33
 Profitability, Growth and Efficiency in the US Life Insurance Industry By William H. Greene  New York University [email protected]  Dan Segal University of Toronto [email protected]  We appreciate the helpful comments from Joshua Livnat, Ajay Maindiratta, Stephen Ryan, James Ohlson, and workshop participants at the Hebrew University of Jerusalem, New York University, Yale University, London Business School, and the University of Toronto. LOMA kindly provided some of the data.

A Usa Grenee Sfa 2004

Embed Size (px)

DESCRIPTION

Stochastic Frontier Analysis

Citation preview

  • Profitability, Growth and Efficiency in

    the US Life Insurance Industry

    By

    William H. Greene New York University

    [email protected]

    Dan Segal University of Toronto

    [email protected]

    We appreciate the helpful comments from Joshua Livnat, Ajay Maindiratta, Stephen Ryan, James Ohlson,

    and workshop participants at the Hebrew University of Jerusalem, New York University, Yale University,

    London Business School, and the University of Toronto. LOMA kindly provided some of the data.

  • 2

    Profitability, Growth, and Efficiency in the US Life

    Insurance Industry

    ABSTRACT: This study explores the relationship between operational efficiency

    and profitability and growth in the US life Insurance industry, and provides a framework

    for linking operating performance and financial success.

    Earnings and growth have particular importance to life insurance companies;

    earnings and capital determine the viability of the insurer, while growth is paramount to

    the insurance operation. Since the life insurance industry is mature and highly

    competitive, cost efficiency may be the main driver of profitability and growth.

    We derived cost efficiency indices using the stochastic frontier method under two

    assumptions about the distribution of inefficiency. Our estimation of the cost efficiency

    measures takes into account the underlying accounting concepts that generate the data

    and, consequently, the product mix (long-duration policies vs. short-duration policies) to

    avoid distorted estimates.

    Our results suggest that operational inefficiency in the life insurance industry is

    substantial relative to earnings, and that inefficiency is negatively associated with

    profitability measures such as the return on equity (ROE) and growth. Similarly, we find

    that relatively efficient firms have higher ROE, growth, and other profitability measures.

    We also find that stock (shareholder-owned) companies are more efficient and profitable

    and grow faster than mutual (policyholder-owned) companies.

    Key Words: Operational efficiency, Value drivers, Life insurance, Organizational form.

    Data Availability: Contact author.

  • 3

    I. Introduction

    The alleged linkage between operating performance and financial success is actually

    quite tenuous and uncertain Kaplan and Norton (1992)

    The purpose of this study is to show the linkage of operating efficiency and cross-

    sectional variation in firm profitability and growth (henceforth value drivers) in the US

    life insurance industry. That industry can be characterized as mature and highly

    competitive, with fairly homogeneous products and services and comparable providers of

    insurance. Few financial inventions can be patented, and most innovations are copied

    shortly after their introduction. Consequently, success in this industry depends on the

    insurers ability to control costs and on various intangibles, such as clientele and

    business-risk preference, marketing skills, reputation, and perceived quality of service.

    Hence, we hypothesize that operational efficiency explains a significant portion of the

    variation in profitability and growth across life insurance companies.

    We also conjecture that the relations among profitability, growth, and operational

    inefficiency are conditioned on organizational form. The two main organizational forms

    of life insurance companies are mutual and stock companies. The owners of a mutual

    company are its policyholders, while the owners of a stock company are its shareholders.

    Jensen and Meckling (1976), Fama and Jensen (1985), and Mayers and Smith (1984,

    1986) argue that firms with alternative ownership structures differ in their operations and

    particularly in their cost of productions. Since the mutual form of ownership gives

    insurance companies mechanisms for controlling and disciplining managers that are less

    effective than those available under stock ownership (primarily because the potential risk

    of takeovers does not exist for mutual companies) we hypothesize that stock companies

  • 4

    are more efficient than mutual companies and, therefore, more profitable and able to

    grow faster.

    The economics literature contains numerous studies of efficiency for many

    industries, including the life insurance industry. However, to the best of our knowledge,

    none of these studies examines the effect of inefficiency on profitability and growth. In

    addition, the studies that investigate the effect of ownership on operational inefficiency in

    the life insurance industry, such as Gardner and Grace (1993) and Cummins and Zi

    (1998), find that mutual and stock companies are equally efficient. Yet these studies fail

    to control for demutualization (the conversion from policyholder ownership to stock

    ownership) or for policy mix. In addition, these studies may incorrectly specify the

    production technology, and the tests they employ may be statistically inefficient.

    Our results indicate that profitability and growth are negatively and significantly

    correlated with inefficiency. In particular, we find that all of the measures of inefficiency

    used in this study indicate unambiguously that efficient firms enjoy returns on assets and

    equity, growth rates, and ratios of operating cash flows to assets that are higher than those

    of inefficient firms. We also find that after adjusting net income for inefficiency in

    operating expenses the differences in the returns on assets (ROA) and the returns on

    equity (ROE) between efficient and inefficient firms become insignificant. In addition,

    we show that firms with consistently high ROE and high ratios of operating cash flows to

    assets (CA) are more efficient than firms with low ROE and CA. The analysis of the

    relationship between organizational form and efficiency indicates that stock companies

    are significantly more efficient than mutual companies, have higher growth rates, and are

    more profitable.

  • 5

    The reminder of this article is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the

    background and motivation for this study. Section 3 provides a brief review of the

    stochastic frontier method. Section 4 describes the outputs, inputs, input prices, and other

    data we used in the estimation of operational inefficiency. Section 5 develops our

    hypotheses and research design. Section 6 provides the empirical results, and Section 7

    concludes the paper.

    II. Background and Motivation

    We set up our study to examine two questions:

    1. Can relative operational efficiency explain the variations in profitability and

    growth across life insurance companies?

    2. Does the organizational form of life insurance companies (mutual companies vs.

    stock companies) affect their operational efficiency and hence their profitability

    and growth?

    Both questions are compelling for the industry because profitability of a life

    insurance company is of paramount importance to its operations. To determine the

    viability of the insurer, regulators rely on the financial reports prepared according to

    statutory accounting principles (SAP) and particularly on net income and the book value

    of equity. If regulators determine that the insurers viability is at risk, they may seize the

    firm or take any other action necessary to improve the deficiency in capital. Because of

    the scrutiny of both net income and equity, the profitability of the insurer determines to

    large extent its ability to invest and grow.

