows that a rebate system in which the rate of the discount increases according to

the volume purchased will not infringe Article 82 EC unless the criteria and rules for

granting the rebate reveal that the system is not based on an economically justified

countervailing advantage but tends, following the example of a loyalty and target rebate,

to prevent customers from obtaining their supplies II - 4102 MICHELIN v COMMISSION

from competitors (see Hoffmann-La Roche v Commission, cited at paragraph 54 above,

paragraph 90; Michelin v Commission, cited at paragraph 54 above, paragraph 85; Irish

Sugar v Commission, cited at paragraph 54 above, paragraph 114; and Portugal v

Commission, cited at paragraph 58 above, paragraph 52).”

104. Based on the foregoing paragraphs, Jones and Suffrin rightfully noted that the legality of quantity

rebates is based on economic efficiencies and gains being passed onto consumers (i.e. an economic

justification).206 In paragraph 62 the Court states that “the mere fact of characterizing a discount

system as quantity rebates does not mean that the grant of such discounts is compatible with Article

102 TFEU”. In that same paragraph, it then goes on the reiterate earlier case-law that all the

circumstances have to considered.207 The Court therefore departed from the Hoffmann La Roche

presumption with regards to quantity rebates. 208

105. Instead of declaring the rebate as presumably legal, the Court went on to analyze all the

circumstances, like it did in earlier cases involving loyalty rebates209.

206Jones & Suffrin (n87) 468. 207 Michelin II (n109) paragraph 62. 208 Pagaina 3 post danmkar II or the quest for administrability and cherence in article 102 TFEU. 209 Michelin II (n109) paragraph 60.

Page 47: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

41

“In determining whether a quantity rebate system is abusive, it will therefore be

necessary to consider all the circumstances, particularly the criteria and rules governing

the grant of the rebate, and to investigate whether, in providing an advantage not based

on any economic service justifying it, the rebates tend to remove or restrict the buyer's

freedom to choose his sources of supply, to bar competitors from access to the market, to

apply dissimilar conditions to equivalent transactions with other trading parties or to

strengthen the dominant position by distorting competition (see Hoffmann-La Roche v

Commission, cited at paragraph 54 above, paragraph 90; Michelin v Commission, cited

at paragraph 54 above, paragraph 73; and Irish Sugar v Commission, cited at paragraph

54 above, paragraph 114).”210

106. Based on the circumstances the Court concluded that the quantity rebate operated by Michelin had

“the characteristics of a loyalty-inducing discount system”. 211 The quantity rebate therefore lost its

presumed legal status it held under the Hoffmann la Roche case law. Seeing as the rebate scheme

was retroactive instead of incremental it would appear that the Hoffmann La Roche didn’t apply as

it could not be considered as a pure quantity rebate based on the volume of sales. The General Court

took the approach of Michelin I and applied it to the rebate scheme at hand. In paragraphs 50 – 52

it concluded that the rebate scheme was unfair212, loyalty-inducing213 and had a market-partitioning

effect214.215

107. Based on the objective justification reasoning, it was possible for Michelin to escape prosecution if

it was able to prove an objective economic justification for the rebate.216 Michelin NV failed, in the

eyes of the Court to provide this proof.217 Jones and Suffrin therefore conclude that “quantity rebates

which are not linked to a demonstrable economic justification may be loyalty-inducing”.218

210 Ibid. 211 Michelin II (n109) paragraph 95. 212 Ibid., paragraph 50. 213 Ibid., paragraph 51. 214 Ibid., paragraph 52. 215 Colomo (n212) 6. 216 Michelin II (n109) paragraph 108. 217 Ibid. 218 Jones & Suffrin (n87) 469.

Page 48: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

4.2.3 British Airways

108. Having considered the Michelin I case, it is justified to have a closer look at the British Airways

judgement of the Court. It is apparent that in this case, the Court again chose to follow its previous

case-law which has been widely criticized219 for lacking an effects-based approach.220 The Court in

paragraph 65 directly refers to the Michelin I and Hoffmann-La Roche judgements:

“In that respect, Michelin is particularly relevant to the present case, since it concerns a

discount system depending on the attainment of individual sales objectives which

constituted neither discounts for quantity, linked exclusively to the volume of purchases,

nor fidelity discounts within the meaning of the judgment in Hoffman La Roche, since

the system established by Michelin did not contain any obligation on the part of resellers

to obtain all or a given proportion of its supplies from the dominant undertaking” 221

109. The facts of the British Airways case are as follows. During the nineties British Airways offered

sizeable extra commissions to its travel agents for the sales of BA tickets to customers, on top of the

basic commissions already provided. For the travel agents there was therefore an extra incentive to

sell BA tickets instead of tickets of its competitors. Essential in the agreements concluded with the

travel agents, is that there was a certain ‘roll-back’ mechanism included222, i.e. once the travel agent

hit a certain target sales, an extra commission would be paid out based on the total amount of sales

during the reference period.223

110. The Commission clarified the marketing agreements as follows in paragraph 29 of its decision224:

“The commission schemes for travel agents described above all have one notable feature

in common. In each case meeting the targets for sales growth leads to an increase in the

commission paid on all tickets sold by the agent, not just on the tickets sold after the

target is reached. In the [marketing agreement] schemes the cash bonus per ticket paid

219 See to that extent the works of Gormsen, Rousseva, Colomo and Pétit mentioned in the biography. 220 European Court of Justice Upholds Judgment of the Court of First Instance in the British Airways/Vir 221 British Airways (n96) paragraph 65. 222 Jones & Suffrin (n87) 475. 223K. BACON, “European Court of Justice upholds judgement of the Court of First Instance in the British Airways

Judgement”, Competition Policy International 2007, 228. 224 British Airways, C-95/04, ECLI:EU:C:2007:166. OJ 2000 L 30, p. 1, paragraph 29.

Page 49: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

43

to the travel agent increases for all tickets sold. In the [performance reward scheme] the

percentage commission paid increases for all ticket sales by the travel agent. This means

that when a travel agent is close to one of the thresholds for an increase in commission

rate selling relatively few extra BA tickets can have a large effect on his commission

income. Conversely a competitor of BA who wishes to give a travel agent an incentive to

divert some sales from BA to the competing airline will have to pay a much higher rate

of commission than BA on all of the tickets sold by it to overcome this effect.”

111. Virgin Atlantic Airways (hereafter ‘VA’), a big competitor of British Airways, filed a complaint

with the European Commission stating that British Airways abused its dominant position in the

market for air travel agency services. The Commission stated in its decision225 that the complaint of

VA was well founded and therefore concluded that British Airways had abused its dominant position

under Article 102 TFEU seeing as the marketing agreements were comparable to the loyalty rebates

(inter alia discussed in Michelin I and Hoffmann La Roche.226 The Court of First Instance confirmed

the decision in the first appeal made by BA. BA appealed the judgement of the Court of First

Instance with the Court of Justice, which in its turn upheld the judgement.227

112. In the British Airways judgement it is once again clear that loyalty rebates are presumed to have an

anticompetitive purpose and therefore are by nature or ‘by object’ contrary to Article 102 TFEU.

113. In paragraphs 67 to 69 the Court clarifies its approach to rebates under Article 102 TFEU. In

paragraph 67 it first goes to reiterate the, already discussed, Michelin I228 paragraph 73. It is however

interesting that the Court added a new examination of this paragraph in paragraph 68.229 Paragraph

68 and 69 read as follows:

“It follows that in determining whether, on the part of an undertaking in a dominant

position, a system of discounts or bonuses which constitute neither quantity discount or

bonuses nor fidelity discounts or bonuses within the meaning of the Judgement in

Hoffmann- La Roche constitutes an abuse, it first has to be determined whether those

discounts or bonuses can produce an exclusionary effect, that is to say whether they are

capable, first , of making market entry difficult or impossible for competitors of the

225 British Airways, C-95/04, ECLI:EU:C:2007:166. OJ 2000 L 30, p. 1 226 British Airways, C-95/04, ECLI:EU:C:2007:166. OJ 2000 L 30, p. 1, paragraph 96. 227 British Airways (n96). 228 Michelin I (n75) paragraph 73. 229 Rousseva, (n73) 180.

Page 50: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

undertaking in a dominant position and, secondly, of making it more difficult or

impossible for its co-contractors to choose between various sources of supply or

commercial partners.

It then needs to be examined whether there is an objective economic justification of the

discount and bonuses granted. In accordance with the analysis carried out by the General

Court in paragraphs 279 to 291 of the judgement under appeal, an undertaking is at

liberty to demonstrate that its bonus system producing an exclusionary effect is

economically justified.”230

114. As is clear from the aforementioned paragraphs, the Court will apply a two stage test with regards

to rebate schemes similar to the ones found in Michelin I and Hoffmann-La Roche.

115. First, the Court will analyze whether the rebate scheme ‘can produce an exclusionary effect by

making market entry very difficult or impossible for competitors of the undertaking or making it

more difficult or impossible for its co-contractors to choose between various sources of supply or

commercial partners’. Concrete effects will therefore not be analyzed, only the capability of

exclusionary effect is relevant for Article 102 TFEU.

116. Second, once the capability of exclusionary effect has been established it is possible for the

dominant undertaking to provide an objective justification for its abuse. With regards to the analysis

of an objective justification for the abuse of BA, the Court said the following:

“Assessment of the economic justification for a system of discounts or bonuses

established by an undertaking in a dominant position is to be made on the basis of the

whole of the circumstances of the case (see, to that effect, Michelin, paragraph 73). It

has to be determined whether the exclusionary effect arising from such a system, which

is disadvantageous for competition, may be counterbalanced, or outweighed, by

advantages in terms of efficiency which also benefit the consumer. If the exclusionary

effect of that system bears no relation to advantages for the market and consumers, or if

it goes beyond what is necessary in order to attain those advantages, that system must be

regarded as an abuse. In this case, correctly basing its examination upon the criteria thus

inferred from the case-law, the Court of First Instance examined whether there was an

economic justification for the bonus schemes at issue. In paragraphs 284 and 285 of the

230 British Airways (n96) paragraph 68 – 69.

Page 51: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

45

judgment under appeal, it adopted a position in relation to the arguments submitted by

BA, which concerned, in particular, the high level of fixed costs in air transport and the

importance of aircraft occupancy rates.

On the basis of its assessment of the circumstances of the case, the Court of First Instance

came to the conclusion that those systems were not based on any objective economic

justification. 88 In this context, it should be noted that BA's arguments concerning the

high level of fixed costs in air transport and the importance of aircraft occupancy rates

are inadmissible for the reasons set out in paragraph 78 of this judgment, since, by those

arguments, BA is in reality challenging the assessment of facts and evidence made by the

Court of First Instance. It is not for the Court of Justice, on an appeal, to substitute its

own assessment of market data and the competitive position for that of the Court of First

Instance”

117. One of the reasons why the British Airways judgement is of importance, lies in the aforementioned

paragraphs. Contrary to previous cases, namely Michelin I , Hoffmann-La Roche and BPB

Industries, the Court did not accept the possibility for the dominant undertaking to escape

prosecution under Article 102 TFEU by objectively justifying231 its abusive conduct.232 In the British

Airways judgement, the Court once again refused to budge away from its form-based approach to

abuse under Article 102 TFEU. British Airway’s main argument was that its marketing schemes did

not in fact have a negative effect on its competitors. The market share of its competitors actually

increased during the time it operated its commissions scheme.

4.3 OBJECTIVE JUSTIFICATION

4.3.1 Overview

118. This concept of objective justification is still unclear as it lacks an analytical framework.233 It is

unfortunate that Article 102 does not contain a provision similar to Article 101 (3) as this would

231 In earlier case-law the Court used ‘objective justification’ whereas in this case it used ‘economic justifcation’. 232 Rousseva (n73) 181. 233A. ALLBORS-LLORENS, “The Role of Objective Justification and Efficiencies in the Application of Article

82 EC”, Common Market Law Review 2007, 1727-1761.

Page 52: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

undo a lot of legal uncertainty. 234 Furthermore, it is not uncommon for rule of EU law to provide a

prohibitory rule followed by an exonerating provision.235 The mandatory requirements reasoning in

the context of freedom of goods is a good example to this.236

119. Van der Vijver237 recognizes three different types of objective justification in Article 102 TFEU

case-law, being:

legitimate business behavior;

legitimate public interest objectives;

and efficiency considerations.

120. The burden of proof for this objective justification will rest on the dominant undertaking, see for

example paragraph 41 of the Post Danmark238 judgement:

In particular, such an undertaking may demonstrate, for that purpose, either that its

conduct is objectively necessary (see, to that effect, Case 311/84 CBEM[1985]

ECR 3261, paragraph 27), or that the exclusionary effect produced may be

counterbalanced, outweighed even, by advantages in terms of efficiency that also benefit

consumers (Case C-95/04 P British Airways v Commission [2007] ECR I-2331,

paragraph 86, and TeliaSonera Sverige, paragraph 76).

“It is incumbent upon the dominant undertaking to provide all the evidence necessary to

demonstrate that the conduct concerned is objectively justified. It then falls to the

Commission to make the ultimate assessment of whether the conduct concerned is not

objectively necessary and, based on a weighing-up of any apparent anti-competitive

effects against any advanced and substantiated efficiencies, is likely to result in consumer

harm.”

234 T. VAN DER VIJVER, “Objective Justification and Article 102 TFEU”, World Competition 2012, 55-76. 235A. ALLBORS-LLORENS, “The Role of Objective Justification and Efficiencies in the Application of Article

82 EC”, Common Market Law Review 2007, 1727-1761. 236E. ROUSSEVA, “The Concept of Objective Justification of An Abuse of a Dominant Position: Can it Help to

Modernise the Analysis under Article 82 EC?, The Competiton Law Review 2006, 68. 237 A. ALLBORS-LLORENS, “The Role of Objective Justification and Efficiencies in the Application of Article

82 EC”, Common Market Law Review 2007, 1727-1761. 238 Post Danmark I (n86) paragraph 41.

Page 53: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

47

121. What the standard of proof is, is to a certain extent unclear. Luc Ghyselen noted in his paper239 that

there are three aspects a dominant undertaking will have to prove240:

the abusive conduct generates efficiencies;

the efficiencies have to be quantifiable;

the conduct is proportionate to achieve the efficiencies.

4.3.2 Legitimate business interest

122. Legitimate business behavior can been seen as ‘normal business behavior’ referred to in the

Hoffmann-La Roche judgement241. 242 In paragraph 189 of the United Brands243 judgement the Court

stated:

“Although it is true as the applicants points out, that the facts that an undertaking is in a dominant

position cannot disentitle it from protecting its own commercial interests if they are attacked, and

that such an undertaking must be concerned the right to take such reasonable steps as it deems

appropriate to protect its said interests, such behavior cannot be countenanced if its actual purpose

is to strengthen this dominant position and abuse it.”

What constitutes as normal business behavior or competition on the merits will be heavily depended

on the facts of the case.

4.3.3 Legitimate public interest.

123. Legitimate public interests objectives were considered in the Hilti244 case. Hilti, the dominant

undertaking whose conduct was under assessment, tried to justify its exclusionary practices by

239L. GYSELEN, “Rebates, Competition on The Merits or Exclusionary Practice?”, European Competition Law

Anual 2003, 288. 240 L. GYSELEN “Rebates, Competition on The Merits or Exclusionary Practice?”, European Competition Law

Anual 2003, 298. 241 Hoffmann La Roche (n83) paragraph 91. 242A. ALLBORS-LLORENS “The Role of Objective Justification and Efficiencies in the Application of Article

82 EC”, Common Market Law Review 2007,1745. 243 United Brands, C-27/76, ECLI:EU:C:1978:22. 244 Hilti, T-30/89, ECLI:EU:T:1991:70.

