A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    1/57

    A REGIONAL ANALYSIS OF MORTGAGE POSSESSIONS: CAUSES, TRENDS

    AND FUTURE PROSPECTS1

    By John Muellbauer, Professor of Economics and Official Fellow and Gavin Cameron, Research

    Officer, at Nuffield College, Oxford

    Executive Summary

    This paper analyses the variation in court possession actions and orders over regions and of

    total UK possessions rates, in order to understand better the causes of the high rates of

    mortgage possessions in the 1990s. It untangles the web of economic forces and

    administrative responses, and forms a view about future prospects.

    Data on court orders given actions and on suspended court orders provide evidence of a shift

    in behaviour by the Courts. Data on court actions brought by lenders provide evidence of a

    shift in behaviour by mortgage lenders. UK data on possessions rates reflect both shifts.

    Evidence suggests that there was a temporary softening of policy in the County Courts

    beginning in 1991 but that Court policy had returned to normal by 1995.

    Shifts in policy by lenders are probably a mix of intended changes in behaviour and initial

    delays in setting up systems to deal with possessions. The evidence suggests that this policy

    softening effect is gradually decaying.

    The outlook for the rate of possessions depends partly on how rapidly this effect decays, on

    the hard-to-quantify effects of the tightening of DSS rules from October 1995 for claimants,

    as well as on the macroeconomic fundamentals.

    1

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    2/57

    The analysis suggests that the falls in the rate of possessions seen at the end of 1996 will be

    followed by significant further falls in 1997-98 provided a significant rise in interest rates can

    be avoided.

    1. INTRODUCTION

    The years 1990 to 1995 saw a record number of households, around 345,000, containing perhaps

    one million individuals2 suffering the misfortune of mortgage possession. An important question

    concerns the institutional response to this crisis: was there a shift in policy by the courts and by

    the mortgage lenders? The purpose of this paper is to analyse the variation over regions, in order

    to understand better the causes of the high rates of mortgage possessions in the 1990s, untangling

    the web of economic forces and administrative responses, and to form a view about future

    prospects. This paper argues that there was a temporary softening of policy in the County Courts

    beginning in 1991 but that Court policy had returned to normal by 1995. There is evidence,

    however, that mortgage lenders are still a little softer'' than they were before 1991.

    We examine four sources of empirical evidence. First, aggregate UK data on the relationship

    between rates of mortgage arrears and possessions indicate a fall in possessions beginning in

    1991 while arrears continued to rise for two more years. This suggests a shift in policy or

    procedures by the courts and/or mortgage lenders. Second, regional data from County Courts for

    England and Wales show a rise in the ratio of suspended court orders beginning in 1991 and

    suggesting a softening of policy. Thirdly, the ratio of court orders to court actions was smaller in

    1991-94 than would have been expected given the economic fundamentals. These last two sets of

    evidence point to a shift in behaviour by courts. Fourthly, the rate of court actions was lower in

    2

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    3/57

    1992-96 than would have been expected given the economic fundamentals, pointing to a shift in

    behaviour by mortgage lenders.

    By pooling time series/cross section data across regions, the methodology is to identify national

    policy shifts by courts and by lenders in terms of common time effects across regions,

    distinguishable from economic fundamentals varying by region and by time. The importance of

    these time effects are confirmed in aggregate time series econometric models for the UK rate of

    mortgage possession. The paper concludes by considering prospects for the rate of court action

    for mortgage possession. The paper also throws interesting light on regional variations in rates of

    court actions and orders. For example, it destroys the myth that the possessions "crisis" was

    largely a Southern phenomenon. Fuller details are set out in the technical appendices to Sections

    4, 5 and 7 and in a data appendix.