  • 6

    The profitability of a life insurance company is critically dependent on its

    operating and financial activities. Operating activity consists of insurance operations:

    selling new policies and servicing existing policies. Financial activity consists of

    investing the policies premiums. The profits from operating activities stem from the

    difference between premium revenue and the total cost of insurance and operations,

    whereas the profits from financial activities stem from the difference between actual

    investment returns and the returns credited to the policies.

    The life insurance industry has recently faced structural changes that have

    adversely affected both aspects of operations and consequently overall profitability. First,

    demand has shifted towards less profitable life policies and towards products that transfer

    the investment risk, along with its return, to the customer. Second, increased regulation,

    triggered by a number of bankruptcies in the late 80s, has prevented insurers from

    investing in high-risk products and has consequently limited investment returns. To

    remain competitive with the providers of other financial products, insurers have had to

    guarantee higher returns or shift the investment returns to the insured, forcing investment

    income down. Third, the emergence of non-traditional competitors such as banks1 that

    operate with much lower product distribution costs and hence have put considerable

    pressure on the profit margins of many traditional insurers. In addition to having adverse

    effects on earnings, these changes have highlighted the importance of growth and cost

    controls - i.e. efficiency in marketing and operations- as crucial determinants of future

    prospects for an insurer.

    Operational inefficiency affects profits and growth through the negative effect of

    wasted resources on earnings and cash flows. The potential reasons for operational

  • 7

    inefficiency are suboptimal usage of the firms resources through overpaying for inputs

    and through employing a technologically inferior operating process. Inefficiency causes

    realizable levels of earnings and cash flows that are lower than those potentially feasible

    with optimal operations. The adverse effects on earnings and cash flows translate into

    lower firm value either through lower dividends or through lower investments that slow

    the firms growth.

    Although growth is an important value driver for all firms, it is of particular

    significance for life insurance firms. The efficient operation of such firm requires

    considerable economies of scale generated by business volume. Without growth, an

    insurer may not garner the business volume necessary to ensure the collective pooling of

    insurance risks under the law of large numbers upon which the insurance operation relies.

    In the domestic market, growth is achieved primarily through expansion of distribution

    systems and technology improvements. Another way for insurers to grow is through

    global expansion. However, to provide for future growth, an insurance company must

    generate and maintain sufficient capital to satisfy regulators as well as to finance its

    expansion.

    By the end of 1998, more than 90% of US life insurance companies were stock

    companies, although mutual companies were, on average, larger than stock companies

    and owned approximately 33% of the total industry assets and 40% of the total amount of

    insurance. During the 1990s a growing number of mutual companies converted to stock

    companies. The primary objective of demutualization is the potential for growth through

    investments in capital and distribution channels and through mergers and acquisitions.2

    Since it is likely that the problems associated with the mutual form of ownership are not

  • 8

    mitigated immediately following the conversion, failure to account for demutualization

    when comparing the efficiency of stock and mutual companies would likely result in

    lower average efficiency of stock companies and therefore in the inability to reject the

    null hypothesis that stock and mutual companies are equally efficient.

    Another issue that confounds the studies that compare the efficiency of mutual

    and stock companies is the nature of the empirical methodologies employed. Cummins

    and Zi (1998) conducted analysis of variance (ANOVA) and other non-parametric tests,

    whereas Gardner and Grace (1993) regressed their inefficiency measure on several

    variables including a dummy variable for organizational form. These two-stage

    estimation procedures provide estimates that are statistically inefficient compared to a

    single-stage approach in which the estimated stochastic frontier takes into account firm-

    specific variables. This issue was addressed by several recent studies, such as Kumbhakar

    et al. (1991), Reifschneider and Stevenson (1991), and Huang and Liu (1994) that

    modeled inefficiency as a function of firm-specific variables.

    III The Stochastic Frontier

    The stochastic frontier (SF) method, first suggested by Aigner, Lovell, and

    Schmidt (1977) and Meeusen and Van Den Broeck (1977), provides a mean to estimate

    cost efficiencies. Cost efficiency consists of two components: technical efficiency, which

    reflects the ability of the firm to obtain maximum output from a given set of inputs, and

    allocative inefficiency, which reflects the ability of the firm to use the inputs in optimal

    proportions, given their respective prices. SF involves the estimation of a cost frontier, as

  • 9

    function of outputs and input prices, where deviation from the frontier are assumed to be

    related to cost inefficiency and statistical noise.

    To control for random error in the estimation and specification, the cost function

    is typically specified with two error components:

    ln Ci = ln C*(yi,pi) + ui + vi = ln C*(yi,pi) + i, (1)

    where i indexes the firms, Ci is the observed total costs for firm i, ln C*(yi,pi) is the log

    cost function, yi is a vector of outputs, pi is a vector of input prices, ui is a one-sided error

    term that captures cost inefficiency (ui0) and vi is a random error term that is assumed to

    be normally distributed with zero mean and variance 2v. In addition, u and v are

    assumed to be independent. From equation (1) it follows that exp (ui) = C/C*, so the cost

    inefficiency the proportion by which the firm could have reduced its costs and still

    attain the same level of outputs is computed as 1-exp(-ui).

    The estimation of the stochastic frontier along with the inefficiency term involves

    specifying the distribution of u as well as of the cost function. For the one-sided

    inefficiency disturbance term ui, several distributions have been suggested, such as the

    absolute value of a normal distribution with zero-mean (half-normal), the absolute value

    of a normal distribution with nonzero mean (truncated normal), the exponential

    distribution, and the gamma distribution. We use the zero-mean half-normal distribution.3

    With the assumed independence of the distributions of vi and ui, the computation of the

    distribution of and the maximum likelihood estimation are usually straightforward.4

    We compute the firm-specific inefficiency, ui, which is not observed directly as the

    conditional expectation E(ui|i) as in Jondrow et al. (1982).

  • 10

    We denote the conditional means of the inefficiency term under the half-normal

    distributional assumption as UNOR. By construction, the conditional mean is greater or

    equal to zero; the closer it is to zero, the more efficient is the firm. To estimate the

    stochastic frontier, we use a translog with the homothetic technology cost function5 (see

    Christensen and Greene (1976)):

    ln Ct = 0 + 0LNAVPL + JJln(Pj) + JIJIln(Pj)ln(Pi) + mmYm + mmYm2 + t, (2)

    where LNAVPL is the natural log of the average amount of insurance of life policies, Ym

    is the natural-log of output m, Pi is the price of input i, and t indexes the sample firms. To

    assure the linear homogeneity of the cost function in the factor prices, we divide each of

    the prices and total costs by one of the prices.