Page 54: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

stating that the abuses were necessary in order to protect the safety and the wellbeing of its

customers.245 These arguments were not accepted by the General Court as it was not Hilti’s

responsibility to protect the public safety, seeing as this was already the task of several governmental

bodies. 246 However, with regards to public interest, the Commission has accepted environmental

concerns as a justification of abuse under Article 102 TFEU.247

124. The last objective justification recognized by Van der Vijver is an efficiency consideration. This

objective justification mirrors in a certain way paragraph 3 of Article 101 TFEU. An objective

justification based on efficiency entails that although there is a foreclosure effect on the market,

there are positive effects being passed onto the consumers that outweigh the negative effects.248

4.3.4 Econocmic jusifcation.

125. So far the Court has not yet accepted an efficiency justification for a rebate scheme abusive under

Article 102 TFEU. As was clear from the Michelin II249 case and the British Airways250

judgement, the Court did consider the possibility. For example in Michelin II, the then Court of First

Instance stated251:

“In those circumstances, it is necessary to consider whether, in spite of appearances, the

quantity rebate system applied by the applicant is based on a countervailing advantage

which may be economically justified (see, in that regard, Michelin v Commission, cited

at paragraph 54 above, paragraph 73; Irish Sugar v Commission, cited at paragraph 54

above, paragraph 114; and Portugal v Commission, cited at paragraph 58 above,

paragraph 52) or, in other words, if it rewards an economy of scale made by the applicant

because of orders for large quantities. If increasing the quantity supplied results in lower

costs for the supplier, the latter is entitled to pass on that reduction to the customer in the

245 Ibid. 105 – 107. 246 T. VAN DER VIJVER, “Objective Justification and Article 102 TFEU”, World Competition 2012, 66. 247 Port of Genoa Decision 97/745 [1997] OJ L 301/27, paragraph 21. 248 Guidance on the Commission’s Enforcement Priorities in Applying Article 82 of the EC Treaty to Abusive

Exclusionary Conduct by Dominant Undertakings, 2009, OJ C45/2, paragraph 30. 249 Michelin II (n109) 250 Case T- 219/99 British Airways plc v Commission [2003] ECR II-5917. 251 Michelin II (n109) paragraph 98.

Page 55: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

49

form of a more favourable tariff (Opinion of Advocate General Mischo in Portugal v

Commission, cited at paragraph 58 above, point 106).”

126. In paragraph 107 the Court stated252:

“It is then necessary to examine whether the applicant has established that the quantity

rebate system, which presents the characteristics of a loyalty-inducing rebate system, was

based on objective economic reasons (see, in that regard, Irish Sugar v Commission, cited

at paragraph 54 above, paragraph 188, and Portugal v Commission, cited at paragraph

58 above, paragraph 56).”

127. When the Court applied this to the facts however into detail, the Court found that Michelin could

not justify its rebate scheme due to cost savings.

“It must be stated that the applicant provides no specific information in that regard. It merely states

'that orders for large amounts involve economies and that the customer is entitled to have those

economies passed on to him in the price that he pays' (point 57 of the application). It also refers to

its reply to the statement of objections and to the transcript of the hearing (reply, point 91). Far

from establishing that the quantity rebates were based on actual cost savings (Opinion of Advocate

General Mischo in Portugal v Commission, cited at paragraph 58 above, point 118), the applicant

merely states generally that the quantity rebates were justified by 'economies of scale in the areas

of production costs and distribution' (transcript of the hearing, p. 62).”253

128. Based on the foregoing paragraphs of the Michelin II judgement, it would appear that the Court

would only accept economic justifications if they reflect cost savings due to an increase in the

volume of purchases. 254

4.4 SUMMARY CONCLUSION

129. Roughly three categories of rebates can be distilled from the case-law as described above. First,

quantity rebates, which based on Hoffmann La Roche will be presumed to be legal. However, after

the Michelin II judgment this presumption of legality was disputed by the General Court. It

concerned a standardized retroactive rebate and as such could not be considered as a quantity rebate

in the sense of Hoffmann La Roche. The General Court therefore assessed the rebate scheme through

252 Michelin II (n109) paragraph 107. 253 Michelin II (n109) paragraph 108. 254E. ROUSSEVA, “The Concept of Objective Justification of An Abuse of a Dominant Position: Can it Help to

Modernise the Analysis under Article 82 EC?, The Competiton Law Review 2006, 103.

Page 56: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

the lenses of the Michelin I case. After it had considered all the circumstances, the General Court

came to the conclusion that the rebate scheme was unfair, loyalty-inducing and market-partitioning.

This leads to the conclusion that the presumption of legality will only be applied to a very strict

category of quantity rebates. One of the questions the Post Danmark II possibly could answer is

whether the presumption also applies to standardized incremental quantity rebates. This will be

discussed in the closing chapters.

130. The second category recognized in the case-law are the exclusionary rebates or loyalty rebates.

These are considered abusive ‘by object’. These are presumed to be contrary to Article 102 TFEU,

like exclusive dealing contracts, as they are very likely to have a negative impact on consumers.255

As noted in the discussed case-law, with regards to exclusivity rebates the Courts will conclude that

the scheme is abusive based on the form that rather the effects. 256

131. The last category is the residual category as held in the Michelin I judgement. Rebate schemes that

do not meet the requirements of either of the aforementioned rebate schemes will be assessed under

the Michelin I - test. This test was further developed in the British Airways case. With regards to

this residual category the Court will accordingly apply a two-stage test. First, it will assess whether

the rebate scheme is capable of producing an exclusionary effect. Second, the Court will assess

whether there is an objective justification for the scrutinized conduct.

132. Based on the objective justification doctrine an dominant undertaking can escape application of

Article 102 TFEU by proving that it was justified. The proof of burden will ultimately be on the

dominant undertaking. So far, roughly three different justifications have been accepted in the case-

law and literature; namely: legitimate business interest, legitimate public interest and economic

efficiencies. Whether the dominant undertaking will be able to justify its conduct based on previous

cases will be ambiguous. This will depend heavily on the factual context of the rebate scheme. As

of yet it is unclear which objective justifications the EU Courts will accept in the future. Considering

the amounts of parameters that can impact the application of the objective justification I am of the

opinion that it is not an ideal framework to assess of abuse of dominance under. It is clear that this

concept is developed on an ad-hoc basis and therefore does not provide the much needed guidance

for dominant undertakings wanting to avoid the application of Article 102 TFEU on their rebate

schemes.

255 Peeperkorn (n92) 53. 256 Jones & Suffrin (n87) 382.

Page 57: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

51

133. In the 2000’s, following the Michelin II and British Airways judgements of the General Court, the

Commission started to rethink its decisional approach to conduct contrary to Article 102 TFEU.

There was a lot of criticism following both these judgements as in both cases, the dominant

undertaking’s competitor’s market shares increased despite the conduct of the dominant

undertakings.257 In July 2005 it published the Report on an Economic Approach to Article 82

(‘Consultation Paper’) 258. The Commission had by then realized that the form-based approach to

rebates under Article 102 TFEU garnered a lot of criticism among legal practitioners and dominant

undertakings alike. The main criticism being that the approach of the EU Court did not involve a

consistent assessment of the effects of the conduct.259 The executive summary of the Consultation

Paper is as follows260:

“This report argues in favor of an economics-based approach to Article 82, in a way

similar to the reform of Article 81 and merger control. In particular, we support an

effects-based rather than a form-based approach to competition policy. Such an

approach focuses on the presence of anti-competitive effects that harm consumers, and

is based on the examination of each specific case, based on sound economics and

grounded on facts.”

In the Consultation Paper the authors therefore clearly plead for an effects based approach to Article

102 TFEU.

134. Shortly following the publication of the Consultation Paper, the Commission published the

Discussion Paper on the Application of Article 82 of the Treaty to Exclusionary Abuses261 (‘the

Discussion paper’). The Commission published this paper in order to incite a debate on what

257 Colomo (n133) 19. 258 Report by the Economic Advisory Group (EAGCP) for Competition Policty ‘An Economic Approach to Article

82 EC’, July 2005, availible at: ec.europa.eu/competition/atintrust/art82. 259 O’Donoghue & Padilla (n81). 260 Report by the Economic Advisory Group (EAGCP) for Competition Policty ‘An Economic Approach to Article

82 EC’, July 2005, 2, availible at: ec.europa.eu/competition/atintrust/art82. 261 DG COMPETITION Discussion Paper on the Application of Article 82 of the Treaty to Exclusionary Abuses,

Brussels, December 2005, available at: ec.europa.eu/competition/atintrust/art82.

Page 58: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

analytical framework the Commission should adopt in its future decisions and guidelines regarding

exclusionary abuses under Article 102 TFEU. It was the first attempt at drafting guidelines for the

application of Article 102 TFEU.262 The Discussion Paper has been criticized by some

commentators however because it “it lacks the vigour found in the EAGCP Report.”263. Akman

further criticized the Discussion Paper for not giving a clear overview how the effects-based

approach should be implemented.264 There are however notions of an effects based approach to be

found in the Discussion Paper265, although not sufficient. Others266 state that the Discussion Paper’s

preferred approach, of making consumer harm the main objective of the Commission’s Policy,

would be contrary to at that time established case-law. Namely, in the case-law multiple objectives

have been cited for Article 102 TFEU, consumer-harm being only one of them.267 As discussed

earlier268

135. The official ‘guidelines’ for the application of Article 102 TFEU were published in December 2008,

carefully titled Guidance on the Commission’s Enforcement Priorities in Applying Article 82 EC

Treaty to Abusive Exclusionary Conduct by Dominant Undertakings (‘Guidance Paper’)269. By

publishing the Guidance Paper, the wanted to create some clarity on its decisional practice and more

importantly its priorities (the Guidance Paper is most of all a prioritization device)270 with regards

to exclusionary conduct under Article 102 TFEU. It is however highly debatable if it succeeded in

that objective.

136. Some commentators, like Ezrachi, have stated that instead of creating more certainty for

undertakings by publishing the Guidance Paper, the Commission has accomplished the opposite.271

262L. GORMSEN, A Principled Approach to Abuse of Dominance in European Competition Law, Cambridge,

Cambridge University Pres, 2010, 157. 263 Discussion Paper (n274). 264 P. AKMAN “The EC Discussion Paper on the Application of Article 82”, not published. Available at:

http://competitionpolicy.ac.uk/documents/8158338/8264816/004.pdf/6364b50a-b785-4529-97e0-ad64a17c7f35. 265 Discussion Paper (n274). 266 L. GORMSEN, A Principled Approach to Abuse of Dominance in European Competition Law, Cambridge,

Cambridge University Pres, 2010, 157. 267 Ibid., 158. 268 Paragraphs 47 and following. 269 DG COMPETITION Discussion Paper on the Application of Article 82 of the Treaty to Exclusionary Abuses,

Brussels, December 2005, available at: ec.europa.eu/competition/atintrust/art82. 270N. PETIT “Rebates and Article 102 TFEU: The European Commission's Duty to Apply the Guidance Paper”,

not published, availible at: http://orbi.ulg.ac.be/handle/2268/192441. 271 Guidance on the Commission’s Enforcement Priorities in Applying Article 82 of the EC Treaty to Abusive

Exclusionary Conduct by Dominant Undertakings, 2009, OJ C45/2, 64.

Page 59: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

53

This uncertainty is created on two fronts according to Ezrachi, namely‘inherent uncertainty’ and

‘external uncertainty’.272 ‘Inherent uncertainty’ in the sense that the concepts brought up by the

Commission are too vague and “open-ended”.273 A diverging approach274 between the EU Courts

and the EU Commission could in turn lead to what Ezrachi calls ‘external uncertainty’.275 While it

was applauded by some for opening the door to a more economic approach of Article 102 TFEU, it

is nonetheless without its flaws.276

137. Certain paragraphs in the Guidance Paper are unfortunate however. Paragraph 22 is a good example

of this::

“There may be circumstances where it is not necessary for the Commission to carry out

a detailed assessment before concluding that the conduct in question is likely to result in

consumer harm. If it appears that the conduct can only raise obstacles to competition and

that it creates no efficiencies, its anti-competitive effect may be inferred.”277

138. These kind of paragraphs further add to the ambiguity and uncertainty touched upon in previous

paragraphs. Regrettable is that the Commission seems to contradict itself in this paragraph as this

indicates that the form-based approach is still at play in the minds of the Commission. Ultimately,

this kind of flexibility does not serve predictability ex ante for dominant undertakings which was

partly the reason why the Commission started this debate in the first place.278

272A, EZRACHI Article 82 EC: Reflections on its Recent Evolution, Oxford, Hart Pubishing, 2009, 53. 273 Ibid. 274 Where the EU courts would adhere to a form-based approach and the EU commission to a more economic

approach. 275 Ezrachi (n285) 55. 276 D. GERADIN “The Decision of the Commission of 13 May 2009 in the Intel case: Where is the Foreclosure

and Consumer Harm?”, Journal of European Competition Law & Practice 2010, 112-122. 277 Guidance Paper (n284) paragraph 22. 278 P. AKMAN, “The Reform of the Application of Article 102 TFEU: Mission Accomplished”, Anti-Trust Law

Journal, forthcoming, 14, available at: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2654679.

Page 60: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

5.1 THE AS-EFFICIENT-COMPETITOR TEST

139. With regards to price-based exclusionary conduct, which would appear as to include loyalty

rebates279, the Commission has set out in its Guidance Paper that it will only intervene “where the

conduct concerned has already been or is capable of hampering competition from competitors

which are considered to be as efficient as the dominant undertaking”.280 In paragraph 25 of the

Guideline the Commission clarifies how this as-efficient-competitor (hereafter ‘AEC- test’) test

would be applied:

“In order to determine whether even a hypothetical competitor as efficient as the

dominant undertaking would be likely to be foreclosed by the conduct in question, the

Commission will examine economic data relating to cost and sales prices, and in

particular whether the dominant undertaking is engaging in below-cost pricing. This will

require that sufficiently reliable data be available. Where available, the Commission will

use information on the costs of the dominant undertaking itself. If reliable information on

those costs is not available, the Commission may decide to use the cost data of

competitors or other comparable reliable data.”

140. The last line of the aforementioned paragraph is highly questionable. Namely, the Commission

states here that, in certain circumstances, when applying the AEC-test, it will assess whether the

dominant undertaking operates below the costs of a competitor. With regards to legal certainty this

cannot be justified. It is unreasonable to require from a dominant undertaking to assess ex ante its

pricing schemes in the light of the costs of another undertaking.281

141. The status of the AEC-test was first discussed in the Intel282 judgement. The Intel case involved

conditional rebates offered by Intel, the dominant undertaking, to its customers. Important to note

is that the Intel case was brought before the General Court before the adaption of the Guidance Paper

279N. PETIT “Rebates and Article 102 TFEU: The European Commission's Duty to Apply the Guidance Paper”,

not published, 2, available at: http://orbi.ulg.ac.be/handle/2268/192441. 280 Guidance on the Commission’s Enforcement Priorities in Applying Article 82 of the EC Treaty to Abusive

Exclusionary Conduct by Dominant Undertakings, 2009, OJ C45/2, paragraph 3. 281 Akman (n291) 15. 282 Intel, T-286/09, ECLI:EU:T:2014:547.

Page 61: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

55

by the Commission283. As is clear from the judgment in Intel284, the General Court decided to stick

to the principles and two stage approach established in earlier case law. The Commission also

concluded that Intel had abused its dominant position by applying the traditional two stage test.

However, it also applied its AEC-test. In this regard, paragraph 992 of the Commission’s decision285

in Intel is noteworthy:

“Intel argues that beyond the requirement of an exclusivity or quasi-exclusivity condition

of the discounts required by the case law quoted in recital (920), the Court also

considered "whether the scheme in question did in fact affect the situation of competitors

(i.e. whether they did actually or likely foreclose competitors)".

However, a reading of the case law referred to in recital (920) reveals that this is not the

case. Contrary to what Intel argues, the Courts do not look into the actual impact of the

alleged anticompetitive conduct on the market in the analysis undertaken in cases like

Microsoft or British Airways either. Indeed, even with regard to conduct that does not

constitute fidelity discounts within the meaning of the Hoffmann La Roche case la the

Community Courts have established that "for the purposes of establishing an

infringement of Article 82 EC, it is not necessary to demonstrate that the abuse in question

had a concrete effect on the markets concerned. It is sufficient in that respect to

demonstrate that the abusive conduct of the undertaking in a dominant position tends to

restrict competition or, in other words, that the conduct in question is capable of having

or likely to have such an effect."

142. In paragraph 923286 the Commission then goes on:

“Contrary to what Intel argues, however, this does not require evidence of actual

foreclosure. In addition, a violation of Article 82 may also result from the anticompetitive

object of the practices pursued by a dominant undertaking.”