    2. COUNTY COURT DATA AND THE HISTORICAL BACKGROUND

    (a) The Relevance of County Court Data

    In most cases, mortgage possession involves court proceedings. Ford et al (1995) report that even

    in cases where households voluntarily handed the keys of their property to their mortgage lender,

    evidence of court proceedings was often a requirement to be eligible for rehousing in the social

    rented sector. Thus, data on court proceedings are of more general interest for understanding the

    phenomenon of mortgage possession. Data on County Court actions and orders for mortgage

    possession have been published for 1986 to the present and on a quarterly basis since 1987. They

    are the only source of regularly available regional data to map possessions.

    3

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    4/57

    To be more specific about the nature of the data, the Lord Chancellor's Department defines terms

    as follows.

    Actions Entered: A plaintiff begins an action for an order for possession of residential property

    by way of a summons in a county court.

    Orders Made: The court, following a judicial hearing, may grant an order for possession

    immediately. This entitles the plaintiff to apply for a warrant to have the defendant evicted.

    However, even where a warrant for possession is issued, the parties can still negotiate a

    compromise to prevent eviction.

    Suspended Orders: Frequently, the court grants the mortgage lender possession but suspends

    the operation of the order. Provided the defendant complies with the terms of the suspension,

    which usually requires the defendant to pay the current mortgage instalments plus some of the

    accrued arrears, the possession order cannot be enforced.

    (b) Historical Background

    4

    Between 1980 and 1990 average mortgage debt in the UK more than doubled relative to income.

    The house price boom of the mid to late 1980s3 came to an end amid sharp rises in interest rates

    in 1988-1990, the response of the policy makers to the deterioration in the UK's balance of

    payments and inflation. House prices fell in nominal terms for the first time since the late 1950s,

    particularly in the Southern regions of the UK. This left many households, particularly those who

    had bought near the top of the boom, with negative equity. The combination of negative equity,

    and the drain on cash flows from the high interest rates of the 1988-1992 period and from income

    loss or business failure, was a particularly critical mix of circumstances. When households have

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    5/57

    positive equity, the opportunity to trade down is available as a response to cash flow problems.

    When households have negative equity, this is unavailable unless mortgage lenders and their

    regulators have a particularly tolerant attitude and allow households to trade down while

    retaining negative equity.4 Initially, negative equity products were not offered by most mortgage

    lenders, though these did become available increasingly over time (see the interview evidence

    cited by Ford et al (1995), ch 4). It appears that practices by the County Courts also altered in the

    1990s, with longer repayment periods for households in payment arrears being permitted, see

    Ford (1994) and Ford et al (1995), ch 5.

    To appreciate the context in which the policy of mortgage lenders and of courts is likely to have

    shifted, recall that in 1991 mortgage possessions were frequently headline news. Heightened

    public concern was reflected in the implicit contract agreed between the Government and

    mortgage lenders in November-December 1991, 6 months before the 1992 General Election, to

    reduce possessions. On the Governments side this included the commitment to pay DSS

    mortgage support payments direct to lenders rather than to mortgagors and to stimulate the

    housing market by raising the Stamp Duty ceiling for a year and by giving ear marked grants to

    housing associations to buy up properties originally intended for owner occupation, see Stephens

    (1996) for fuller details. By the time of the November 1994 Budget, however, public concern

    about possessions had faded sufficiently that the Government felt able to announce major

    reductions in the DSS safety net for new mortgagors and some reductions for existing

    mortgagors to take effect from October 1995, see Dale (1995 ) and Stephens (1996).

    5

    The Courts are unlikely to have been immune from these shifts in public and official concern. It

    can also be argued that the Courts may have placed more of the responsibility for mortgage

    default in the early 1990's on lending practices in the 1980s of some mortgage lenders and on

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    6/57

    macro policy mismanagement by the Government. This would also have led to a softening of

    court policies. The passage of time and a declining proportion of cases coming to court of

    mortgages originating in the 1980's would in due course cause a return to normal practices.