    IV. Model Specification and Data

    Outputs

    Like all service sectors, the life insurance industry presents difficulties of output

    definitions and measurement. Most studies identify outputs with lines of business - that

    is, life policies, annuities, and accident and health (A&H) - whereas some add investment

    income as an additional output. The major differences among studies of the cost structure

    of the industry are in output measurement. Geehan (1986) provides a useful discussion of

    the issues involved, and compares the output measures of major studies.

    Grace and Timme (1992), Gardner and Grace (1993), and Fecher et al. (1993)

    measure outputs as the dollar value of premiums and annuity considerations. Premiums

    are, however, a questionable measure of life policies. They represent not physical output

    but rather revenues (price times number of policies). Furthermore, for whole life

  • 11

    insurance policies, only a portion of the premium covers the risk-bearing that life

    insurance companies provide to the insured. The remaining portion covers the savings

    element of the policy; it therefore actually belongs to the insured and cannot be

    considered as revenue of the insurer.

    Yungert (1993) measures outputs by additions to reserves. The major problem

    with this measure is that reserves change when policies age, regardless of whether new

    policies are sold. In addition, the change in reserves measures the change in liabilities,

    rather than the output of the selling effort. In a more recent study, Cummins and Zi

    (1998) distinguish between the two principal services provided by life insurance

    companies: risk bearing/pooling, and intermediation services. As a measure of the

    former, they use incurred benefits by line of business, whereas for the latter they use

    additions to reserves. Here again the output measure is disputable. Benefits represent

    obligations that were incurred in the past; hence they measure past cumulative output, not

    current output.

    Following Cummins and Zi (1998), we characterize the outputs by the service

    provided. Life policies give either pure risk protection (through term life policies) or a

    mix of risk protection and intermediation services (through whole life policies). Annuities

    can be viewed as saving vehicles and, therefore, the service they provide can be

    characterized as intermediation. A&H policies, on the other hand, provide risk protection

    service alone.

    The risk bearing/pooling services that companies provide on new life insurance

    policies can be approximated by the total amount of insurance sold during the year.6 That

    amount measures the outcome of the selling effort and the additional risk that the

  • 12

    company bears and, therefore, can represent the output of the life insurance line of

    business.7 Furthermore, this output measure may be appropriate for all types of life

    policies, both term life and whole life.

    Profits and losses from annuities arise from the difference between the actual

    return on investments and the return credited to the contracts. Assuming a positive

    spread, the larger the annuity considerations (premiums) the larger is the expected profit.

    Hence, a plausible proxy for this output is annuity considerations, which represent the

    increase in the earning base of this line of business.

    A&H policies primarily provide risk protection. Since one cannot quantify the

    amount of risk associated with each new policy, we use A&H premiums as a proxy for

    these policies output. In equilibrium, where the risk associated with A&H policies is

    priced correctly, premiums serve as a good proxy for risk.

    To sum up, we use three outputs: amount of life insurance, total annuity

    considerations and total A&H premiums8.

    Inputs and Inputs Prices

    For this study we employ three inputs: labor, capital, and other. Labor is defined

    as the number of employee-days. The price of labor is computed as the total cost of

    employees and agents divided by their total number. Capital comprises two components:

    financial capital, defined as book value of equity plus the asset valuation reserve (AVR);9

    and physical capital, defined as the sum of capital expenses - rent, rental of equipment,

    and depreciation.10 We define the price of capital as the opportunity cost of holding the

    financial capital and measure it as the difference between the ratio of five years total net

  • 13

    income to total financial capital (return on equity) and the ratio of total investment

    income to total assets (return on investments) over the same period.11,12

    Our third input (other) consists of all operating expenses other than labor and

    capital expenses. Most of these expenses are related directly to selling and servicing

    policies. We use the number of policies sold and terminated during the year as a proxy

    for the number of policies sold and serviced during the year. And we quantify the price of

    this third input as the related expenses divided by the total number of policies sold or

    terminated.13

    Data

    Life insurance companies are required to file two sets of financial statements.

    One, intended primarily for shareholders, is prepared according to generally accepted

    accounting principles (GAAP). The other, highly detailed and intended for regulators, is

    prepared according to statutory accounting principles (SAP).

    The primary interest of SAP is measuring the solvency of the firm--i.e, the

    amount of capital needed to cover all obligations under extreme economic conditions,

    emphasizing financial results under very conservative assumptions. The measurement of

    operational inefficiency requires detailed financial information on the outputs and inputs

    used in the production process. Given the importance of earnings according to SAP and

    the level of detail prescribed by those principles, we use the regulatory reports in the

    analysis.

    We obtained the insurance financial data from the regulatory annual statements

    filed by insurers and reported to the National Association of Insurance Commissioners

    (NAIC) life insurance data tapes for 1995 through1998. Because the NAIC tapes do not

  • 14

    include the number of employees and agents whom insurers employ--information

    required to adequately estimate labor and its pricewe collected these data from two

    sources: responses to a survey that requested the number of companies employees and

    agents, and the Life Office Management Associations (LOMAs) Expense Management

    Program (EMaP). 14

    The initial sample consisted of 733 observations (company-years). We excluded

    from the sample companies that had fewer than 10 employees and agents (78

    observations), firms that did not sell either term or whole life policies (46 observations),

    and those for which the data show negative direct premiums, revenues, benefits,

    commissions, amount of insurance, labor-related expenses, or capital expenses (120

    observations). The final sample consists of 489 observations: 121 firms in 1995, 126

    firms in 1996, and 121 firms in each of 1997 and 1998.

    V. Hypotheses and Research Design

    When measuring inefficiency using data from regulatory reports, one needs to

    consider the underlying concepts of SAP, which do not distinguish among the durations

    of different policies and requires the immediate expensing of acquisition costs, the major

    cost associated with the issuance of life insurance policy. The acquisition costs are larger

    for long-duration policies than for short-duration policies and generally are recovered

    several years after the inception of the policy. Hence, SAP effectively ignore the concept

    of matching expenses with their associated revenues. Since inefficiency is measured with

    respect to a given level of output, the SAPs failure to account for the type of policy

    (long-term vs. short-term) would mean distorted inefficiency scores, and that applies to

  • 15

    any choice of outputs. Firms that primarily issue long-term policies would appear to be

    inefficient while firms that concentrate on short-term policies would appear as efficient

    because the former incur higher acquisition costs for any given level of output.