283 The case came under investigation in the early 2000s,whereas the Guidance Paper was published in December

2008. See Nicholas Petit, pagina 3, rebates and the duty to apply the AEC test. 284 Intel (n295) paragraph 80 – 81. 285 Intel, T-286/09, ECLI:EU:T:2014:547, OJ 2009 C 227, p. 13 286 Intel, T-286/09, ECLI:EU:T:2014:547, OJ 2009 C 227, p. 13, paragraph 923.

Page 62: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

With this paragraph the Commission seems to contradict its own Guidance Paper as it states that

proof of actual foreclosure effects.

143. Intel’s main argument was that no actual foreclosure effects had been proven. In response to this,

the Commission referred to the established case-law up to that point. It therefore saw no reason why

it had to establish anti-competitive effects. In its decision it did however apply the AEC – test to the

case.287

144. The Commission described the AEC it would apply as follows:

“The as efficient competitor analysis is a hypothetical exercise in the sense that it

attempts to analyze whether a competitor which is as efficient as Intel (in terms of

producing x86 CPUs and in terms of delivering x86 CPUs that provide the same value to

customers as Intel), but which would not have as broad a sales base as Intel, would be

foreclosed from entering.”

“Given all the relevant parameters (namely de facto conditions for the rebates applied

by the dominant undertaking, contestable share, reference period and cost measure), the

as efficient competitor analysis as applied in this case examines what price an as efficient

competitor would have to offer an Intel trading partner in order to compensate it for the

loss of any Intel rebate. If Intel’s rebate scheme means that in order to compensate an

Intel trading partner for the loss of the Intel rebate, an as efficient competitor has to offer

its products below a viable measure of Intel's cost, then it means that the rebate was

capable of reducing access to Intel trading partners which could offer products from the

as efficient competitor, or in other words capable of foreclosing a hypothetical as efficient

competitor. This would thereby deprive final consumers of the choice between different

products which the Intel trading partner would otherwise have chosen to offer were it to

make its decision solely on the basis of the relative merit of the products and unit prices

offered by Intel and its competitors.”288

287 Intel, T-286/09, ECLI:EU:T:2014:547, OJ 2009 C 227, p. 13, paragraph 1002-1576. 288 Intel, T-286/09, ECLI:EU:T:2014:547, OJ 2009 C 227, p. 13, paragraph 1154.

Page 63: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

57

145. To summarize, the AEC test tries to give a solution for the orthodox form-based approach of Article

102 “by defining foreclosure as instances where a dominant firm forces rivals to effectively compete

with below-cost prices” as noted by Zenger.289 With the AEC-test there is a parting of the automatic

assumption that there are anti-competitive effects on the competitive structure once the requirements

for an infringement of Article 102 TFEU, based on the case-law, have been identified.290 As it is

stated in paragraph 23 of the Guidance paper:

“…the Commission will normally only intervene where the conduct concerned has

already been or is capable of hampering competition from competitors which are

considered to be as efficient as the dominant undertaking.”

146. The Intel decision was a first insight on how the Commission would apply the AEC-test. It in turn

was however criticized by commentators for several reasons.291 One of the reasons being that,

despite having announced that it would adopt a more economic approach with regards to Article

102 TFEU292, when push comes to shove, the Commission still falls back on its form-based

approach.293

147. Some points of criticism are to be made with regards to the legal framework put forward in the

Guidance Paper. When the Commission would apply the AEC-test, it would take certain parameters

289H. ZENGER, “Devising Loyalty Rebates that Comply with the As-Efficient-Competitor Test”, Concurrences

Review 2013, 16-19. 290 Gormsen, are anti competitive effects necessary for an analysis under article 102 TFEU? 291D. GERADIN “The Decision of the Commission of 13 May 2009 in the Intel case: Where is the Foreclosure

and Consumer Harm?”, Journal of European Competition Law & Practice 2010, 112-122. 292 The then Commissioner for EU competition is said to have announced this as early as 23 september 2005. See

Neelie Kroes, “Preliminary Thoughts on Policy Review of Article 82”, Speech at the Fordham Corporate Law

Institute New York, 23 September 2005. 293 Geradin (n305) 23.

Page 64: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

into account such as ‘the contestable share294’ and the ‘relevant range295’. There are several reasons

why these parameters would be difficult to estimate.296 For dominant undertakings it would therefore

be very difficult to calculate when its abusive conduct is likely to fall under the prohibitions of

Article 102 TFEU. Lang concludes with his main criticism being that the Guidance Paper makes no

clear distinction between ‘legitimate foreclosure’ and ‘anti-competitive foreclosure’. 297

148. Ultimately, the AEC test is not a desirable solution for the formalistic approach of Article 102

TFEU. As mentioned in the above paragraph, the parameters are too difficult for an undertaking to

estimate which in turn could cause legal uncertainty298. Another issue is that it is still too orthodox

in the sense that, as Gormsen notes, the standard of proof is still based on the ‘capability’ of

competition restricting effects.299

5.2 THE LEGAL NATURE OF THE AS-EFFICIENT-COMPETITOR TEST

149. In the following paragraphs I will assess the legal nature of the Paper, and more specifically the

AEC-test contained within the Guidance Paper, as this was also to a certain extent unclear for the

referring Court in the Post Danmark II prejudicial question.300

294 “As with exclusive purchasing obligations, the likelihood of anti-competitive foreclosure is higher where

competitors are not able to compete on equal terms for the entire demand of each individual customer. A

conditional rebate granted by a dominant undertaking may enable it to use the ‘non contestable’ portion of the

demand of each customer (that is to say, the amount that would be purchased by the customer from the dominant

undertaking in any event) as leverage to decrease the price to be paid for the ‘contestable’ portion of demand (that

is to say, the amount for which the customer may prefer and be able to find substitutes)”. See Guidance on the

Commission’s Enforcement Priorities in Applying Article 82 of the EC Treaty to Abusive Exclusionary Conduct

by Dominant Undertakings, 2009, OJ C45/2. 295 Commission will estimate what price a competitor would have to offer in order to compensate the customer for

the loss of the conditional rebate if the latter would switch part of its demand (‘the relevant range’) away from the

dominant undertaking. See Guidance paper. 296J. TEMPLE LANG and R. O’ DONOGHUE,“Defining Legitimate Competition: How to Clarify Pricing Abuses

Under Article 82 EC, Fordham Int Lt. 2002, 139 297 Ibid. 298 See to this extent also paragraph 108. 299L. GORMSEN, “Are Anti-Competitive Effects Necessay for an Analysis under Article 102 TFEU?”, World

Competition 2013, 223-246. 300 See paragraph 124.

Page 65: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

59

150. In paragraph 3 of the Guideline it states that the paper does not “constitute a statement of the law”.301

Guidelines in EU law are generally considered to be soft law. 302 With regards to Guidelines the

Court clarified its legal status in the Dansk Rørindustri A/S judgement, in paragraph 207 it stated:

“The Court has already held, in a judgment concerning internal measures adopted by the

administration, that although those measures may not be regarded as rules of law which

the administration is always bound to observe, they nevertheless form rules of practice

from which the administration may not depart in an individual case without giving

reasons that are compatible with the principle of equal treatment. Such measures

therefore constitute a general act and the officials and other staff concerned may invoke

their illegality in support of an action against the individual measures taken on the basis

of the measures (see Case C-171/00 P Liberos v Commission [2002] ECR I-451,

paragraph 35).”

151. Based on the aforementioned paragraph, the Commission would have to apply the Guidance Paper

in subsequent cases involving Article 102 TFEU. The Commission already noted in its Discussion

Paper however that it would have to respect the interpretation of the EU Courts given to Article 102

TFEU.303 Therefore the Commission would still have to respect the boundaries as determined by

the EU Courts.304 This could cause issues for Commission who allegedly wants to further its more

economic approach agenda. The reason for this is that the Commission can shape its policy in a

proactive way whereas the Courts can only develop a new approach in a reactive way, i.e. when a

new relevant case is brought before the Courts.305

152. The Court of Justice had an opportunity to reshape its policy with regards to Article 102 TFEU. In

the Tomra306 it involved again an exclusive dealing and rebate scheme set up by dominant

301 Guidance on the Commission’s Enforcement Priorities in Applying Article 82 of the EC Treaty to Abusive

Exclusionary Conduct by Dominant Undertakings, 2009, OJ C45/2, paragraph 3. 302 Z. GEORGIEVA, Soft Law in EU Competition Law and its Judicial Reception in Member States -- A

Theoretical Perspective (October 2014). TILEC Discussion Paper No. 2014-035. Available at

SSRN:http://ssrn.com/abstract=2506617 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2506617. 303 DG COMPETITION Discussion Paper on the Application of Article 82 of the Treaty to Exclusionary Abuses,

Brussels, December 2005, paragraph 6 available at: ec.europa.eu/competition/atintrust/art82. 304A. EZRACHI; “Article 82 EC: Reflections on its Recent Evolution”, Oxford, Hart Pubishing, 2009, 51. 305 Ibid. 306 Tomra, C-549/10, ECLI:EU:C:2012:221.

Page 66: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

undertaking Tomra. It was clear from the judgement however that the Court had no intention to

apply the Commission’s Guidance Paper. In paragraph 81 it stated:

“The appellants’ arguments that the Commission’s Guidance (see paragraph 52 of this judgment),

provides for a comparative analysis of prices and costs cannot invalidate that conclusion. As the

Advocate General observes in point 37 of his Opinion, the Guidance, published in 2009, has no

relevance to the legal assessment of a decision, such as the contested decision, which as published

in 2006.”

Jones & Sufrin rightfully note that the above begs the question that if the Guidance had been

published after the Commission’s decision would the Paper have been relevant in the Courts

assessment?307

153. Pétit states that the AEC test can be seen as a “rule of practice” as mentioned above.308 He also notes

that the Commission should apply the AEC test when assessing a price abuse, however a marginal

discretion has to be taken into account.309

5.3 THE AS-EFFICIENT COMPETITOR TEST FOLLOWING THE POST

DANMARK II JUDGMENT

154. In Post Danmark II the referring Court asked the Court Justice, inter alia, the following in its

prejudicial question:

In its answer the Court is further requested to clarify what relevance, if any, the dominant

undertaking’s prices and costs have to the evaluation pursuant to Article 82 EC of such a rebate

scheme (relevance of an “as-efficient-competitor” test).

155. The Advocate General is of the opinion that the AEC is not binding on the national competition

authorities.310 The reasons for this are twofold. First, the Commission states in its Enforcement

307 Jones & Suffrin (n87) 482. 308 N. PETIT “Rebates and Article 102 TFEU: The European Commission's Duty to Apply the Guidance Paper”,

not published, availible at: http://orbi.ulg.ac.be/handle/2268/192441. 309 N. PETIT “Rebates and Article 102 TFEU: The European Commission's Duty to Apply the Guidance Paper”,

not published, 10, availible at: http://orbi.ulg.ac.be/handle/2268/192441. 310 Post Danmark II, C-23/14, ECLI:EU:C:2015:651, opinion of AG Kokott, paragraph 60.

Page 67: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

61

Priorities Communication that it is not ‘a statement of the law’311. Second, it is settled case-law that

statements of the Commission are not legally binding.312 However, the national competition

authorities are not precluded form utilizing a price/cost analysis in their assessment.313

156. To further corroborate her opinion, the Advocate General also refers to the fact there is no case law

that states that a price/cost analysis is an absolute requirement when assessing a rebate scheme. 314

Therefore she is also of the opinion that the Court should confirm their position on this issue.315

157. To make such an analysis conditional would be unreasonable in the eyes of Advocate General

Kokott. She lists a number of reasons for this. First, she remarks that it would take up a lot of the

limited resources of the national competition authorities.316 Second, in order for the AEC test to be

reliable, the input data has to be reliable.317 And in order for the data to be reliable the dominant

undertaking that is subject of the investigation has to be cooperative at all times. She states that this

is an unreasonable presumption as corporate data is open to a lot of different interpretations.318 Third,

the AEC test compares the dominant undertaking with an as efficient competitor. But the relevant

market is structured in such a way (high barriers of entry, economies of scale) that it is near

impossible for another undertaking to be as efficient as Post Danmark.319 The Advocate General

concludes that to compare the dominant undertaking with an as efficient hypothetical undertaking,

which is not able to exit, would lead to undesirable result.

158. The Advocate General thus pleads for a more general assessment where all the relevant

circumstances of the rebate scheme have been taken into account. She states:

“In particular, however, a finding of abuse in the context of Article 82 (now art. 102

TFEU), as in other contexts, always requires an evaluation which takes into account all

the relevant circumstances of the individual case in question and must not be confined to

311Guidance on the Commission’s Enforcement Priorities in Applying Article 82 of the EC Treaty to Abusive

Exclusionary Conduct by Dominant Undertakings, 2009, OJ C45/2, paragraph 23. 312 Expedia, C-226/11, EU:C:2012:795, paragraph 29 – 31. 313 Post Danmark II, C-23/14, ECLI:EU:C:2015:651, opinion of AG Kokott, paragraph 60. 314 Ibid. 63. 315 Ibid. 64. 316 Ibid. 66. 317 Ibid. paragraph 66. 318 Ibid. paragraph 67. 319 Ibid. paragraph 71.

Page 68: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

an examination of price and cost components alone. On the contrary, there are many

other factors, such as the specific modus operandi of a rebate scheme and certain

characteristics of the market on which the dominant undertaking operates, that may also

be relevant to finding of abuse. In fact, they may be much more informative than a

price/cost analysis.”320

159. So in conclusion, the Advocate General pleads for an approach that involves all the relevant

circumstances without the AEC test being mandatory for the national competition authorities, based

on the foregoing reasons. An AEC test can however be applied in the assessment of the rebate

scheme under art. 102 TFEU. 321

“2. Article 82 EC does not require the abusive nature of the rebate scheme operated by

a dominant undertaking to be demonstrated by means of a price/cost analysis such as the

as-efficient-competitor test, where its abusive nature is immediately shown by an overall

assessment of the other circumstances of the individual case.

However, the authorities and courts dealing with competition cases are at liberty to avail

themselves of a price/cost analysis in their overall assessment of all the circumstances of

the individual case, unless, on account of the structure of the market, it would be

impossible for another undertaking to be as efficient as the dominant undertaking.”

160. In paragraphs 51 and following, the Court discussed the relevance of the as-efficient-competitor test

in assessing a rebate scheme under art. 102 TFEU.322

161. In its judgement, the Court agrees with the Advocate General on the fact that there is no legal

obligation resting on national competition authorities to apply the as-efficient-competitor test when

assessing a rebate scheme under art. 102 TFEU. 323 According to the Court there is simply no

possible reading of art. 102 TFEU that would allow this.324

320 Ibid. paragraph 68. 321 Ibid. paragraph 75. 322 Ibid. paragraph 52. 323 Ibid. paragraph 57. 324 Ibid.

Page 69: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

63

162. It can, however, be reasonable to apply an as-efficient-competitior test when assessing a rebate

scheme, but it cannot be made obligatory.325 In the present case, the Court is of the opinion, just like

the Advocate General, that, to apply an as-efficient-competitor test on the rebate scheme applied by

Post Danmark, would not make much sense. To back this up, the Court notes similar arguments as

the Advocate General.326 To conclude, the Court sees the AEC test as a tool available to the national

competition authorities when assessing a rebate scheme under art. 102 TFEU and is therefore not a

necessary condition. 327

163. It can therefore be concluded that following the Post Danmark II judgement the AEC – test is a

valid option for the assessment of rebates. Pétit notes: “this means that the Commission can set for

itself stricter standards than those found in Article 102 TFEU case-law.”328 Seeing as the AEC test

can be seen as a ‘rule of practice’, the Commission would be under an obligation based on the case

law to apply the AEC-test.

5.4 SUMMARY CONCLUSION

164. A divide between the assessment of rebate schemes by the Commission and the EU Courts can be

noticed following the publication of the Guidance Paper in 2009. Preceding the Guidance Paper, the

Commission published the Consultation and Discussion Paper. The Commission wanted to spark

the debate on how to modernize the legal framework of Article 102 TFEU. The conclusion from

these documents is that the Commission wanted to push the assessment of conduct, thus including

rebate schemes, under Article 102 TFEU into the direction of an effects-based approach. This intent

was predominantly present in the Consultation paper which clearly urged for a more economic

approach. The spirit of the Consultation paper was however to a lesser extent present in the

documents that followed up on it. It is unfortunate that the Discussion and Guidance paper did not

contain the same enthusiasm as the Consultation paper.