    It is also possible that what we interpret as a purposive temporary softening of policy may have

    been partly the result of the inability of existing court facilities to cope with the flood of

    possessions cases. This would imply an apparent softening of policy as the number of cases

    peaked, followed by an apparent hardening as the number of cases declined again. Mortgage

    lenders would have been subject to the same set of influences as defaults increased, including

    lags in training staff and setting up systems for dealing with cases. Interview evidence in Ford et

    al (1995) suggests this was the case.

    This view contrasts with another interpretation of a pattern of high possessions rates followed by

    lower rates. This emphasizes the efficiency and speed of reaction of mortgage lenders in

    possessing the most disastrous first, implying a later reduction in possessions rates. The latter

    would result from the change in the composition of the population at risk with the removal of

    many of the highest risk cases. As we will see, there are several important pieces of evidence

    against this interpretation.

    6

    In addition, two further arguments are often put forward. The first is that an apparent softening of

    policy could have been the result of the difficulty lenders had, particularly in 1991-3, in selling

    houses which had been taken into possession. A related argument concerns the fact that

    mortgage indemnity policies typically insured the top 25% of the value of a property. It has been

    argued that mortgage lenders therefore had incentives for taking possession rapidly when losses

    were small. Typically, homes in possession appear to sell at a discount below similar regular

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    7/57

    homes. Thus, when nominal house prices in Southern regions in 1991-3 fell to levels 10% or

    more below their 1988-90 levels, the argument is that mortgage lenders would have begun to

    bear a significant part of the losses and so had reduced incentives to exercise the possession

    option. Note that this argument would imply a significantly greater softening of policy in the

    Southern regions where the biggest nominal falls occurred. We test for such an effect later.

    There is a third, less controversial aspect to this line of argument. If, as Breedon and Joyce

    (1992) argue, taking homes into possession weakens house prices further, such action by one

    mortgage lender imposes negative externalities on the others by bringing about further defaults.

    Thus, there is scope for collective action. The implicit contract between mortgage lenders and the

    Government in November-December 1991 can be seen as providing just the required impetus for

    such collective action to slow possessions rates.

    To understand the variations that have occurred in rates of mortgage possession, such alleged

    shifts in behaviour need to be taken into account along with the influence of variations in

    economic conditions, such as the debt/equity ratio (i.e., the ratio of mortgage debt to the value of

    the home) and debt service ratios (i.e., the ratio of mortgage interest payments to income),

    unemployment shocks, small business failure rates, and house price developments. Indeed,

    econometric studies of aggregate mortgage possession data such as Breedon and Joyce (1992),

    Brookes et al (1994), and Allen and Milne (1994) estimated on data up to 1990 or 1991 break

    down badly on later data. These studies use mortgage arrears to help explain mortgage

    possessions. But from 1991, possessions started to fall while arrears continued to rise for some

    time, introducing a break in their relationship, see Chart 1. Though this is not conclusive

    evidence of a structural shift in behaviour, it is very much consistent with this hypothesis.

    7

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    8/57

    Incidentally, this shift in behaviour appears not to be due to distortions in the month in arrear

    data, see Muellbauer (1996), the source for the estimated 10% in arrear rate shown in Chart 1.

    CHART 1: RATES OF POSSESSION, 12 MONTH AND 10% IN ARREAR

    Note: The rates are log possessions rate, the log 12 month in arrear rate and the fitted log 10% balance in arrear rate

    3. REGIONAL CONTRASTS

    Regional data offer more scope than aggregate data for detecting such shifts in behaviour. It

    seems likely that shifts in behaviour by County Courts and mortgage lenders would be

    approximately uniform across the country, though short-term variations could be region

    specific: there is pressure on the courts to operate a national system of justice and the major

    mortgage lenders operate in all the regions. The housing market experience of different

    regions has been more diverse: nominal and real house prices have moved very differently in

    different regions and the timing of the build-up of mortgage debt differed across regions.