    To control for the type of the policies in the estimation of inefficiency we

    consider and control for the insurers product mix--in particular, the relative weights of

    long-term policies and short-term policies. To account for the mix of life policies we

    construct a variable (mix ratio) to represent it: the ratio of total new whole life policies

    amount of insurance to total term and whole new life policies amount of insurance.

    We then classify the firms into two groups--those with a mix ratio greater than

    half, and those with a mix ratio less than half--and estimate inefficiency separately for the

    two groups.

    To mitigate the influence of extreme variables on the results, we further exclude

    firms with ROEs less than 50% or greater then 200% (7 observations), firms for which

    we could not estimate the growth rate and firms with growth rate greater than 100% (10

    observations). Thus, the final number of firm-year observations available for the analysis

    of the association between inefficiency and profitability and growth is 472.

    Profitability, Growth, and Inefficiency

    To test our hypotheses we need first to distinguish between efficient and

    inefficient firms. For that purpose we rank the sample firms for which we have four years

    of data (368), and we label each observation as efficient (top 33%), partially efficient

    (middle 33%), and inefficient (bottom 33%). For every year, firms that are efficient are

    assigned a score of 2, firms that are partially efficient a score of 1 and inefficient firms a

  • 16

    score of 0. We then compute each firms total score by summing its scores over all four

    years. We define the group of firms with total scores of 0 or 1 as consistently inefficient,

    and the group of firms with scores of 7 or 8 as consistently efficient.

    For these two groups, we test whether their profitability and growth measures

    differed significantly and in the expected direction. To do so, we examine the association

    between inefficiency and the following measures: ROE, defined as the ratio of net

    income in year (t) to the average book value of equity in years t and t-1; ROA, defined as

    the ratio of net income in year t to the average of total assets in years t and t-1; CA, the

    ratio of operating cash flows in year t to the average of total assets in years t and t-1; and

    the two-year average growth (GR) in direct premium revenues. Formally, we test the

    following hypotheses (stated in null form):

    H1a: ROEEFFROEIEF (ROE)

    H1b: ROAEFFROAIEF (ROA)

    H1c: CAEFFCAIEF (CA)

    H1d: GREFFGRIEF (GR),

    where the suffix EFF (IEF) indicates consistently efficient (inefficient) firms. We use a

    one-tail test for all hypotheses.

    To test the hypothesis that firms that perform better in terms of profitability and

    growth rate are more efficient than poorly performing firms, we repeat the methodology

    with which we create portfolios of consistently efficient and inefficient firms and use it to

    construct portfolios of firms with consistently high [low] ROA, ROE, GR, and CA,

    denoted HROA [LROA], HROE [LROE], HGR [LGR], and HCA [LCA], respectively.

    We then compute the average efficiency for each efficiency measure and test whether the

  • 17

    average efficiency of HROA, HROE, HGR, and HCA is greater respectively than that of

    LROA, LROE, LGR, and LCA.

    This leads to the next set of hypotheses (stated in null form):

    H1e: Eff(HROA) Eff(LROA)

    H1f: Eff(HROE) Eff(LROE)

    H1h: Eff(HGR) Eff(LGR)

    H1i: Eff(HCA) Eff(LCA),

    where Eff is the average efficiency of UNOR and UEXP. Testing Hypotheses H1e

    through H1i together with H1a through H1d as already stated would indicate whether a

    significant relationship exists between inefficiency and ROA, ROE, GR, and CA. That is,

    rejection of all of the null hypotheses would indicate that inefficiency has negative

    impact on ROA, ROE, GR, and CA and conversely that firms with low ROA, ROE, GR,

    and CA are also less efficient.

    Efficiency and Organizational Form

    The data contain 20 mutual companies that had converted to stock companies

    during the 1995-98 period. To control for demutualization, we omit from the analysis the

    68 firm-year observations following the conversions. The sample then consists of 404

    observations, of which 107 are mutual-years and 297 stock-year observations.

    To use a statistically efficient test of the relationship between firm-specific

    variables and inefficiency, as suggested by Huang and Liu (1994), we re-estimate the

    frontier using a Cobb-Douglas cost function with the mean of the inefficiency term, di,

    formulized as

  • 18

    di = + 1STOCKi + 2MIXi, (3) where STOCK is a dummy variable valued at 1 for stock companies and 0 for mutual

    companies, MIX is the policy-mix ratio, and i indexes the firms. (We add MIX to the

    equation since we estimate the frontier over the entire data.15)

    We then test the following hypotheses (stated in null form):

    H2a: 10

    H2b: 20

    VI. Results

    Table 1 provides descriptive statistics about the sample. Panel A of Table 1 shows

    that the average size (total assets) of the sample firms ranges from $4,435 million in 1995

    to $5,430 million in 1998. In 1998, the aggregate total assets of these firms were about

    $657 billion, approximately a third of all assets in the industry. Thus, our sample covers a

    material portion of all firms in the industry. Panel B of Table 1 presents the percentage of

    direct premium revenues by line of business.

    [Insert Table 1]

    Table 2 demonstrates the effect of inefficiency on earnings. The table presents the

    median and mean cost of inefficiency as a percentage of earnings before tax and as a

    percentage of revenues, denoted EFFIN and EFFREV, respectively. We compute the cost

    of inefficiency as one minus the exponent of -U times the inputs. We calculate the cost of

    inefficiency in operating expenses, which comprise labor-related expenses (not including

    commissions), physical capital, and all other expenses (Thus, our cost of inefficiency

    does not include any inefficiency in the amount of financial capital held nor in the

    commissions paid to agents16).

  • 19

    [Insert Table 2]

    The median of EFFIN in 1995 through 1997 is around 60%; in 1998, EFFIN is

    much higher- 75%. The median of EFFREV is stable across the period, indicating that the

    cost of inefficiency as percentage of revenues is 4.5%. Hence, inefficiency is substantial

    relative to earnings and revenues.