165. The culmination of the modernization debate by the Commission was the Guidance Paper. In this

Guidance Paper the Commission offered an insight into its enforcement priorities for the future.

This would allow dominant undertakings, who are the subject of Article 102 TFEU, to better assess

325 Ibid. paragraph 58. 326 See paragraph 32. 327 Post Danmark II, C-23/14, ECLI:EU:C:2015:651, paragraph 62. 328 PETIT, N. “Rebates and Article 102 TFEU: The European Commission's Duty to Apply the Guidance Paper”,

not published, pagina 11, availible at: http://orbi.ulg.ac.be/handle/2268/192441.

Page 70: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

their conduct ex ante as to avoid prosecution by way of Article 102 TFEU. Whether the Commission

succeeded in achieving its goals is debatable. The reason for this is that the Commission contradicts

itself in the Guidance Paper which in turn leads to uncertainty. Moreover, the Guidance Paper allows

for a lot of flexibility for the Commission329. Geradin has given a nice example of the ambiguity

plaguing the Guidance Paper. Namely, he counted eighteen times the use of the term ‘generally’ and

five times the term ‘in principle’ in the Guidance Paper.330

166. In the Guidance Paper the Commission included the as-efficient-competitor test. This test involves

assessing whether a hypothetical competitor as efficient as the dominant undertaking would be likely

to be foreclosed by the conduct in question. Therefore when the AEC-test suggests that the pricing

level has the potential to foreclose on equally efficient competitors, the Commission will take this

into account when deciding whether the conduct is exclusionary. The Guidance Paper states that the

AEC-test is relevant in the overall assessment but is not decisive in the final decision. The

Commisison can therefore also take other factors into account. 331The Commission gave some

insight on the concrete application of this AEC-test in the context of rebate schemes with its decision

in the Intel case. Several commentators have noted that the parameters used in the AEC-test are

difficult to estimate for dominant undertakings and therefore not reliable.

167. Whether the Guidance Paper and the AEC-test was legally binding for the Commission and the

national competition authorities was still contested, to a certain extent, up until the Post Danmark

II judgment. The Court of Justice has stated in previous case-law that, although not being rules of

law, guidelines are rules of practice. Therefore the Commission could not depart from these

guidelines without giving a specific reason. The Commission also had to take the case-law of the

EU courts into account when assessing conduct from dominant undertakings. Clarity on this issue

came with the Post Danmark II judgement. The Court held that the application of the AEC-test is

purely optional competent authority conducting the investigation. However when the relevant

authority does apply the AEC-test it will have to take the case-law of the EU courts into account.

168. Although it is a step in the right direction, the AEC-test is not the ideal way of modernizing Article

102 TFEU. If the Commission is serious about modernizing Article 102 TFEU it should put its

money where its mouth is. The AEC-test is currently only optional and only forms an aspect of its

329 D. GERADIN, “Is the Guidance Paper on the Commission’s Enforcement Priorities in Applying Article 102

TFEU to Abusive Exclusionary Conduct Useful?” in ETRO, F. and KOKKORIS, I., Challenges in the

Enforcement of Article 102, Oxford, Oxford University Press, 2010. 330 Ibid. 331 Ibid.

Page 71: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

65

hypothetical decision. The Commission needs to admit that the previous case-law involving rebates

was wrong. Not only because its bad case-law but also because it lacks an administrable framework

which could in turn chill competition and ultimately affect consumers who could benefit from

certain rebates.

169. In previous chapters I have established that when a rebate scheme cannot be considered as either a

quantity or loyalty rebate, the Courts will apply the legal test applied in Michelin I and further

developed in British Airways. In this assessment it will consider ‘all the circumstances’ of the rebate

scheme and will allow the dominant undertaking to proof an objective justification. In short, the test

will try to assess whether the rebate scheme is ‘loyalty-inducing’. I will argue that this ‘by object’

approach of rebate schemes, and more specifically quantity rebates, under Article 102 TFEU is not

desirable. A possible solution would be to extent the case-law concerning selective-price cuts and

margin squeezes to rebate schemes. This would shift the legal framework from a ‘by object’ rule to

a ‘by effect’ standard.

170. The Court needs to develop a legal standard with regards to rebates so that dominant undertakings

can legitimately foresee ex ante whether or not their conduct would be contrary to Article 102 TFEU.

The case-law discussed in previous chapters indicates that the legal framework, as it stands now,

lacks an analytical and economic dimension.332 A good example of this is the application of the

Michelin I test in the context of quantity rebates.

171. The Michelin I case concerned target rebates whereas, for example, in the Michelin II case it

concerned a standardized quantity rebate. The reasoning in the case law with regards to target

rebates was created in a very specific context. Colomo notes that “applying the principles sketched

in Michelin I to quantity rebates would indeed amount to stretching that in of case law beyond the

limits of its logic”.333 Furthermore, in the Hoffmann La Roche judgement the Court dictated that

quantity rebates are presumed to be legal. This would, from a normative point of view, imply a

different approach with regards to quantity rebates. If the competent authority would take Hoffmann

La Roche presumption into account, it would have to prove that the purpose of the rebate scheme is

332 Colomo (n212) 15. 333 Colomo (n212) 15.

Page 72: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

to foreclose competition and not to save costs based on higher volumes. It would also have to prove

the absence of any objective justification.

172. The case-law is still not clear on how the ‘all the relevant circumstances’ should be estimated by

dominant undertakings.334 This is important seeing as it forms one of the main steps of the Michelin

I case law. Aspects that have been taken into account are e.g. a long reference period. But under

what circumstances would a reference period be long? It is clear that these ‘loyalty-inducing’ factors

are bad proxies for indicating anti-competitive effects on the relevant market, as has been shown in

British Airways case where the market share of the competitor was not badly affected (on the

contrary rather).

173. The Michelin I line of case law was developed in a specific factual context.335 In essence, it involved

a target rebate (in the Michelin I case, individualized and not transparent) which require a different

approach than quantity rebates (see Hoffmann La Roche). The Court analyzed whether the target

rebate had a similar purpose as a loyalty rebate. It is not hard to imagine that individual target rebates

are offered to customers in order to foreclose competitors. However with regards to standardized

quantity rebates based on the volume of sales, it is harder to make the same argument.336

174. Colomo argues that applying the Michelin I to volume-based rebate schemes reverses the burden of

proof on dominant undertakings.337 Namely, based on Hoffmann La Roche quantity rebate schemes

were presumed to be economically justified. However as is clear from Michelin II, the Court decided

to skip that presumption and in turn, put the burden of proof again with the dominant undertaking:

“It is then necessary to examine whether the applicant has established that the quantity rebate

system, which presents the characteristics of a loyalty-inducing rebate system, was based on

objective economic reasons (see, in that regard, Irish Sugar v Commission, cited at paragraph 54

above, paragraph 188, and Portugal v Commission, cited at paragraph 58 above, paragraph 56).

“338

334 Ibid. 335 See paraghraph 92 and following. 336 Colomo (n212) 11. 337 Ibid. 12. 338 Michelin II (n109) paragraph 107.

Page 73: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

67

175. The main concern or presumption with loyalty rebates is that they are fueled by the same incentives

as exclusive purchasing obligations, i.e. anti-competitive intent. However in the Michelin II for

example it has been proven that this was not the case.339

176. Based on the foregoing paragraphs, applying the Michelin I test to quantity rebates would not be

desirable.340 From Michelin I it follows that it is possible for the competition authorities to brand a

rebate scheme as ‘loyalty-inducing’, without an assessment of the concrete anti-competitive effect,

for it to be contrary to Article 102 TFEU. Colomo argues that this is clearly not an administrable

test.341 With regards to quantity rebates, the Court of Justice should therefore move away from the

‘by object’ prohibition under Article 102 TFEU.

177. A new approach to quantity rebates under Article 102 TFEU should therefore involve the Hoffmann-

La Roche assumption, i.e. the assumption that quantity rebates are legal. A quantity rebate should

only be seen as contrary to Article 102 TFEU when, applied by a dominant undertaking, it is possible

for it to exclude equally efficient competitors. 342

178. With the Post Danmark II judgement, the Court received a chance to change its heavily criticized

case-law concerning rebate schemes in the light of Article 102 TFEU. It could have already had

this opportunity, had the judgement of the General Court in Michelin II been appealed.

Unfortunately, this was not the case. In the following chapter the Post Danmark II case and its

impact on the state of standardized quantity rebates will be analyzed.

6.1 A NEW LEGAL FRAMEWORK FOR REBATE SCHEMES

179. As indicated in the introduction to this chapter, a possible solution would be to adopt the line of case

law held in selective price cuts and margin squeeze cases. These are two types of conduct that can

potentially cause foreclosure on the relevant market.

339M. MOTTA “‘Michelin II: The Treatment of Rebates” in LYONS, B. Cases in European Competition Policy:

The Economic Analysis, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 2009, 86. 340 Colomo (n212) 10. 341 Colomo (n212) 14. 342 Colomo (n212) 18.

Page 74: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

180. Selective price cutting is essentially a form of predatory pricing. Predatory pricing is generally seen

as pricing policy whereby the goals is to force competitors of the market. Selective price cutting is

defined as follows by Latham & Watkins as follows:

“Predation can take the form of selective price-cutting when the predator imposes below-

cost prices to a competitor’s customers or to customers that would otherwise desert to a

competitor while leaving other prices to other existing customers at a higher level.”343

181. Jones & Suffrin define margin squeezs as follows:

“A margin squeeze occurs where a vertically integrated undertaking which is dominant

the upstream market for an input sets its prices at such a level that its competitors on the

downstream market cannot compete with it for the supply of products or services to

customers.”344

182. With regards to margin squeezes and selective price cuts, the EU institutions apply a legal standard

instead of a rule when it assesses conduct under Article 102 TFEU.345 With respect to these types of

abuses the Court will investigate whether there are in fact anti-competitive effects detectable on the

relevant market. See to that extent paragraph 61paragraph 61 of the TeliaSonera Sverige346 case:

“ It must be observed in that regard that, bearing in mind the concept of abuse of a

dominant position explained in paragraph 27 of this judgment, the Court has ruled out

the possibility that the very existence of a pricing practice of a dominant undertaking

which leads to the margin squeeze of its equally efficient competitors can constitute an

abuse within the meaning of Article 102 TFEU without it being necessary to demonstrate

343 ROSENBLATT, H., ARMENGOD, H., A. “Post Danmark: predatory pricing in the European Union”, The

European Anti-Trust Review 2013, 21-24. 344 Jones & Suffrin (n87) 426. 345 COLOMO, P., “Intel and Article 102 TFEU Case Law: Making Sense of a Perpetual Controversy”, LSE

Working Papers, 4. 346 TeliaSonera, C-52/09, ECLI:EU:C:2011:83.

Page 75: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

69

an anti-competitive effect (see, to that effect, Deutsche Telekom v Commission,

paragraphs 250 and 251).”347

183. A good example on how selective price cuts are assessed, is the Post Danmark I case. In this case it

involved Post Danmark348 applying selective price cuts towards specific customers, to the alleged

detriment of certain competitors.349 In its assessment, the Court could rely on the case-law on

predatory pricing, of which the AKZO350 case is the most important one. In paragraphs 71 and 72

the Court of the AKZO judgment it established a reasoning that has been confirmed in following

cases concerning predatory pricing. 351

It said the following:

“Prices below average variable costs (that is to say, those which vary depending on the

quantities produced) by means of which a dominant undertaking seeks to eliminate a

competitor must be regarded as abusive. A dominant undertaking has no interest in

applying such prices except that of eliminating competitors so as to enable it subsequently

to raise its prices by taking advantage of its monopolistic position, since each sale

generates a loss, namely the total amount of the fixed costs (that is to say, those which

remain constant regardless of the quantities produced) and, at least, part of the variable

costs relating to the unit produced.”

“Moreover, prices below average total costs, that tis to say, fixed costs plus variable

costs, but above average variable costs, must be regarded as abusive if they are

determined as part of a plan for eliminating a competitor. Such prices can drive from the

market undertakings which are perhaps as efficient as the dominant undertaking but

which, because of their smaller financial resources are incapable of withstanding the

competition waged against them”.352

184. In paragraph 40 of the Post Danmark I judgment the Court added:

347 TeliaSonera, C-52/09, ECLI:EU:C:2011:83, paragraph 61. 348 the same dominant undertaking as in Post Danmark II. 349 Post Danmark I, C-209/10, ECLI:EU:C:2012:172. 350 AKZO, C-62/86, ECLI:EU:C:1991:286. 351 See Post Danmark I, C-209/10, ECLI:EU:C:2012:172. 352 AKZO (n365) paragraph 70 – 71.

Page 76: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

“If the court making the reference, after carrying out that assessment, should

nevertheless make a finding of anti-competitive effects due to Post Danmark’s actions, it

should be recalled that it is open to a dominant undertaking to provide justification for

behaviour that is liable to be caught by the prohibition under Article 82 EC (see, to this

effect, Case 27/76 United Brands and United Brands Continentaal v Commission [1978]

ECR 207, paragraph 184; Joined Cases C-241/91 P and C-242/91 P RTE and

ITP v Commission [1995] ECR I-743, paragraphs 54 and 55; and TeliaSonera Sverige,

paragraphs 31 and 75).”353

185. Based on the aforementioned paragraphs, the test for selective-price cuts is therefore either the

finding of anti-competitive effects354 or prices below the average variable costs.355 It is, just like

margin squeezes, subject to a legal standard instead of a legal rule.356

186. Within the two lines of law there is an analysis of ‘all the relevant circumstances’357. There are

however differences between the two approaches. The analysis in selective price cut cases is

objective where the analysis in rebate cases is subjective.358 Objective in the sense that the

exclusionary effect is inferred “because of their impact on the behavior of individual customers”.359

187. The case law concerning margin squeezes and selective price cuts can be relevant to rebates seeing

as they both take the form of price-based conduct.360 With regards to quantity rebates, there are no

requirements expected from the customer. Quantity rebates in the true sense of the word, do not

require the customer to buy a certain amount.361 Colomo is for this reason of the opinion that quantity

rebates should be assessed in the same manner as margin squeezes and selective price cuts.362 Put

into concrete terms, this would mean that a new more viable test for quantity rebates under Article

102 TFEU would be that a quantity rebate scheme could only be illegal under EU competition law

if the pricing is under a certain cost measure.363

353 Post Danmark I, C-209/10, ECLI:EU:C:2012:172, paragraph 40. 354 Ibid., paragraph 34-39. 355 Colomo (n212) 8. 356 Colomo (n133) 29. 357 See for example paragraph Michelin I paragraph 54 for rebates and paragraph 26 Post Danmark I. 358 Colomo (n133) 29. 359 Ibid. 360 Colomo (n212) 4. 361 Colomo (n212) 9. 362 Colomo (n133) 9. 363 Colomo (n133) 9.

Page 77: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

71

188. Selective price cut cases like, Post Danmark I, often have a lot in common with cases concerning

‘loyalty-inducing rebates’.364 In Post Danmark I several parties (including the Commission) argued

that selective price cuts should be treated in a same manner as loyalty rebate:

“In contrast, FK, the Danish and Italian Governments, the EFTA Surveillance Authority

and to a certain extent the Commission, take the opposite view, particularly after the

clarification of its position made by the latter at the hearing. In broad outline, those

interested parties submit that, irrespective of costs, selective pricing by a dominant

undertaking in relation to customers of its only genuine competitor leads, or may very

likely lead, to the exclusion of the latter if such pricing is not justified on economic

grounds, particularly economies of scale. That is said to be the situation in the main

proceedings.”365

189. Applying the selective price-cuts principles to quantity rebates would imply that a quantity rebate

would be per se abusive when it does not pass the AKZO test provided in paragraph 71. With regards

to quantity rebates, dominant undertakings should be able to compete on the merits. With regards

to selective-price cut this was affirmed in Post Danmark I:

“Thus, not every exclusionary effect is necessarily detrimental to competition (see, by

analogy, TeliaSonera Sverige, paragraph 43). Competition on the merits may, by

definition, lead to the departure from the market or the marginalization of competitors

that are less efficient and so less attractive to consumers from the point of view of, among

other things, price, choice, quality or innovation.”366

190. This would mean that only when equally efficient undertakings are likely or actually being affected

by the conduct that the rebate would be contrary to Article 102 TFEU. When a dominant supplier

offers above-cost rebates its equally efficient competitors would in theory be able to compete on the

merits with the dominant undertaking.