    Table 3 sets out the average inefficiency of the sample firms. The mean

    inefficiency over the entire period is approximately 38%. This finding is consistent with

    those of Cummins and Zi (1998) and Yungert (1993), which also document inefficiency

    in the range of 30% to about 40%.

    [Insert Table 3]

    Panel A of Table 4 shows the distribution of firms across the three efficiency

    groups (consistently efficient, partially efficient, and consistently inefficient), as well as

    the mean inefficiency of each group. About 25% of the firms are considered to be

    consistently efficient, 27% consistently inefficient and the reminder partially efficient.

    The average inefficiency of the consistently inefficient (efficient) firms is 54% (25%).

    Panel B of Table 4 provides descriptive statistics about the profitability and

    growth measures. The means of ROA, ROE, GR, and CA over the entire period are 1.8%,

    10%, 7%, and 6%, respectively. Panel C of Table 4 shows the Spearman correlations of

    the efficiency measure of the entire sample with the value drivers. All correlations are

    positive, i.e., efficiency is positively associated with ROA, ROE, CA, and GR and, in

    general, significant at 5%.

    Panel D of Table 4 presents the mean and average Wilcoxon rank scores of the

    value drivers of the consistently efficient and inefficient firms. For example, the mean

  • 20

    ROA of the consistently efficient (inefficient) firms is 2.3% (1.3%), and the Wilcoxon

    rank is 105 (88). The profitability and growth measures are significantly, generally at the

    5% level, higher for consistently efficient firms. Efficient firms have higher return on

    assets, higher return on book value of equity, higher growth rate and higher ratio of

    operating cash flows to total assets.

    [Insert Table 4]

    To test whether the differences in ROA and ROE can be explained by operational

    inefficiency, we compute the yearly net income of the sample firms as if they were fully

    efficient. For each firm, we add to net income and to operating cash flows the cost of

    inefficiency in operating expenses after tax.17 We then test whether the adjusted ROA,

    ROE, and CA differ between consistently efficient and inefficient firms. Panel E of Table

    4 presents the mean and average Wilcoxon rank scores of the adjusted profitability

    measures for the portfolios of consistently efficient and inefficient firms. The results

    indicate that the differences in the adjusted ROA and ROE between the portfolios

    become insignificant. The adjusted mean CA is still significantly (10%) higher for

    efficient firms. Hence, these results appear to suggest that operational inefficiency

    explains the differences in profitability between the consistently efficient and inefficient

    firms.

    To test hypotheses H1g through H1j we created portfolios of firms with the

    highest (lowest) ROA, ROE, GR, and CA, denoted HROA (LROA), HROE (LROE),

    HGR (LGR), and HCA (LCA), respectively. Panel F of Table 4 provides the average of

    each efficiency measure of each portfolio. The mean and Wilcoxon rank score tests

    indicate that the mean efficiency of HROE is significantly (5%) greater than the mean

  • 21

    efficiency of LROE; the mean efficiency of HCA is significantly greater than the mean

    efficiency of LCA, the difference is significant at 10%. The differences in efficiency

    between HGR and LGR and between HROA and LROA are not significant.

    In sum, the results suggest a one-to-one relationship between ROE and CA, and

    the efficiency score of the firm the higher the efficiency score, the higher are ROE and

    CA, and vice versa.

    Our second research question relates organizational form to efficiency. We repeat

    the estimation of inefficiency, assuming a positive half-normal distribution (of the

    inefficiency component) where the mean is a function of organizational form and policy

    mix, using the Cobb-Douglas functional form. Panel A of Table 5 shows the regression

    results. We find that the coefficient of STOCK, a dummy variable set at zero for mutual

    companies and one for stock companies, is negative and significant, indicating that the

    latter are significantly more efficient than the former. The coefficient of MIX is, as

    expected, positive and highly significant, indicating that failure to account for the type of

    policy (whole vs. term) results in higher inefficiency scores for firms that primarily issue

    whole life policies; the most likely reason is that SAP ignore the matching concept.

    Finally, Panel B of Table 5 provides the means and average Wilcoxon rank scores

    of the profitability and growth measures of the two organizational forms. Over the entire

    period, the stock companies have significantly (5%) higher ROA, ROE, CA, and GR. On

    a yearly basis, the ROA and CA of stock companies are significantly, higher in every

    year, at 10% or better. The ROE of stock companies is significantly higher in 1995 and in

    1996, while GR is significantly higher in 1996 and in 1998.

  • 22

    Overall, we find that stock companies are significantly more efficient than mutual

    companies, and that their growth rates and profitability are significantly higher. Given

    our prior results, the two findings may be related: that is, since stock companies are more

    efficient they are more profitable and grow faster.

    VII. Summary and Conclusion

    The main purpose of this study is to explain cross-sectional differences in

    profitability and growth rates of life insurance companies. Since the life insurance

    industry is mature and highly competitive, we hypothesize that operational inefficiency

    may have a strong negative effect on earnings and consequently on growth. We measure

    inefficiency and the profitability and growth measures using the regulatory reports, which

    are prepared according to the SAP. Since the SAP ignores the matching concept, we

    distinguish between the different types of life policies results in order not to bias the

    inefficiency scores.

    We find that the industry is, on average, 38% inefficient. We also find that

    efficiency is paramount to profitability and growth. Efficient firms have significantly

    ROA and ROE, higher GR, and higher CA ratios. Furthermore, after adjusting net

    income to the cost of inefficiency, we find that the differences in profitability between

    efficient and inefficient firms become insignificantly different from zero. Thus,

    operational inefficiency seems to explain the variation in profitability and growth. In

    addition, high-value firms--i.e., those firms with the highest ROE, and CA--are more

    efficient than low-value firms. These findings suggest the existence of a one-to-one

  • 23

    relationship between value and efficiency; efficient firms have higher value, and higher

    value firms are more efficient.

    The two main organizational forms of life insurance companies are mutual

    (owned by policyholders) and stock (owned by shareholders). Since the mutual form of

    ownership allows less effective mechanisms for controlling and disciplining managers

    than the stock ownership, we hypothesize that stock companies are more efficient than

    mutual companies, and therefore, are also more profitable and grow faster. Our results

    support the hypothesis: stock companies are indeed more efficient. Also, they exhibit

    significantly higher ROA, ROE, CA, and GR than mutual companies.

  • 24

    References Aigner, D., K. Lovell and P. Schmidt. 1977. Formulation and Estimation of Stochastic Frontier Production

    Function Models. International Economic Review 17, 377-396

    Charnes, A., W. W. Cooper, and E. Rhodes. 1978. Measuring the Efficiency of Decision-Making Units. European Journal of Operational Research 2(6), 429-444

    Christensen, R. L., and W. H. Greene. 1976. Economies of Scale in U.S. Electric Power Generation. Journal of Political Economy 84, 655-675

    Cobb, S. and P. Douglas. 1928. A Theory of Production. American Economic Review 18, 139-165

    Coelli, T. J. (1994). A Guide to FRONTIER Version 4.1: A Computer Program for Stochastic Frontier and Cost Function Estimation mimeo, Department of Econometrics, University of New England, Armidale

    Cummins, J. D., and H. Zi. 1998. Comparison of Frontier Efficiency Models: An Application to the U.S Life Insurance Industry. Journal of Productivity Analysis 10, 131-152

    Fama, F. E., and M. C. Jensen. 1993. Separation of Ownership and Control. Journal of Law and Economics 26, 301-325

    Gardner, L., and M. F. Grace. 1993. X-Efficiency in the U.S Life Insurance Industry. Journal of Banking and Finance 17, 497-510

    Geehan, R. 1986. Economies of Scale in Insurance: Implications for Regulation. The Insurance Industry in Economic Development 137-160

    Grace, F. M. and S. G. Timme. 1992. An Examination of Cost Economics in the United States Life Insurance Industry. Journal of Risk and Insurance 59, 72-103

    Greene, W. H. 1990. A Gamma Distributed Stochastic Frontier Model. Journal of Econometrics 46, 141-163

    Huang, C. and J. Liu. 1994. Estimation of a Non-Neutral Stochastic Frontier Production Function. Journal of Productivity Analysis

    Jensen, M. C. and Meckling W. H. 1976. Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior Agency Costs and Ownership Structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3, 305-360

    Jondrow, J., K. Lovell, I. Materov and P. Schmidt. 1982. On the Estimation of Technical Inefficiency in the Stochastic Frontier Production Function Model. Journal of Econometrics 19, 233-238

    Kaplan, R. S. and D. P. Norton. 1992. The balanced scorecard-Measures that drive performance. Harvard Business Review 74(1), 71-79

    Kumbhakar, S., S. Ghosh and J. McGuckin. 1991. A generalized Production Frontier Approach for Estimating Determinants of Inefficiency in U.S. Dairy Farm. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 9, 279-286

    Life Office Management Association (LOMA), Inc. 1998. Expense Management Program (Emap) Manual, Expense Year 1997 February 1998

    Mayers, D., and W. S. Clifford, JR. 1998. Ownership Structure Across Lines of Property-Casualty Insurance. Journal of Law and Economics 41, 351-378

    Mayers, D. and W. S. Clifford, JR. 1986. Ownership Structure and Control: The Mutualization of Stock Life Insurance Companies. Journal of Financial Economics 16, 73-98

    Meeusen, W. and J. Van Den Broeck. 1977. Efficiency Estimation from Cobb-Douglas Production Functions with Composed Error. International Economic Review 18, 435-444

    Reifschnieder, D. and R. Stevenson. 1991. Systematic Departures from the Frontier: A Framework for the Analysis of Firm Inefficiency. International Economic Review 32, 715-723

  • 25

    Stevenson, E. R. 1980. Likelihood Functions For Generalized Stochastic Frontier Estimation. Journal of Econometrics v13(1), 57-66.

    Yungert, A. M. 1993. The Measurement of Efficiency in Life Insurance: Estimates of a Mixed Normal-Gamma Error Model. Journal of Banking and Finance 17, 483-496

  • 26

    Table 1 Descriptive Statistics Table 1, Panel A Total Assets ($million) Sample Year N Mean Min. Max. Entire Sample 95 121 4,435 1.8 125,831 96 126 5,263 1.9 120,823 97 121 5,505 2.2 128,035 98 121 5,430 2.7 125,620 Stock Companies 95 99 4,641 1.8 125,831 96 96 2,948 1.9 85,694 97 98 3,458 2.2 92,455 98 96 3,585 2.7 100,251 Mutual Companies 95 22 3,506 11 38,311 96 30 12,670 103 120,823 97 23 14,225 103 128,035 98 25 12,518 102 100,251 Table 1, Panel B Analysis of Percentage of Premiums by Line of Business Year N Mean

    Premium ($millions)

    Life Annuity A&H

    95 121 480 49% 27% 23% 96 126 551 51% 27% 22% 97 121 579 49% 27% 24% 98 121 515 51% 28% 21%

    Notes: 1. Mean Premium is the average direct premium revenues of the sample firms. 2. Life, Annuity, and A&H stand for the life insurance, annuity, and accident and health lines of businesses, respectively.

  • 27

    Table 2 The Median (Mean) Cost of Inefficiency as a Percentage of Income before Tax and as a Percentage of Revenues

    N Year CoI EFFIN 116 95 0.63

    (1.15) 121 96 0.63

    (1.05) 114 97 0.58

    (1) 114 98 0.75

    (1.34) EFFREV 116 95 0.04

    (0.05) 121 96 0.044

    (0.053) 114 97 0.042

    (0.05) 114 98 0.045

    (0.055) Notes: 1. CoI is the cost of inefficiency, which is computed as one minus the exponent of minus the efficiency measure, ui, times total

    general expenses. 2. EFFIN is the ratio of cost of inefficiency over absolute value of income before taxes. 3. EFFREV is the ratio of cost of inefficiency over revenues. 4. We omitted from the analysis observation for which the ratio total general expense to revenues was greater than one, or

    observations for which the ratio of total general expense to absolute value of income before tax is greater than 25.

    Table 3 The Stochastic Frontier Measure of Inefficiency YEAR N UNOR

    95 121 0.35 96 126 0.39 97 121 0.38 98 121 0.38

    Average 0.38 Notes (Table 3): 1. UNOR is the means of ui, the inefficiency component in the estimated stochastic frontier, where ui is assumed to have half-

    Normal distribution. The inefficiency score is computed as 1-exp(-ui).