364 Colomo (n212) 9. 365 Post Danmark I, C-209/10, ECLI:EU:C:2012:172, Opinion of Advocate General Mengozzi, paragraph 52. 366 Post Danmark I (n86) paragraph 22.

Page 78: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

191. A ‘by effect’ approach of rebates under Article 102 TFEU would improve the consistency between

Article 102 and 101 TFEU. This is important because they do not only serve the same goal367 but

also because it is possible to assess one type of conduct under both articles.368 The Van den Bergh369

case being a good example of this.

192. Adopting a ‘by effect’ standard would imply that the national competition authorities and courts

would have to assess the effects of the conduct. A direct consequence would therefore be that this

would take up time and resources, two scarce commodities. This is one of the arguments in

maintaining the status quo.370 Colomo argues however that the current rule potentially chills

competition and over enforcement, which in turn could involve extra costs for society.

193. Moreover, it is not a full blown economic analysis that is required under the ‘by effect’ standard.

Insights from economics could provide guidance in the assessment. This is also not required in the

Guidance Paper:

“The Commission will normally intervene under Article 82 where, on the basis of cogent and

convincing evidence, the allegedly abusive conduct is likely to lead to anti-competitive

foreclosure…”371

6.2 SUMMARY CONCLUSION

194. There are several issues concerning the application of the Michelin I – test to quantity rebates. First,

the Michelin I case did not involve quantity rebates nor an exclusivity rebate. Therefore the case

concerned a different factual context. Second, the presumption of legality as held in Hoffmann La

Roche is not respected with this approach. Third, it is not clear for dominant undertakings how to

assess ‘all the relevant circumstances’ beforehand. This concept is, as the case-law stands now, too

vague. The fact that this is developed on a case-by-case basis does not help. Fourth, not respecting

the presumption of legality of quantity rebates implies that the burden of proof is reversed. Dominant

undertakings would have to proof that their quantity rebate scheme is economically justified while

in the past this was assumed.

367 Continental Can, Case 6-72, ECLI:EU:C:1973:22, paragraph 25. 368 L. PEEPERKORN, “Conditional pricing: Why the General Court is wrong in Intel and what the Court of Justice

can do to rebalance the assessment of rebates”, Concurrences Review 2015,43-63; COLOMO, P., “Intel and Article

102 TFEU Case Law: Making Sense of a Perpetual Controversy”, LSE Working Papers, 45. 369 Van Den Bergh, T-65/98, ECLI:EU:T:2003:281. 370 Colomo (n133) 28. 371 Paragraph 20, Guidance Paper.

Page 79: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

73

195. The case law on selective price cuts and margin squeezes could be used as an example for the

assessment of rebates under Article 102 TFEU. In these cases the Court applies a ‘by effect’

approach rather than a ‘by object’. This implies that potential anti-competitive effects will have to

be proven if rebate schemes are to be found abusive. The Court should therefore revise its case law

and do away with its form based approach. A new approach should be in line with Hoffmann La

Roche, therefore quantity rebates should be presumed to be legal. When applying the reasoning from

AKZO, a quantity rebate scheme could be contrary to Article 102 if the rebate leads to a pricing level

below average costs.372

7.1 FACTS

196. In the Post Danmark II case373 the Court of Justice of the European Union (hereafter ‘the Court’)

was asked by the Danish Sø-og Handelsretten (Maritime and Commercial Court) for a preliminary

ruling on the interpretation of Article 102 TFEU. The facts leading up to the preliminary ruling will

be discussed below.

197. Post Danmark A/S (hereafter ‘Post Danmark’) is a Danish company responsible for the postal

service in Denmark. In the period between 2007 and 2008 the company was controlled by the Danish

State and was inter alia responsible for the one-day universal postal service including bulk mail,

weighing less than 2 kg. The Danish government imposed a tariff scheme on Post Danmark A/S,

whereby the prices of services covered by the universal service obligation could not differ according

to the places of destination.374

198. In return for this imposed tariff scheme and universal service obligation, Post Danmark A/S received

a statutory monopoly on a broad range of services. These included the distribution of letters, but

also the delivery of bulk mail, direct advertising mail375 e.g., weighing up to 50 grams.376

372 Colomo, post danmark ii, pagina 18. 373 Post Danmark II, C-23/14, ECLI:EU:C:2015:651 374 Post Danmark II, C-23/14, ECLI:EU:C:2015:651, paragraph 3. 375 Direct mail is a synonym for advertising mail, that is the delivery of advertisements through postal mail. 376 Post Danmark II, C-23/14, ECLI:EU:C:2015:651, paragraph 4.

Page 80: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

199. In 2003, at a time where Post Danmark was the only company active in the market of bulk mail in

Denmark, Post Danmark implemented a standardized377 rebate scheme in respect of direct

advertising.378 It was standardized in the sense that the conditions for the rebates were public and

were offered to all the customers of Post Danmark.

200. The rebate scheme contained several “steps” starting from a 6% rebate for customers ordering more

than 30,000 letters over a reference period of a year leading up to a maximum rebate of 16% for

orders exceeding 2,000,000 letters per year. In between the minimum and maximum rebates, were

eight other rebate levels, depending on the aggregate number of orders placed within a reference

year. Advocate General Kokott clarifies in her opinion379: “In the case of the first seven rebate levels,

the discount increased by one percentage point per level, and in the case of the last two rebate

levels, by two percentage points per level reaching the maximum rate of 16%”.380

201. At the beginning of each year, Post Danmark and its customers made agreements on the expected

quantities of mailings that year.381 When agreements were made, the rebates were invoiced based

on those estimations. However, if at the end of the reference year, the customer did not order the

estimated quantities, it had to reimburse Post Danmark.382

202. In her opinion Advocate General Kokott notes that “the rebate scheme made no distinction in regard

to whether the mailings were covered by Post Danmark’s monopoly or whether there was a

competitor operating in the area in question”.383 In accordance with its obligations vis-à-vis the

Danish government, it applied the rebate scheme to all advertising mail bearing the address of the

addressee, regardless of whether the mail was covered by the Post Denmark’s monopoly.

203. On 1 Janauary 2007 Bring Citymail Danmark A/S (hereafter ‘Bring Citymail’) began delivering

direct advertising mail in Denmark. Bring Citymail is a subsidiary of Post Norge A/S, a Norwegian

377 Standardized target rebates are schemes where all customers are set the same target and get the same rebates,

see Jones & Suffrin (n87) 455. 378 Post Danmark II, C-23/14, ECLI:EU:C:2015:651, paragraph 6. 379 Post Danmark II, C-23/14, ECLI:EU:C:2015:651, opinion of AG Kokott. 380 Ibid., paragraph 11. 381 Ibid., paragraph 8. 382 Ibid., paragraph 12. 383 Post Danmark II, C-23/14, ECLI:EU:C:2015:651, opinion of AG Kokott, paragraph 10.

Page 81: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

75

postal service. 384 The only competitor active in the Danish market for the delivery of advertising

mail in bulk was Post Danmark.385

204. In the period of 2010 Bring Citymail suffered heavy losses and as a result had to withdraw its

activities from the Danish market. It filed a complaint with the Konkurrencerådet (Danish

Competition Council), stating that Post Danmark had abused its dominant position on the market

for the delivery of bulk mail. 386

205. The Konkurrencerådet found, by a decision of 24 June 2009, that Post Danmark had indeed abused

its dominant position on the aforementioned market by applying the rebate scheme, in 2007 and

2008, in respect of direct advertising mail. According to the Konkurrencerådet, the rebate scheme

had a foreclosing effect on the market and tied customers to Post Danmark. It was of the opinion

that Post Danmark had no way of proving any economic justification for the rebate scheme, i.e. it

failed to prove that there were efficiency gains that benefited consumers and that those gains

neutralized the restrictive effect of the rebate on competition. 387

206. In its judgement, the Konkurrencerådet also referred to the characteristics of the bulk mail market.

The relevant market was characterized by economies of scale and high barriers of entry. In this

market, Post Danmark held a share of almost 95%. As a result the Konkurrencerådet found that Post

Danmark was an unavoidable trading partner. 388

207. Most problematic for the Konkurrencerådet was the fact that the rebate scheme had a retroactive

nature with a one-year period for the acquisition of rights and the amplitude of the rebate rates

applied.389 The Konkurrencerådet thus concluded that the rebate scheme had an anti-competitive

exclusionary effect on the market.

208. Konkurrencerådet did not apply an ‘as-efficient-competitor’ test in its reasoning. Seeing as the

relevant market had certain characteristics (high barrier of entry, economies of scale e.g.), it could

384 Ibid., paragraph 10. 385 Ibid., paragraph 11. 386 Ibid., paragraph 13. 387 Post Danmark II, C-23/14, ECLI:EU:C:2015:651, paragraph 13. 388 Ibid., paragraph 14. 389 Post Danmark II, C-23/14, ECLI:EU:C:2015:651, paragraph 16.

Page 82: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

not be required, for the purposes of the test, that a new competitor be as efficient in the short term

as Post Danmark.390

209. Post Danmark appealed the decision of the Konkurrencerådet to the Konkurrenceankenævnet

(Competition Appeals Tribunal). By decision of 10 May 2010, it upheld the first instance decision.

210. The case was then brought before the Sø-og Handelsretten (Maritime and Commercial Court). The

Sø-og Handelsretten had doubts concerning the criteria it had to take into account to determine

whether the rebate scheme, had an exclusionary effect on the relevant market contrary to art. 82 EC

(now art. 102 TFEU). 391

211. The Sø-og Handelsretten therefore referred the following questions to the Court of Justice392:

“What guidelines should be used to decide whether the application by a dominant

undertaking of a rebate scheme with a standardized volume threshold having the

characteristics referred to in the order for reference constitutes an abuse of a dominant

position contrary to Article 82 EC?

In its answer the Court is requested to clarify what relevance it has to the assessment

whether the rebate scheme’s thresholds are set in such a way that the rebate scheme

applies to the majority of customers on the market.

In its answer the Court is further requested to clarify what relevance, if any, the dominant

undertaking’s prices and costs have to the evaluation pursuant to Article 82 EC of such

a rebate scheme (relevance of an “as-efficient-competitor” test).

At the same time the Court is requested to clarify what relevance the characteristics of

the market have in this connection, including whether the characteristics of the market

can justify the foreclosure effect being demonstrated by examinations and analyses other

than an as-efficient-competitor test (see, in that regard, paragraph 24 of the

[communication from the Commission entitled “Guidance on the Commission’s

enforcement priorities in applying Article 82 of the EC Treaty to abusive exclusionary

conduct by dominant undertakings” (OJ 2009 C 45, p. 7)].

390 Ibid., paragraph 17. 391 Ibid., paragraph 19. 392 Ibid., paragraph 20.

Page 83: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

77

(2) How probable and serious must the anti-competitive effect of a rebate scheme having

the characteristics referred to in the order for reference be for Article 82 EC to apply?

(3) Having regard to the answers given to Questions 1 and 2, what specific circumstances

must the national court take into account in assessing whether a rebate scheme, in

circumstances such as those described in the order for reference (characteristics of the

market and the rebate scheme), has or is capable of having such a foreclosure effect in

the specific case that it constitutes an abuse covered by Article 82 EC?

In this connection, is it a requirement that the foreclosure effect should be appreciable?”

7.2 OPINION AG KOKOTT

212. In her Opinion393 delivered on 21 may 2015, Advocate General Kokott sets off with examining the

first part of the first question of the preliminary ruling, being the applicable rules to the assessment

of rebates schemes operated by dominant undertakings.394 She recognizes that dominant

undertakings are in a special position as they are not free to apply every marketing technique as they

desire, there are certain restrictions when compared to non-dominant undertakings.395 A rebate

scheme which can be seen as an exclusionary abuse , applied by a non-dominant undertaking, will

be legal whereas this is not necessarily true for dominant undertakings. Whether the rebate scheme

applied by a dominant undertaking implies an extensive investigation.396

213. Advocate General Kokott then refers to the settled case law involving the legality of rebates within

the meaning of art. 102 TFEU.397 In the Intel case, the General Court gave a taxonomy of the

categories of rebates.398 She states, however, that it is “ultimately immaterial whether the scheme

can be assigned to a traditional category of rebate”.399 The Advocate General is of the opinion that

the only deciding factor is whether “the rebates seek to remove or restrict the buyer’s freedom to

choose his sources of supply, to bar competitors from access to the market, or to strengthen the

dominant position by distorting competition”. 400

393 Post Danmark II, C-23/14, ECLI:EU:C:2015:651, opinion of AG Kokott. 394 Ibid., paragraph 22. 395 Ibid., paragraph 25. 396 Ibid., paragraph 27. 397 Ibid., paragraph 28. 398 Intel (n295) paragraph 75. 399 Post Danmark II, C-23/14, ECLI:EU:C:2015:651, opinion of AG Kokott. 400 Post Danmark II, C-23/14, ECLI:EU:C:2015:651, opinion of AG Kokott, paragraph 29.

Page 84: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

214. The main deciding factor is thus whether the rebate granted by the dominant undertaking is capable

of producing on the relevant market an exclusionary effect which is not economically justified. 401

According to the Advocate General this would only be the case when the undertaking can save

certain costs, caused by economies of scale, which are then passed on the customers.402 The

Advocate-general is therefore clearly in favor of maintaining the form-based approach.

215. To determine whether or not the rebate scheme is capable of producing an exclusionary effect, all

the relevant circumstances of the individual case have to be examined.403 In the first part of the third

prejudicial question, the Sø-og Handelsretten asked the Court to shine a light on the circumstances

it has to take in account when examining the legality of rebate schemes.404

216. Advocate General Kokott distills several deciding factors originating from case law for assessing a

rebate scheme under art. 102 TFEU.405 First, she discusses the criteria and rules governing the grant

of the rebate. Second, she comments on the conditions of competition prevailing on the relevant

market and the position of the dominant undertaking on that market.406

217. It would be impossible for the Court to list an extensive list of criteria and rules governing the grant

of a rebate. However, Advocate General Kokott states that when the effect of the rebate scheme is

not purely incremental407 and is retroactive, there is an indication that the rebate scheme is

abusive.408

218. The reason for this is that such a rebate scheme has, in her opinion, a ‘suction effect’.409 The

customer have a monetary incentive to stay loyal to the dominant undertaking, i.e. it has a ‘loyalty-

building effect’. In this case, the Advocate General, argues that there was an indication of a strong

suction effect due to the rebates were being granted retroactively over a reference period of one

401 Ibid., paragraph 29. 402 Ibid., paragraph 29. 403 Ibid., paragraph 31. 404 Ibid., paragraph 32. 405 Ibid., paragraph 35. 406 Ibid., paragraph 35. 407 “Incremental in the sense that the achievement of each new rebate threshold not only triggers a reduction in

the price of all further orders” see Post Danmark II, C-23/14, ECLI:EU:C:2015:651, opinion of AG Kokott,

paragraph 36. 408 Ibid., paragraph 36. 409 Ibid., paragraph 21.

Page 85: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

79

year.410 The fact that the rebate applied “without distinction both to the contestable part of demand

and to the non-contestable part of demand, that is to say, in particular letters up to 50g, which are

covered by Post Danmark’s statutory monopoly” was further proof for the Advocate General for

the loyalty-building effect of the rebate.411

219. Next, special attention has to be given to the position of the undertaking on the relevant market and

the prevailing conditions of competition.412 The Advocate General notes that Post Danmark has held

a share of 95% of the Danish bulk market versus the 5% of Bring Citymail.413 The conditions

prevailing on the Danish bulk market are so that, according to the Advocate General, the rebate

scheme applied by Post Danmark could produce exclusionary effects. 414 The reasons for this are:

the high barrier to entry of the relevant market, the high economies of scale and the fact that Post

Danmark could be seen as unavoidable trading partner.415

220. There rebate scheme took away monetary incentives of the customer to change to the competition

of Post Danmark. Two thirds of the mailings were open to competition, but a change in postal

supplier would entail a loss of the rebate for the customers concerned. This further adds to the illicit

nature of the rebate scheme from the point of view of art. 102 TFEU. 416417

221. In the second part of the first prejudicial question, the Sø-og Handelsretten asked for clarity on the

question whether widespreadness of the rebate scheme operated by Post Danmark added to the

abusive nature of the rebate scheme. The referring court points out to the fact that the rebate is

standardized and thus applies to a large quantity of customers on the market (i.e. Post Danmark did

not target individual customers).418

410 Post Danmark II, C-23/14, ECLI:EU:C:2015:651, opinion of AG Kokott, paragraph 38. 411 Ibid., paragraph 38. 412 Ibid., paragraph 42. 413 Ibid., paragraph 42. 414 Ibid., paragraph 50. 415 Ibid., paragraph 46. 416 Ibid., paragraph 49. 417 Ibid., paragraph 49. 418 Ibid., paragraph 51.

Page 86: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

222. In several other cases concerning the legality of rebate schemes in the light of art. 102 TFEU, the

Court has already rebutted this.419 In conclusion the widespreadness of the rebate is irrelevant when

assessing the abusive nature of a rebate scheme under art. 102 TFEU. 420

223. Based on the foregoing, the Advocate General concludes the following:

“A rebate scheme operated by a dominant undertaking constitutes abuse within the

meaning of Article 82 EC (now art. 102 TFEU) where an overall assessment of all the

circumstances of the individual case shows that the rebates are capable of producing an

economically unjustified exclusionary effect, it being important to take into account in

that regard, in particular, the criteria and rules governing the grant of the rebate, the

conditions of competition prevailing on the relevant market and the position of the

dominant undertaking on that market.”421

224. In the last part of her opinion, the Advocate General discusses the second question of the prejudicial

question. It involves the question whether there has to be a certain ‘appreciability’ of the anti-

competitive effect in order to conclude there is an abuse under art. 102 TFEU. 422 She dissects the

prejudicial question into two parts. First, she considers the likelihood of the presence of an anti-

competitive effect caused by a rebate scheme. Second, the seriousness of the likely anti-competitive

effect.423

225. With regards to the likelihood of the anti-competitive effect, the Advocate General refers to previous

case law where the Court has already decided in the Michelin I case that “for the purposes of

establishing an infringement of Article 82 EC (now art. 102 TFEU), it is sufficient to show that the

abusive conduct of the undertaking in a dominant position tends to restrict competition or, in other

words, that the conduct is capable of having that effect.”424 In her opinion the Advocate General

therefore concludes that there is no reason why the competition authorities should take the likelihood

419 Suiker Unie, C-40/73, ECLI:EU:C:1975:174, paragraph 511. 420 Post Danmark II, C-23/14, ECLI:EU:C:2015:651, opinion of AG Kokott, paragraph 54. 421 Post Danmark II, C-23/14, ECLI:EU:C:2015:651, opinion of AG Kokott, paragraph 55. 422 Ibid., paragraph 76. 423 Ibid., paragraph 78. 424 Michelin I (n75) paragraph 39.

Page 87: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

81

of anti-competitive effects into account. It can however play a role when the competent competition

authority has to decide on a punishment. 425

226. Lastly, the Advocate General answers the question whether art. 102 TFEU includes a de minimis

test, in the sense that the restriction on competition has to reach a certain threshold in order to

conclude to a violation of art. 102 TFEU.426 She is of the opinion that a de minimis threshold is

unnecessary for two reasons. First, she reaffirms her stance that the exclusionary effect have to be

determined, based on all the relevant circumstances.427 Secondly, she reminds the reader that art.

102 TFEU is only geared towards conduct that is capable of affecting trade between Member

States.428

227. Based on the foregoing, her opinion concludes with the following:

“1. A rebate scheme operated by a dominant undertaking constitutes abuse within the

meaning of Article 82 EC where an overall assessment of all the circumstances of the

individual case shows that the rebates are capable of producing an economically

unjustified exclusionary effect, it being important to take into account in that regard, in

particular, the criteria and rules governing the grant of the rebate, the conditions of

competition prevailing on the relevant market and the position of the dominant

undertaking on that market.

3. Aside from the requirement that a rebate scheme operated by a dominant undertaking

must have an actual or potential adverse effect on trade between Member States, the

exclusionary effect that may be produced by such a scheme does not have to exceed any

form of appreciability (de minimis) threshold in order to be classified as abuse within the

meaning of Article 82 EC. It is sufficient for the presence of such an exclusionary effect

to be more likely that its absence.”429

425 Ibid., paragraph 85. 426 Ibid., paragraph 87. 427 Ibid.,, paragraph 93. 428 Post Danmark II, C-23/14, ECLI:EU:C:2015:651, opinion of AG Kokott, paragraph 93. 429 Ibid., paragraph 96.

Page 88: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

7.3 THE JUDGEMENT OF THE COURT

228. In its judgement of 6 october 2015, the Court answered the prejudicial questions430 asked by the Sø-

og Handelsretten.431 For the facts of the proceedings I refer to the overview discussed before.432 The

Court first discusses the first and second paragraphs of prejudicial question 1 and the first

subparagraph of Question 3.433 Secondly, the Court considers the third and fourth subparagraphs of

Question 1.434435 Lastly, it investigates Question 2 and the second subparagraph of Question 3.436

229. In the first part of its judgement, the Court answers the question what the criteria are that have to be

taken into account when deciding on the exclusionary effect of a rebate scheme under art. 102

TFEU.437 In the first subparagraph of Question 3, the referring court also asks what the relevance is

of the fact that the rebate scheme is applicable to the majority of customers on the market.438

230. The Courts starts off by assessing the features of the rebate scheme operated by Post Danmark.439It

notes that it has three main features being that the rebate scheme is: standardised440, conditional441

and retroactive442. The rebate scheme under investigation therefore shares a lot of similarities with

the rebate scheme found to be abusive in the Michelin II judgment.443

231. In the Intel case the General Court made a distinction between several kinds of rebates. See to that

extent paragraph 74:

“ As regards in particular whether the grant of a rebate by an undertaking in a dominant

position can be characterized as abusive, a distinction should be drawn between three

categories of rebates (see, to that effect, Case 322/81 Nederlandsche Banden-Industrie-

430 See paragraph 16. 431 Post Danmark II, C-23/14, ECLI:EU:C:2015:651. 432 See paragraph 1 and following. 433 Post Danmark II, C-23/14, ECLI:EU:C:2015:651, paragraph 21. 434 Ibid., paragraph 51. 435 Discussed in paragraphs 48 and following. 436 Post Danmark II, C-23/14, ECLI:EU:C:2015:651, paragraph 63. 437 Post Danmark II, C-23/14, ECLI:EU:C:2015:651, paragraph 21. 438 Ibid., paragraph 21. 439 Ibid.,, paragraph 22. 440 Ibid., paragraph 23. 441 Ibid., paragraph 24. 442 Ibid., paragraph 25. 443 Michelin II (n109).

Page 89: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

83

Michelin v Commission [1983] ECR 3461 (‘Michelin I’), paragraphs 71 to 73, and Case

C-95/04 P British Airways v Commission [2007] ECR I-2331 (‘Case C-95/04 P British

Airways’), paragraphs 62, 63, 65, 67 and 68). “444

232. In her opinion Advocate General Kokkott did not agree with this approach, as can be seen from

paragraph 29 of her Opinion:

“For the purposes of assessing the rebate scheme operated by a dominant undertaking

from the point of view of Article 82 EC, however, it is ultimately immaterial whether the

scheme can be assigned to a traditional category of rebate (in particular, quantity rebates

or loyalty rebates). The decisive criterion is, rather, whether, in providing an advantage

not based on any economic supply justifying it, the rebates seek to remove or restrict the

buyer’s freedom to choose his sources of supply, to bar competitors from access to the

market, or to strengthen the dominant position by distorting competition. “445

233. In paragraph 27, the Court reiterates the Hoffmann La Roche446 distinction between quantity rebates

and loyalty rebates.447 According to this line of case law, loyalty rebates are per se illegal.448 Whereas

loyalty rebates are presumed to be illegal, quantity rebates that are linked to the volumes of

purchases are not. The Court therefore disagrees with Advocate General Kokott as it still adhere to

a system of distinguishing several types of rebates in its judgment.

234. Seeing as the rebates are granted on the basis of the aggregate orders over a given period, the Court

is of the opinion that the rebate in question cannot be considered as a plain quantity rebate coupled

to the volume of purchases.449 There was however no contractual obligation for the customers of

Post Danmark to obtain all or a specific amount of their purchases from Post Danmark. Therefore,

the Court concludes that the rebate scheme can neither be seen as a loyalty rebate in the sense of the

Hoffman La Roche case.450

444 Intel (n295) paragraph 74. 445 Post Danmark II, C-23/14, ECLI:EU:C:2015:651, opinion of AG Kokott, paragraph 29. 446 Hoffmann La Roche (n83) paragraph 90. 447 Post Danmark II, C-23/14, ECLI:EU:C:2015:651, paragraph 27. 448 Jones & Suffrin (n87) 458. 449 Post Danmark II, C-23/14, ECLI:EU:C:2015:651, paragraph 28. 450 Ibid., paragraph 28.

Page 90: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

235. The Court therefore resorts back to the Michelin I case-law451, where it also concerned a rebate

scheme that could neither be categorized as a loyalty rebate nor as a quantity rebate linked to the

volume of purchases. To solve this the Court has adopted the following reasoning in previous case

law452:

“In those circumstances, in order to determine whether the dominant undertaking in a

dominant position has abused that position by applying a rebate scheme such as that at

issue in the main proceedings, the Court has repeatedly held that it is necessary to

consider all the circumstances, particularly the criteria and rules governing the grant of

the rebate, and to investigate whether, in providing an advantage not based on any

economic service justifying it, the rebate tens to remove or restrict the buyer’s freedom

to choose his sources of supply, to bar competitors from access to the market, to apply

dissimilar conditions to equivalent transactions with other trading parties or to

strengthen the dominant position by distorting competition.”.453

“Having regard to the particularities of the present case, it is also necessary to take into

account, in examining all the relevant circumstances, the extent of Post Danmark’s

dominant position and the particular conditions of competition prevailing on the relevant

market.”454

236. Based on the foregoing, the Court applies a double test which can be traced back to earlier case law.

First, it determines whether the rebates can produce an exclusionary effect and secondly it has to

examine whether there is an objective economic justification for the rebates granted.455

237. However, a new added element is to be found in paragraphs 29-30. In Michelin II the General Court

assessed whether the non-conditional rebate had a ‘loyalty-inducing’ effect. The General Court

would have stopped at paragraph 29 in Michelin II but in here in Post Danmark II the Court adds a

new step. When assessing all the relevant circumstances it will take the dominant position of the

undertaking into account and “the particular conditions of competition prevailing on the relevant

451 British Airways (n96) paragraph 65. 452 British Airways, C-95/04, ECLI:EU:C:2007:166. 453 Post Danmark II, C-23/14, ECLI:EU:C:2015:651, paragraph 29. 454 Ibid., paragraph 30. 455 Post Danmark II, C-23/14, ECLI:EU:C:2015:651, paragraph 31; British Airways, C-95/04,

ECLI:EU:C:2007:166. Paragraph 68 – 69.

Page 91: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

85

market”. This added line can be traced back to the opinion of the Advocate General.456 This is not

a revolutionary step as it is in essence just another added ‘circumstance’ the Court can take into

account when assessing the rebate scheme under the Michelin I case law.

238. In paragraph 31, however, a much awaited element is introduced to the case law of the Court:

“In that regard, it first has to be determined whether those rebates can produce an

exclusionary effect, that is to say whether they are capable, first, of making market entry

very difficult or impossible for competitors of the undertaking in a dominant position and,

secondly, of making it more difficult or impossible for the co-contractors of that

undertaking to choose between various sources of supply or commercial partners. It then

has to be examined whether there is an objective economic justification for the discounts

granted (judgment in British Airways v Commission, C-95/04 P, EU:C:2007:166,

paragraphs 68 and 69)”457

239. This marks a tacit departure from the form based approach adhered in Michelin II (by the General

Court) and British Airways (by the ECJ). It would appear that, based on the aforementioned

paragraph, standardized retroactive quantity rebates do not form a prima facie violation of Article

102 TFEU. This would also confirm that there is a distinction between ‘by object’ and ‘by effect’

abuses in Article 102 TFEU. In paragraph 31 the Court states that in order to conclude that the rebate

scheme was abusive it needed to assess whether the rebate was capable of having anti-competitive

effects. This is important as the Court does not assume that the rebate scheme has anti-competitive

effect.

240. The Post Danmark II judgement shows that the Court does not agree with the analysis of the General

Court of standardized rebate schemes in Michelin II.

241. The distinction between the Michelin II judgement of the General Court and the Post Danmark II

judgement is clear in the following paragraphs:

“It follows from all of the foregoing that a quantity rebate system in which there is a

significant variation in the discount rates between the lower and higher steps, which has

456 See paragraph 231 above. 457 Post Danmark II, C-23/14, ECLI:EU:C:2015:651, paragraph 31.

Page 92: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

a reference period of one year and in which the discount is fixed on the basis of total

turnover achieved during the reference period, has the characteristics of a loyalty-

inducing discount system.”458

“It follows that, for the purposes of applying Article 82 EC, establishing the anti-

competitive object and the anti-competitive effect are one and the same thing (see, in that

regard, Irish Sugar v. Commission, cited at paragraph 54 above, paragraph 170). If it is

shown that the object pursued by the conduct of an undertaking in a dominant position

is to limit competition, that conduct will also be liable to have such an effect.”459

242. In the aforementioned paragraphs the General Court assumed that the standardized rebate scheme

(much like the one under scrutiny in Post Danmark II) is an abuse ‘by object’ and it is therefore

assumed that it will have anti-competitive effects. Therefore, whether the rebate scheme had actual

anti-competitive effects on the relevant market or was capable of having such effects was not

relevant for the General Court. This was thus not a viable defense for the dominant undertaking, the

only option left was to show that it had an objective justification of the rebate scheme. I therefore

conclude that in Michelin II the Court first analyzed whether the rebate scheme was ‘loyalty-

inducing’, if this was the case then dominant undertaking could escape the prohibition by proving

an objective justification.

243. In Post Danmark II, the Court applies a two-stage test. For the Court it is not enough to only analyze

the ‘loyalty-inducing’ aspects of the rebate scheme.

“In that regard, it first has to be determined whether those rebates can produce an

exclusionary effect, that is to say whether they are capable, first, of making market entry

very difficult or impossible for competitors of the undertaking in a dominant position and,

secondly, of making it more difficult or impossible for the co-contractors of that

undertaking to choose between various sources of supply or commercial partners. It then

has to be examined whether there is an objective economic justification for the discounts

458 Michelin II (n109) paragraph 95. 459 Michelin II (n109) paragraph 241.

Page 93: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

87

granted (judgment in British Airways v Commission, C-95/04 P, EU:C:2007:166,

paragraphs 68 and 69).”460

244. In its judgement, the Court concludes that the rebate scheme applied by Post Danmark has a likely

exclusionary effect on the relevant market.461462 To come to this conclusion the Court applies the

reasoning mentioned above463 to the facts of the case. The circumstances it took into account were

the following:

the retroactive nature of the rebate scheme464;

the fact that the rebate scheme was based on a reference period of a year465;

for a large amount of Post Danmark’s customers it was economically not interesting to

switch over to a competitor of Post Danmark for fear of loss of the rebates466, i.e. there was

a big incentive to purchase a big portion of their supplies from Post Danmark;

on the bulk mail market, Post Danmark held a dominant position with a market share of

95%467;

Post Danmark enjoyed structural advantages due to its statutory monopoly468;

Post Danmark constituted an unavoidable business partner by reason of its high market

share469;

245. In paragraph 50 the Court further clarified:

“The fact that the rebate scheme covers the majority of customers on the market may

constitute a useful indication as to the extent of that practice and its impact on the market,

which may bear out the likelihood of an anti-competitive exclusionary effect.”470

460 Post Danmark II, C-23/14, ECLI:EU:C:2015:651, paragraph 31. 461 Ibid., paragraph 29. 462 Ibid., paragraph 42. 463 See paragraph 44. 464 Ibid., paragraph 32. 465 Ibid., paragraph 33. 466 Ibid., paragraph 36. 467 Ibid., paragraph 39. 468 Ibid., paragraph 39. 469 Ibid., paragraph 40. 470 Ibid., 50.