  • 28

    Table 4 Analysis of Profitability, Growth and Inefficiency Measures Table 4, Panel A Distribution of Efficient, Partially Efficient and inefficient Firms and Their Mean Inefficiency Portfolio N % Mean

    Inefficiency Inefficient 92 25 0.54 Partially 176 48 0.36 Efficient 100 27 0.25 Notes: 1. The inefficient, partially, and efficient portfolios consist of firms that are, respectively, consistently inefficient, partially

    inefficient, and consistently efficient. Table 4, Panel B Means and Medians of Value Drivers

    YEAR N ROA ROE GR CA 95 92 0.018

    (0.011) 0.10

    (0.09) 0.06

    (0.05) 0.06

    (0.06) 96 92 0.019

    (0.011) 0.10

    (0.08) 0.07

    (0.05) 0.07

    (0.05) 97 92 0.019

    (0.012) 0.11

    (0.10) 0.08

    (0.05) 0.05

    (0.05) 98 92 0.016

    (0.012) 0.09

    (0.09) 0.06

    (0.04) 0.05

    (0.05) Mean 368 1.8% 10% 7 % 6%

    Notes: 1. ROA is net income (t) over average total assets at the end of year t-1 and year t. 2. ROE is net income (t) over average book value of equity (including the AVR) at the end of year t-1 and year t. 3. GR is two years average growth in direct premiums. 4. CA is operating cash flows (t) over average total assets at the end of year t-1 and year t. Table 4, Panel C Spearman Correlations between Efficiency Measures and Value Drivers (N=368) Value Driver UNOR ROA 0.075* ROE 0.105** CA 0.14** GR 0.087** Notes: 1. * (**) indicates significance level of 10% (5%) for the test of equality between the efficient and inefficient portfolio or for

    correlations between variables. 2. For definitions of ROA, ROE, CA and GR refer to the notes to Table 4, Panel B. 3. For definition of UNOR refer to the notes to Table 3.

  • 29

    Table 4, Panel D - Means and Average Wilcoxon Rank Scores (in parentheses) of Value Drivers, by Portfolio

    Value Driver

    Portfolio UNOR

    ROA Efficient Inefficient

    0.023**(105)** 0.013 (88)

    ROE Efficient Inefficient

    0.13** (109)** 0.08 (83)

    GR Efficient Inefficient

    0.087* (103)** 0.055 (90)

    CA Efficient Inefficient

    0.08** (105)** 0.05 (87)

    Notes: 1. * (**) indicates significance level of 10% (5%) for the test of equality between the efficient and inefficient portfolio or for

    correlations between variables. 2. For definitions of ROA, ROE, CA and GR refer to the notes to Table 4, Panel B. 3. The Efficient (Inefficient) portfolio consists of consistently efficient (inefficient) firms. Table 4, Panel E Means and Average Wilcoxon Rank Scores (in parentheses) of Profitability Measures Adjusted for Inefficiency, by Portfolio Profitability Measure

    Portfolio UNOR

    ROA* Efficient Inefficient

    0.035 (96) 0.029 (98)

    ROE* Efficient Inefficient

    0.21 (96) 0.17 (97)

    CA* Efficient Inefficient

    0.10* (101) 0.07 (91)

    Notes: 1. * (**) indicates significance level of 10% (5%) for the test of equality between the efficient and inefficient portfolio or for

    correlations between variables. 2. ROE*, ROA* and CA* are computed as described in the notes to Panel B but with the cost of efficiency (after tax) with respect

    to total general expenses added to net income and operating cash flows. 3. The Efficient (Inefficient) portfolio consists of firms with the highest (lowest) profitability measure. 4. For definition of UNOR refer to the notes to Table 3. Table 4, Panel F Mean Efficiency Measures for the Portfolios of Firms with the Highest and Lowest ROA, ROE, and CA Portfolio N UNOR

    HROA LROA

    92 76

    0.53 (80) 0.55 (90)

    HROE LROE

    84 88

    0.46** (67)** 0.55 (81)

    HGR LGR

    88 88

    0.57 (77) 0.55 (79)

    HCA LCA

    92 104

    0.47* (80)* 0.52 (91)

    Notes: 1. * (**) indicates significance level of 10% (5%) for the test of equality between the efficient and inefficient portfolio or for

    correlations between variables. 2. HROA (LROA) is the portfolio of firms with the largest (smallest) ratio of return on assets, computed as net income in year t

    over average total assets at the end of year t-1 and year t. 3. HROE (LROE) is the portfolio of firms with the largest (smallest) ratio of net income in year t over average book value of equity

    at the end of year t-1 and t. 4. HGR (LGR) is the portfolio of firms with the highest (smallest) two-year average growth in direct premiums revenue. 5. HCA (LCA) is the portfolio of firm with the largest (smallest) ratio of operating cash flow in year t over average total assets at

    the end of year t-1 and year t.

  • 30

    Table 5 Analysis of Efficiency Measures and Organizational Form Table 5, Panel A Regressions Results of Stochastic Frontier in Cobb-Douglas Functional Form: ln C = 0 + JJln(PJ) + mBmtQm + vi+ui, ui~N(di, u2), di = + 1STOCKi + 2MIXi Intercept 3.4 (5.9) Amt 0.58 (19) Ann 0.047 (4.2) Ah 0.06 (6.3) Pl 0.011 (0.3) Pk 0.19 (3) Pm 0.19 (5) Alpha -13 (-3.9) STOCK -0.04 (-2) MIX 13.4 (3.9) Table 5, Panel B Means and Wilcoxon Rank Scores (in parenthesis) of Profitability and Growth Measures by Organizational Form Year Type of firm N ROA ROE CA GR

    95 Stock Mutual

    37 72

    0.02* (48)** 0.014 (59)

    0.11* (50) 0.09 (58)

    0.067 (50)* 0.055 (58)

    0.077 (53) 0.051 (56)

    96 Stock Mutual

    25 77

    0.017 (56)** 0.007 (36)

    0.10* (54)** 0.06 (41)

    0.08** (57)** 0.03 (33)

    0.077* (53)* 0.031 (44)

    97 Stock Mutual

    23 74

    0.02** (52)** 0.01 (39)

    0.11 (49) 0.09 (46)

    0.058**(53)** 0.028 (49)

    0.086 (50) 0.045 (45)

    98 Stock Mutual

    22 74

    0.017* (51)* 0.01 (40)

    0.1 (49) 0.8 (46)

    0.053* (53)** 0.023 (32)

    0.086**(50)* 0.029 (42)

    Overall Stock Mutual

    100 389

    0.02**(216)** 0.01 (164)

    0.1** (210)** 0.08 (181)

    0.065**(220)** 0.037 (153)

    0.08** (209)** 0.04 (183)

    Notes (Table 5): 1. Amt total amount of insurance. 2. Ann total annuity considerations. 3. AH total A&H considerations. 4. Pl price of labor. 5. Pk price of capital. 6. Pm price of indirect expenses. 7. Alpha intercept of di. 8. MUTUAL dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if stock company and 0 otherwise. 9. MIX is the mix of life policies ratio amount of insurance of whole life policies sold during the year over the total amount of

    insurance (whole + term) 10. In Panel A, T values appear in parentheses. 11. For definition of ROA, ROE, CA, and GR see notes to Table 4.