Page 94: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

246. If, however, Post Danmark could prove that the exclusionary effect was justified, due to economic

benefits being passed onto its customers, it could avoid persecution under art. 102 TFEU.471 In

earlier case law472 the Court has stated:

“In that last regard, it is for the dominant undertaking to show that the efficiency gains

likely to result from the conduct under consideration counteract any likely negative effects

on competition and consumer welfare in the affected markets, that those gains have been

, or are likely to be, brought about as a result of that conduct, that such conduct is

necessary for the achievement of those gains in efficiency and that it does not eliminate

effective competition, by removing all or most existing sources of actual potential

competition .”473

247. Here, the Court reaffirmed that it was possible for Post Danmark to escape violation of Article 102

TFEU if it managed to present an objective justification:

“In particular, a dominant undertaking may demonstrate that the exclusionary effect

arising from its conduct may be counterbalanced, or outweighed, by advantages in terms

of efficiency which also benefit the consumer (see judgments in British

Airways v Commission, C-95/04 P, EU:C:2007:166, paragraph 86, and TeliaSonera

Sverige, C-52/09, EU:C:2011:83, paragraph 76).”474

248. Concerning whether the likelihood of anti-competitive effects is relevant for the application of art.

102 TFEU, the Court confirms the opinion of the Advocate General.475 Based on earlier case law,

for example the TeliaSonera Sverige476 case, the Court holds that, in order for a certain practices to

fall under the scope of art. 102 TFEU, the conduct has to potentially effect the competition on the

relevant market. Therefore there have to be anti-competitive effects, but they do not have to be

471 Ibid.,, paragraph . 472 Post Danmark I paragraph 42. 473 Post Danmark I, C-209/10, ECLI:EU:C:2012:172., paragraph 42. 474 Ibid., paragraph 48. 475 Post Danmark II, C-23/14, ECLI:EU:C:2015:651, paragraph 67. 476 TeliaSonera, C-52/09, ECLI:EU:C:2011:83., paragpah 64.

Page 95: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

89

concrete. 477 To come to the conclusion that the conduct is capable of having anti-competitive

effects, the competent authority still has to take into account all the relevant circumstances. 478

249. The presence of a dominant undertaking weakens the structure of the market according to the

Court.479 Since the seminal Hoffmann La Roche480 case, this has been confirmed numerous times.481

Based on this fact, the dominant undertaking has to compose itself in a more strict way than other

non-dominant undertakings. In short, it has a “special responsibility not to allow its behavior to

impair genuine, undistorted competition on the internal market”482.483 The structure of the market

already suffers from the presence of the market, therefore any further abuse committed by the

dominant undertaking would further weaken the market. The Court and the Advocate General are

therefore of the opinion that a de minimis test of the anti-competitive effects is not in order.484 As

discussed in previous paragraphs, here the ‘special responsibility’ concept does not have a definitive

legal consequence for Post Danmark.

250. The Court has stated that anti-competitive effects have to be probable. The question is however,

what the threshold is and when it will be crossed. The Court tries to clarify this in the following

paragraphs:

“In that regard, and as the Advocate General stated in point 80 of her Opinion, the anti-

competitive effect of a particular practice must not be of purely hypothetical.

The Court has also held that, in order to establish whether such a practice is abusive,

that practice must have an anti-competitive effect on the market, but the effect does not

necessarily have to be concrete, and it is sufficient to demonstrate that there is an anti-

competitive effect which may potentially exclude competitors who are at least as efficient

as the dominant undertaking (judgment in TeliaSonera Sverige, C-52/09, EU:C:2011:83,

paragraph 64).

477 Post Danmark II, C-23/14, ECLI:EU:C:2015:651, paragraph 66. 478 Ibid., paragraph 68. 479 Ibid., paragraph 71. 480 Hoffman/La Roche, C-85/76, ECLI:EU:C:1979:36, paragraph 123. 481 France Télécom, C-202/07, ECLI:EU:C:2009:214, paragraph 107. 482 Post Danmark I, C-209/10, ECLI:EU:C:2012:172., paragraph 123. 483 For a further discussion in this concept see paragraph 74. 484 Post Danmark II, C-23/14, ECLI:EU:C:2015:651, paragraph 73.

Page 96: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

It follows that only dominant undertakings whose conduct is likely to have an anti-

competitive effect on the market fall within the scope of Article 82 EC.

In that regard, the assessment of whether a rebate scheme is capable of restricting

competition must be carried out in the light of all relevant circumstances, including the

rules and criteria governing the grant of the rebates, the number of customers concerned

and the characteristics of the market on which the dominant undertaking operates.”485

251. In conclusion the Court answered the prejudicial questions in the following way:

“ 1. In order to determine whether a rebate scheme, such as that at issue in the main

proceedings, implemented by a dominant undertaking is capable of having an

exclusionary effect on the market contrary to Article 82 EC, it is necessary to examine

all the circumstances of the case, in particular, the criteria and rules governing the grant

of the rebates, the extent of the dominant position of the undertaking concerned and the

particular conditions of competition prevailing undertaking concerned and the

particular conditions of competition prevailing on the relevant market. The fact that the

rebate scheme covers the majority of customers on the market may constitute a useful

indications to the extent of that practice and its impact on the market, which may bear

out the likelihood of an anti-competitive exclusionary effect.

2. The application of the ‘as-efficient-competitor’ test does not constitute a necessary

condition for a finding to the effect that a rebate scheme is abusive under Article 82 EC.

In a situation such as that in the main proceedings, applying the as-efficient-competitor

test is of no relevance.

3. Article 82 EC must be interpreted as meaning that, in order to fall within the scope of

that article, the anti-competitive effect of a rebate scheme operated by a dominant

undertaking, such as that at issue in the main proceedings must be probable, there being

no need to show that it is of a serious or appreciable nature.”486

252. With the Post Danmark II judgment the Court confirms that, just like in Article 101 TFEU, there is

a ‘by object’ and ‘by effect’ divide between abuses in Article 102 TFEU. Certain forms of abuse

will be considered as an abuse by ‘object’, like exclusivity dealings, loyalty rebates, tying and

bundling, predatory pricing schemes that are below average variable costs. This means that for these

forms of abuse the Court will not assess whether the conduct has potential or actual effect on the

485 Ibid. paragraph. 65-68. 486 Post Danmark II, C-23/14, ECLI:EU:C:2015:651, paragraph 75.

Page 97: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

91

competitive process. The Court considers that these types of conduct have anti-competitive goals as

their object and will therefore be liable to have anti-competitive effects.

253. On the other hand, with other types of conduct like margin squeezes, selective price cuts and, after

the Post Danmark II judgement, standardized retroactive rebates the Court will assess whether the

conduct is capable of having anti-competitive effects. A similar approach as in Article 101 to Article

102 can therefore be inferred.

254. After the Post Danmark II it appears that the Court of Justice took note of the mounting criticism of

its case-law. The judgement appears to be in line with the Guidance Paper published by the

Commission.

7.4 SUMMARY CONCLUSION

255. The Post Danmark II case concerned a standardized retroactive rebate scheme. The Advocate

General reaffirmed previous case law concerning this type of conduct in her opinion. First, in

continuation with Michelin I, ‘all the relevant circumstances’ have to be assessed. In this assessment

the Court should take “the criteria and rules governing the grant of the rebate” into account, namely

“the conditions of competition prevailing on the relevant market and the position of the dominant

undertaking on that market.”487 Second, a violation of Article 102 TFEU could be avoided by Post

Danmark II had it proven the existence of economic efficiencies. Based on previous case-law, she

stated, explicitly, that an assessment of the possible anti-competitive effects is not necessary.

Apparent from Advocate General Kokott’s opinion is that she is not keen on modernizing the legal

framework applied to rebate schemes under Article 102 TFEU. Instead she pleads for a continuation

of the orthodox approach. This is unfortunate as this modernization process needs as much allies in

the EU courts as possible. This was on one hand however to be expected as Advocate General

Kokott can be regarded as an adherent of ordoliberalism.488

256. The European Court of Justice, however, was more ambitious in her judgment than the Advocate

General. In the assessment of the ‘all the relevant circumstances’ it added another ‘circumstance’ to

be taken into consideration, namely the extent of Post Danmark’s dominant position and the

particular conditions of competition prevailing on the relevant market. This was also proposed by

the Advocate General in her opinion.489

487 Post Danmark II, C-23/14, ECLI:EU:C:2015:651, opinion of AG Kokott, paragraph 55. 488 Ibid., paragraph 56-57. 489 Ibid., paragraph 231.

Page 98: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

257. In paragraph 31 the Court required proof that the standardized retroactive rebate scheme can

potentially cause anti-competitive effects. This marks an evolution in comparison to the approach

previously applied by the EU Courts to rebate schemes. In the Michelin II case it concerned a similar

rebate scheme as in Post Danmark II. The General Court did not find it necessary however to assess

the potential negative effects on the market as it resorted to the tried and tested method of Michelin

I.

258. After the Post Danmark II judgement, retroactive standardized quantity rebates will be assessed

under a ‘by effect’ approach as opposed to the previoues ‘by object’ assessment. As clarified in the

judgement, concrete effects do not need to be proven. Moreover, these effects are not subjected to

a de minimis test. Therefore it is not required to show that the anti-competitive effects are of a serious

or appreciable nature.

Page 99: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

93

259. This thesis discussed the development of case law concerning rebate schemes applied by dominant

undertakings under Article 102 TFEU. Starting with the seminal Hoffmann La Roche judgment, the

Court made a distinction between quantity rebates on one hand and loyalty rebates on the other.

According to the Court loyalty rebates had the same impact on the market, and therefore consumer

welfare, as exclusive purchasing obligations. These exclusive purchasing obligations have an

exclusionary effect, according to the Court, when they are applied by a dominant undertaking as

they generally require the customer to purchase all of their requirements from the dominant

undertaking. With regards to loyalty rebates the Court assumed that those kind of rebate schemes

have a similar negative impact on the market as exclusive purchasing obligations. The anti-

competitive effects experienced by the consumer is however not mentioned once. This judgement

started the form-based approach to rebates under Article 102 TFEU. Contrary to exclusivity rebates,

quantity rebates linked solely to the volume of purchases are presumed to be legal.

260. The Hoffmann La Roche judgement was a decisive case for the further development of Article 102

TFEU as its philosophy was repeated in subsequent cases. In following cases the Hoffmann La

Roche reasoning was applied, even though the factual context of those cases was different. The

form-based approach led to questionable results however. The main criticism is that the assumption

regarding the anti-competitive effect of loyalty rebates is contrary to recent economic insights. In

certain circumstances, loyalty rebates can invoke pro-competitive effects. Ignoring this reality

ultimately leads to over-enforcement. EU competition policy is still managed through the rule of

law so understandably certain abstractions have to be me made. Alternative approaches to rebate

schemes are however open to the EU institutions handling these cases. This would involve moving

away from the ‘by object’ violation of Article 102 TFEU to a ‘by effect’ approach of rebate schemes.

261. From a historical point of view there is a basis to adopt a new approach. Recent research, primarily

done by Pinar Akman, has indicated that the drafters of the EU competition rules were not inspired

by ordoliberalism. Consequently, Article 102 TFEU is not an ordoliberal provision of EU

competition law. Ordoliberalism is primarily concerned with the economic freedom of its actors and

consumer welfare is to a lesser effect a priority. To accept ordoliberalism as the guiding philosophy

of Article 102 TFEU would slow the modernization process of Article 102 TFEU. These renewed

insights on the origins of Article 102 TFEU form a teleogical basis for the institutions to reform its

legal framework with regards to rebate schemes. Ordoliberalism, however, still has its adherents in

the EU Courts, Advocate General Kokott being a notable one.

Page 100: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

262. With the Post Danmark I judgment the Court of Justice, in a Grand Chamber session, confirmed

that consumer welfare is the objective of Article 102 TFEU. This would allow for an approach that

takes efficiencies into account.

263. Following the Michelin I judgement the General Court was keen on applying the ‘all the relevant

circumstances’ legal test to quantity rebates. This two stage test was developed in the Michelin I

judgement for the residual category of rebate schemes, i.e. rebate schemes that could not be

categorized as either a quantity rebate or exclusivity rebate within the meaning of Hoffmann La

Roche. This two stage test first assesses whether the rebate scheme has ‘loyalty-inducing’ elements

and second whether there is an objective justification once a violation of Article 102 TFEU has been

found. The General Court again applied a line of case law without regard to its factual context. The

Michelin I case concerned the so called ‘target rebates’ whereas in the Michelin II case it concerned

standardized retroactive quantity rebates. Following the judgement of the General Court in Michelin

II and the ruling in British Airways of the Court of Justice there was mounting criticisms from

commentators and legal practitioners for a modernization of the assessment of rebates under Article

102 TFEU.

264. In 2005 then EU Commissioner Kroes announced in a speech that ‘a more economic’ approach of

Article 82 EC was imminent. Following this speech, several ‘soft law’ papers (like the Consultation

Paper and the Discussion Paper) were published to discuss this process. This resulted in the

publication of the Guidance Paper. In this Guidance Paper the Commission tried to create clarity on

how it would prioritize its enforcement policy with regards to abuse of dominance under Article 102

TFEU. The criticism of the then form-based approach was not only that it lacked a sound economic

basis but also the characteristics of an administrable test. Seeing as case law was developed on a

case-by-case basis it was not clear on how the Court would apply ‘all the relevant circumstances ‘

in the future. Therefore, ex ante it was particularly hard for legal counsel to advise dominant

undertakings on the litigious nature of their rebate schemes.

265. Unfortunately the amount of flexibility that the Commission gives itself undermines this goal. At

the center of the Guidance Paper was the as-efficient-competitor test. Based on this test, the

Commission will only intervene where the conduct concerned has already been or is capable of

hampering competition from competitors which are considered to be as efficient as the dominant

undertaking. Several commentators have argued that the parameters, that the Commission will take

into account when applying the AEC-test, are not ideal. Parameters like ‘contestable share’ and

‘relevant range’ are difficult to estimate as a dominant undertaking and therefore do not provide the

necessary legal certainty. Furthermore, the Guidance Paper allows the Commission, when deciding

the allowed cost-price level, to apply the price costs of competitors. It cannot be required of

dominant undertakings to take the price-cost levels of their competitors into account.

Page 101: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

95

266. In its decision in the Intel case, the Commission regrettably contradicted itself. It had the opportunity

to apply the AEC-test, which it did, but then again it stated that it is not required to indicate possible

anti-competitive effects to find a violation of Article 102 TFEU. It was also not clear whether the

AEC-test was mandatory for competition authorities dealing with rebate cases or just optional. This

was a question that was answered by the Post Danmark II judgement. The Court ruled that the AEC

is wholly optional and thus not mandatory. In the words of the Court the AEC-test is thus a “tool

amongst others” But seeing as this could be regarded as a ‘rule of practice’ it will have to take the

relevant case law of the EU courts into account when applying the AEC-test. Even though the

Guidance Paper showed that the Commission had the intention to reform its assessment of Article

102 TFEU, its ambition progressively declined after the publication of the Consultation Paper and

resulted in the -at most- average Guidance Paper.

267. Article 102 TFEU is a puzzling article as it lacks applicable definitions. It is therefore left up to the

EU courts to give a workable framework to this article. The Post Danmark II case was an ideal

opportunity to clarify what the assessment should be of quantity rebates under Article 102 TFEU.

The characteristics of the rebate scheme were comparable to the rebate scheme under investigation

in Michelin II. Michelin chose however not to appeal the decision.

268. The Court started off by assessing all the relevant circumstances’ of the quantity rebate scheme. In

this assessment it, remarkably, took the competitive structure of the market into consideration. This

was a new element not previously seen in other judgements concerning rebates. The biggest

improvement caused by the judgement was when the Court took the possible anti-competitive

effects of the rebate scheme into account. The Court analyzed whether the rebate scheme was

capable of causing anti-competitive effects on the market. This marked somewhat of an evolution

seeing as this introduces a ‘by effect’ standard to the assessment of rebates under Article 102 TFEU.

This also confirms that there is, as it is imbedded in the text of Article 101 TEFU, a distinction

between ‘by object’ and ‘by effect’ violations of Article 102 TFEU. Selective price cuts and margins

squeezes are types of conduct where the Court will investigate where there are anti-competitive

effects on the relevant market. Accordingly, following the Post Danmark II, judgment quantity

rebates will only violate Article 102 TFEU if, in the absence of an objective justification and having

considered all the relevant circumstances, the Court comes to the conclusion that the rebate scheme

has the capability of producing anti-competitive effects. The degree of these anti-competitive effects

will not be subjected to a de minimis-test. The anti-competitive effect have to be ‘probable’ and

must not be purely hypothetical. What should be understood under probable anti-competitive effects

is still an unanswered question.

269. The Post Danmark II is more of an evolution than a revolution. The Court has realligned its case

law with this judgment in the direction of the Guidance Paper. The Court should in the future

Page 102: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

abandon the ‘by object’ with regards to loyalty rebates and exclusivity dealing. The impact of these

practices can have a negative impact on consumer welfare but I remain of the opinion that these

effects should be proven and not merely assumed. The Hoffmann La Roche assumption with regards

to quantity rebates was not respected to a full extent. Under the presumption of legality the dominant

undertaking should not be required to provide proof that its rebate scheme is economically justified,

as was the case in the Post Danmark II judgment. As of yet it appears that a completely new way of

doing things is not a concern for the EU Courts. The question is of course what stance the EU courts

will take in following rebate cases. Many questions remain unresolved after the Post Danmark II

judgement. The fate of exclusivity rebates and exclusive purchasing obligations being one of them.

Hopefully, the Court will assess these unanwered questions in the coming Intel judgment.

Page 103: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

97

Bibliography

1. LEGISLATION

Consolidated version of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union, OJ C 326, 26.10.2012,

p. 47–390.

1.1. Soft Law

Report by the Economic Advisory Group (EAGCP) for Competition Policty ‘An Economic Approach

to Article 82 EC’, July 2005, availible at: ec.europa.eu/competition/atintrust/art82.

DG COMPETITION Discussion Paper on the Application of Article 82 of the Treaty to Exclusionary

Abuses, Brussels, December 2005, available at: ec.europa.eu/competition/atintrust/art82.

Guidance on the Commission’s Enforcement Priorities in Applying Article 82 of the EC Treaty to

Abusive Exclusionary Conduct by Dominant Undertakings, 2009, OJ C45/2.

Preliminary Thoughts on Policy Review of Article 82”, Speech at the Fordham Corporate Law Institute

New York, 23 September 2005.

Intergovernmental Committee of the Messina Conference, ‘Report by the Heads of Delegations to the

Foreign Ministers’ (Spaak Report’) 21 April 1956

1.2. OECD Report

Loyalty and fidelity discounts and rebates, OECD report of 4 February 2003, DAFEE COMP (2002)

21), p. 7.

2. JURISPRUDENCE

2.1. General Court

Hilti, T-30/89, ECLI:EU:T:1991:70.

Page 104: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

BPB Industries, T-65/89 ,ECLI:EU:T:1993:31.

Irish Sugar, T-228/97, ECLI:EU:T:1999:246. 7

Van Den Bergh, T-65/98, ECLI:EU:T:2003:281.

Dansk Rørindustri, T-21/99 ECLI:EU:T:2002:74.

Michelin II, T- 203/01, ECLI:EU:T:2003:250.

Microsoft, T-201/04, ECLI:EU:T:2007:289.

Intel, T-286/09, ECLI:EU:T:2014:547.

Continental Can, Case 6-72, ECLI:EU:C:1973:22.

Suiker Unie, C-40/73, ECLI:EU:C:1975:174.

Hoffman/La Roche, C-85/76, ECLI:EU:C:1979:36.

Michelin I, C-322/81, ECLI:EU:C:1983:313.

Port of Genoa, Case C-179/90, ECLI:EU:C:1991:464.

AKZO, C-62/86, ECLI:EU:C:1991:286.

Merci convenzionali porto di Genova SpA v Siderurgica Gabrielli SpA., Case C-179/90,

ECLI:EU:C:1991:464.

Portugal vs. Commission, C-163/99, ECLI:EU:C:2001:189.

Compagnie Maritime Belge, C-95/04, ECLI:EU:C:2007:166.

British Airways, C-95/04, ECLI:EU:C:2007:166.

GlaxoSmithKline Services and Others v Commission and Others, C-501/06, ECLI:EU:C:2009:610.

France Télécom, C-202/07, ECLI:EU:C:2009:214

Deutsche Telekom AG v European Commission. C-280/08, ECLI:EU:C:2010:603.

Deutsche Post, C-399/08, ECLI:EU:C:2010:48.

TeliaSonera, C-52/09, ECLI:EU:C:2011:83.

Post Danmark I, C-209/10, ECLI:EU:C:2012:172.

Tomra, C-549/10, ECLI:EU:C:2012:221.

Expedia, C-226/11, EU:C:2012:795.

Post Danmark II, C-23/14, ECLI:EU:C:2015:651.

2.2. European Court of Justice

Deutsche Post, C-399/08, ECLI:EU:C:2010:48, OJ 2002 L 247, p. 27

British Airways, C-95/04, ECLI:EU:C:2007:166, OJ 2000 L 30, p. 1

Intel, T-286/09, ECLI:EU:T:2014:547, OJ 2009 C 227, p. 13

Page 105: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

99

Tetra Pak International SA v Commission of the European Communities, Case T-83/91

ECLI:EU:T:1994:246, Opinion of Advocate Kirschner.

British Airways, C-95/04, ECLI:EU:C:2007:166, Opinion of Advocate General Kokott.

Post Danmark I, C-209/10, ECLI:EU:C:2012:172, Opinion of Advocate General Mengozzi.

Post Danmark II, C-23/14, ECLI:EU:C:2015:651, Opinion of Advocate General Kokott.

3. DOCTRINE

3.1. Books

AKMAN, P., The Concept of Abuse in EU Competition Law, Oxford, Hart Publishing, 2015, 354p.

EZRACHI, A, Article 82 EC: Reflections on its Recent Evolution, Oxford, Hart Pubishing, 2009,232p.

GERBER, D., Law and Competition in Twentieth-Century Europe: Protecting Prometheus, Oxford,

Oxford University Press, 504p.

GILLINGHAM , J., Coal, steel and the Rebirth of Europe, 1945 – 1955, Cambridge, Cambridge

University Press, 397p.

GORMSEN, L., A Principled Approach to Abuse of Dominance in European Competition Law,

Cambridge, Cambridge University Pres, 2010, 226.

GOYDER, D.G., EC Competition Law, Oxford, Oxford University Press, 2003, 592p.

JONES, A. and SUFRIN, B., EU Competition Law, Oxford, Oxford University Press, 2014, 1331p.

JOLLIET, R., Monopolization and Abuse of Dominant Position: A Comparative Study of the American

and European Approaches to the Control of Economic Power, Michigan, Faculté de droit, 1970, 329p.

NAZINNI, R., The Foundations of European Union Competition Law, Oxford, Oxford University Press,

2011, 488p.

Page 106: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

O’DONOGHUE, R. AND PADILLA, J., The Law and Economics of Article 102 TFEU, Oxford, Hart

Publishing, 2013, 1078 p.

PATEL, K. AND SCHWEITZER, H., The Historical Foundations of EU Competition Law, Oxford,

Oxford University Press, 256p.

PEACOCK, A., Germany's Social Market Economy: Origins and Evolution, Basingstoke, Palgrave

Macmillan, 1989, 242p.

RIDYARD, D, “Exclusionary Pricing and Price Discrimination Abuses Under Article 82 An Economic

Analysis”, European Competition Law Review 2003, 286-303.

ROSE, V., and BAILEY, d., European Union Law of Competition, Oxford, Oxford University Press,

3560p.

ROUSSEVA, E., Rethinking Exclusionary Abuses in EU Competition Law, Oxford, Hart Publishing,

578p.

SCHÜTZE, R., European Union Law, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 2015, 945p.

VAN BAEL,I and BELLIS, J.F., Competition Law of the European of the European Community, Alphen

aan Den Rijn, Kluwer Law International, 1728p.

3.2. Articles

AKMAN, P., “Searching for the Long-lost Soul of Article 82 EC”, Oxford Journal of Legal Studies,

Volume 29 Issue 2, 267-303.

AKMAN, P., “The Reform of the Application of Article 102 TFEU: Mission Accomplished”, Anti-Trust

Law Journal, forthcoming, available at: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2654679.

ALLBORS-LLORENS, A., “The Role of Objective Justification and Efficiencies in the Application of

Article 82 EC”, Common Market Law Review 2007, 1727-1761.

AHLBORN, C and GRAVE, C., “Walter Eucken and Ordoliberalism: An Introduction from a Consumer

Welfare Perspective, Competition Policy International 2006, 197-219.

Page 107: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

101

BACON,K. “European Court of Justice upholds judgement of the Court of First Instance in the British

Airways Judgement”, Competition Policy International 2007, 227-237.

CHIRTA, A. A Legal-Historical Review of the EU Compeitition Rules, ICLQ 2014, 281 – 316.

COLOMO, P., “Intel and Article 102 TFEU Case Law: Making Sense of a Perpetual Controversy”, LSE

Working Papers, 2-31.

COLOMO, P., “Post Danmark II, or the Quest for Administrability and Coherence in Article 102

TFEU”, LSE Working Papers, 15/2015.

ELLIS, J., “Source Material for Article 85(1) of the EEC Treaty”, Fordham Law Review 1963, 247-277.

EZRACHI, A. “The European Commission Guidance on Article 82 EC – The Way in which Institutional

Realities Limit the Potential for Reform, University of Oxford Legal Research Papers 2009, 1-31.

FAELLE. G. “The Anti-Trust Assessment of Loyalty Discounts and Rebates”, not published, available

at: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1079504.

GERBER, D., “The Future of Article 82: Dissecting the Conflict”, European Competition Law Annual

2007, 39-54.

GERBER, D. “ Constituionalizing the Economy: German Neoliberalism, Competition Law and the

“New Europe”, Americian Journal of Comparative law 1994. 25-84.

GERADIN, D. and HENRY, D., “Abuse of Dominance in The Postal Sector – The Contribution of the

Guidance Paper on Art. 82 EC” in CREW, M., KLEINDORFER, P. in Heightening Competition in the

Postal and Delivery Sector, Cheltenham, Edward Elgar Publishing Limited, 2010, 385p.

GERADIN, D. “The Decision of the Commission of 13 May 2009 in the Intel case: Where is the

Foreclosure and Consumer Harm?”, Journal of European Competition Law & Practice 2010, 112-122.

GERADIN, D., “Is the Guidance Paper on the Commission’s Enforcement Priorities in Applying Article

102 TFEU to Abusive Exclusionary Conduct Useful?” in ETRO, F. and KOKKORIS, I., Challenges in

the Enforcement of Article 102, Oxford, Oxford University Press, 2010.

Page 108: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

GERADIN, D.” Loyalty Rebates after Intel: Time for the European Court of Justice to Overrule

Hoffman-La Roche”, Journal of Competition Law & Economics 2015, 1-38.

GEORGIEVA, Z., Soft Law in EU Competition Law and its Judicial Reception in Member States -- A

Theoretical Perspective (October 2014). TILEC Discussion Paper No. 2014-035. Available at

SSRN:http://ssrn.com/abstract=2506617 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2506617.

GORMSEN, L. “Are Anti-Competitive Effects Necessay for an Analysis under Article 102 TFEU?”,

World Competition 2013, 223-246.

GORMSEN, L. “Article 82 EC: Where Are We Coming From and Where Are We Going To?”, The

Competition Law Review 2006, 4-26.

GYSELEN, L. “Rebates, Competition on The Merits or Exclusionary Practice?”, European Competition

Law Anual 2003, 288.

HOFMANN, H., “Negotiated and Non-Negotiated Administrative Rule-Making: The Example of EC

Competition Policy, Common Market Law Review 2006, 153-178.

KJÆRSGAARD, N., GRAVENGAARD, M., “The EU Commission Guidance on Exclusionary abuse

of Dominance and its consequences in pracice”, E.C.L.R 2005, 285-305.

KALLAUGHER, J. and SHER, B. “Rebates Revisited: Anti-Competitive Effects and Exclusionary

Abuse Under Article 82 EC”, E.C.L.R 2004, 263 – 285.

MOTTA, M. “‘Michelin II: The Treatment of Rebates” in LYONS, B. Cases in European Competition

Policy: The Economic Analysis, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 2009.

NIHOUL, P.”The Ruling of the General Court in Intel: Towards the End of an Effect-based Approach

in European Competition Law?”, Journal of European Competition Law and Practice 2014, 1-10.

PEEPERKORN. L., “Conditional pricing: Why the General Court is wrong in Intel and what the Court

of Justice can do to rebalance the assessment of rebates”, Concurrences Review 2015, 43-63.

PETIT, N. “Rebates and Article 102 TFEU: The European Commission's Duty to Apply the Guidance

Paper”, not published, availible at: http://orbi.ulg.ac.be/handle/2268/192441.

Page 109: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

103

PETIT, N., “Intel, leveraging rebates and the goals of Article 102 TFEU”, European Competition

Journal 2015, 26-68.

PORTUESE, A, GOUGH, O., TANEGA, J., “The Principle of Legal Certainty as a Principle of

Economic Efficiency”, Research Paper No. 13-13, University of Westminster School of Law, 1-36.

ROSENBLATT, H., ARMENGOD, H. SCORDAMAGLIA-TOUSIS, A. “Post Danmark: predatory

pricing in the European Union”, The European Anti-Trust Review 2013, 21-24.

ROUSSEVA, E, “Modernizing By Eradicating: How the Commission's New Approach to Article 81 Ec

Dispenses with the Need to Apply Article 82 Ec to Vertical Restraints”, Common Market Law Review

2005, 587-638.

ROUSSEVA, E., “The Concept of Objective Justification of An Abuse of a Dominant Position: Can it

Help to Modernise the Analysis under Article 82 EC?, The Competiton Law Review 2006, 68.

ROUSSEVA, E. and MARQUIS, M. “Hell Freezes Over: A Climate Change for Assessing Exclusionary

Conduct under Article 102 TFEU”, Journal of European Competition La wand Practice 2012, 1-19.

SPECTOR, D., “Loyalty Rebates: An Assessment of Competition concerns and a Proposed Rule of

Reason”, Competition Policty International 2005, 89-114.

TANGEA, J. PORTUESE, A., GOUGH, O. “The Principle of Legal Certainty as a Principle of

Economic Efficiency”, European Journal of Legal Studies 2013, 1-36.

TEMPLE LANG, J., “How Can The Problems of Exclusionary Abuses under Article 102 TFEU be

Resolved?”, ELRev 2012, 141-142.

TEMPLE LANG, J. and O’ DONOGHUE, R. Defining Legitimate Competition: How to Clarify Pricing

Abuses Under Article 82 EC, Fordham Int Lt. 2002, 83-161.

VAN DER VIJVER, T., “Objective Justification and Article 102 TFEU”, World Competition 2012, 55-

76.

WAELBROECK, D. “Michelin II: A per se Rule Against Rebates by Dominant Companies?”, Journal

of Competition La wand Economics 2005, 149-171.

Page 110: Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II · Academiejaar 2015-2016 Abuse of Dominance after Post Danmark II Masterproef van de opleiding ‘Master in de rechten’ Ingediend door

WHISH, R. “Intel v. Commission: Keep Calm and Carry on!”, Journal of European Competition Law

& Practice 2014, 1-2.

ZENGER, H., “Devising Loyalty Rebates that Comply with the As-Efficient-Competitor Test”,

Concurrences Review 2013, 16-19.

ZENGER, H., “Loyalty Rebates and The Competitive Process”, Journal of Competition Law &

Economics 2012, 717-768.

ZENGER, H. “Rebates and Competition Law: An Overview of EU and National Law”, not published,

available at: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2429138.

KARAGIANNIS, Y., Preference Heteregeneity and Equilibrium Institutions: The Case of European

Compeititon Policy, Florence, European University Institute, 2007, not published.

Further Reading

WILS, W.,“The judgment of the EU General Court in Intel and the so-called 'more economic approach'

to abuse of dominance”, World Competition 2014, 405 – 434.

In the aforementioned article, Prof. dr. Wils defends the idea that form-based approach is sound case-

law.