  • 31

    1 Prior to Gramm-Leach-Bliley act of 1999 banks could not underwrite insurance.

    However, they could sell insurance and have made major inroads into the annuity market.

    2 Additional encouragements for demutualization are greater access to capital markets,

    potential tax savings, and greater financial incentives for executives.

    3 The truncated normal, which Stevenson (1980) suggested, avoids the restriction of a

    zero mean for the normal distribution. However, it is not clear whether this restriction has

    any effect on the efficiency estimates. Moreover, based on our experience, when (the

    mean of u) is unrestricted, the log-likelihood seems to be ill behaved, the standard errors

    of the parameters are inflated, and the function cannot converge. The normal/gamma

    distribution, which Greene (1990) suggested, is superior to the other distributions since it

    does not restrict either the location or the shape of the distribution. However, the log-

    likelihood is currently highly complicated to estimate. In general, the ranking of the firms

    according to the efficiency score is preserved across the different distributions of u.

    4 Although OLS provides consistent estimates of the parameters with the exception of the

    constant term, maximum likelihood estimation provides more efficient estimates of the

    parameters.

    5 The choice between this cost function and the regular translog function relies on the

    statistical power of the estimated regression. The full translog function would increase

    the number of variables significantly. Given our sample size (see the Data Section) that

    would hamper seriously the statistical properties of the estimated regression and therefore

    of the inefficiency estimates.

    6 By using this measure we implicitly ignore the intermediary output associated with

    whole life policies. In this type of policies, insurance companies make a profit both on

  • 32

    the insurance and on the investments of the savings portion of the policy. However, we

    believe that the main output of the life insurance line of business is the insurance risk

    assumed by the insurer. Second, given the data limitations, it is impossible to separate the

    premiums on whole life policies into their insurance and savings components.

    7 Another potential proxy is the change in the amount of insurance in force during the

    year. It would measure the net additional amount of risk that the company assumes

    during the year. However, this measure could take on negative values in cases of

    reinsurance or when the amount of insurance paid is greater than the amount of insurance

    sold in any given year.

    8 Cummins and Zi (1998) and Grace and Timme (1992) control also for group and

    individual policies in the cost function. Given our sample size, we do not control for

    group and individual policies because of lack of degrees of freedom. Another important

    aspect that might affect the results is the marketing distribution system of the firm.

    Insurers use various marketing distribution systems such as branch offices, agencies and

    direct marketing. The results reported here are possibly associated with the distribution

    system. Most insurers, however, employ more than one distribution system and hence

    one cannot determine the unique distribution system of each firm.

    9 The AVR does not reflect future obligations (as do other reserves) but is set aside to

    protect against an extreme decline in the value of the assets that back up liabilities.

    10 We are aware that the financial capital is a stock variable while physical capital is a

    flow variable. We assume that flow is a fixed proportion of the stock.

    11 We measure these ratios over five years, rather than averaging the yearly ratios, in

    order to mitigate the influence of extreme fluctuations in the returns ratios on the price

  • 33

    of capital. If the price of capital in a particular case is negative--that is, if the five-year

    investment return was greater than the return on equity--we compute the price of capital

    as the average price of capital of the sample for that year.

    12 We do not account for the price of the physical capital in the aggregate price of capital

    since the related expenses are rather negligible compared to the magnitude of the

    financial capital.

    13 The data do not contain information as to the number of insured under A&H group

    master policies. Therefore, we used the number of master policies in the computation.

    14 EMaP is a detailed expense study of life insurance companies that chose to participate

    in the program. LOMA agreed to provide the data as part of a study of the cost structure

    of the life insurance industry.

    15 We did not use this procedure in estimating the SF measures for two reasons related to

    the software (Frontier (Coelli (1984)): (1) the program allows for only the half normal

    distribution assumption of the inefficiency component; and (2) the program uses only a

    simple Cobb-Douglas cost function, which imposes constant returns to scale.

    16 We did not include commissions and amount of financial capital in the computation of

    the cost of inefficiency because we believe that these variables are subject to less

    discretion by management as compared with other operating expenses.

    17 We computed the tax rate as the four-year mean of the ratio of tax expense to earning

    before income tax. If the computed tax rate is greater than 35% or negative, we changed

    it to 35% and 0%, respectively.

    Profitability, Growth and Efficiency in the US Life Insurance IndustryByDan [email protected] appreciate the helpful comments from Joshua Livnat, Ajay Maindiratta, Stephen Ryan, James Ohlson, and workshop participants at the Hebrew University of Jerusalem, New York University, Yale University, London Business School, and the University of ToroProfitability, Growth, and Efficiency in the US Life Insurance IndustryKey Words: Operational efficiency, Value drivers, Life insurance, Organizational form.The alleged linkage between operating performance and financial success is actually quite tenuous and uncertain Kaplan and Norton (1992)IV. Model Specification and DataOutputs

    V. Hypotheses and Research DesignVI. ResultsTable 1 Descriptive StatisticsTable 1, Panel B Analysis of Percentage of Premiums by Line of Business

    Life

    EFFREV is the ratio of cost of inefficiency over revenues.Table 3 The Stochastic Frontier Measure of InefficiencyYEAR

    Table 4 Analysis of Profitability, Growth and Inefficiency MeasuresTable 4, Panel A Distribution of Efficient, Partially Efficient and inefficient Firms and Their Mean InefficiencyTable 4, Panel B Means and Medians of Value DriversYEAR

    Value Driver

    PortfolioNTable 5 Analysis of Efficiency Measures and Organizational Form