    Debt service ratios differ across regions with varying ratios of debt relative to income and the

    differential impact of the mortgage interest tax relief ceiling. Unemployment rates and small

    business failure rates have also varied substantially across regions. In these various

    dimensions, a broad North-South grouping of regions is helpful in summarizing information:

    within each broad group there were more shared experiences than between groups.

    To give some background to the regional data from the courts for 1986-1996, note that the

    Southern regions led the strong UK upswing in house prices in 1986-88. After interest rates

    rose from the summer of 1988 to a peak in 1990, house prices in the Southern regions slowed

    sharply and then declined in 1990-93 by 17 to 23%, even though interest rates were by then

    8

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    9/57

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    10/57

    CHART 2B: RATE OF COURT ACTIONS, DEBT/EQUITY RATIO AND DEBT

    SERVICE RATIO (NORTHERN REGIONS)

    Note: The Northern regions are defined as: North, North West, Yorkshire & Humberside, West Midlands and

    Wales

    To compare court actions across regions it is necessary to scale by the number of outstanding

    mortgages in each region. Charts 2A and 2B show basic data on court action rates,

    debt/equity ratios and debt service ratios, respectively averaged across Southern and Northern

    regions. These charts show that in 1986-1988 court action rates were higher in Northern than

    in Southern regions but that Southern rates rose more sharply to the 1991 peak before falling

    back to similar rates in 1995. These charts explode the myth that the possessions "crisis" was

    largely a Southern phenomenon.

    The charts also show that debt/equity ratios started lower in Southern regions, since

    historically loan-to-value ratios have been lower there, see Table 2 below. With the fall in

    nominal house prices after 1989, however, debt/equity ratios rose much more strongly there.

    Debt service ratios (defined in the note to Table 2) have throughout been higher in Southern

    regions. This is consistent with the systematically higher ratio of house prices to earnings

    found in these regions. The rising and falling pattern shows clearly the influence of the rises

    in interest rates in 1988-90 and the subsequent declines. Not surprisingly, our empirical

    results confirm the strong association between court action rates and debt service ratios

    visually apparent in these charts.

    10

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    11/57

    TABLE 2 AVERAGE LOAN TO VALUE RATIOS IN 1970-95 FOR FIRST-TIME BUYERS BY REGIONS

    ND 1986 VALUES OF DEBT/EQUITY AND DEBT SERVICE RATIOSAPeriod Yorks & East East South South West North

    North Humber Mid Anglia East West Mid West Wales

    LVR% 84.3 83.9 83.0 80.4 79.1 79.9 82.6 84.0 83.1

    Debt/Equity % 40.9 38.6 35.3 36.2 34.2 37.1 38.4 37.0 39.3

    D ebt/Service % 28.7 27.4 28.4 36.0 44.5 39.3 31.3 27.8 28.6Source: LVR from DOE 5% sample. Debt/Equity = average mortgage/average 1985 second-hand house price indexed by mix-adjusted

    indices. Debt Service = (average mortgage) (tax adjusted mortgage interest)/personal disposable income per capita indexed to regional

    earnings index, see forthcoming CML Discussion Paper for further details.

    It is instructive to look at court orders relative to court actions, see Charts 3A and 3B. Court

    orders, including suspended orders, rest on specific decisions by courts whereas court actions

    are largely the consequence of cases brought by mortgage lenders. There are some notable

    differences in movements of the ratio of orders to actions. In particular, there is little sign of a

    fall since 1992 in the South East, South West and East Anglia, in contrast to the other

    regions. This can be explained partly in terms of a worse underlying debt/equity position in

    the Southern regions, see Chart 2A. However, because of delays in court procedures, there is

    also a lag of orders behind actions.

    CHART 3A: RATIO OF COURT ORDERS TO ACTIONS, IMPLEMENTED ORDERS TO

    COURT ORDERS AND CHANGE IN NOMINAL HOUSE PRICES (SOUTHERN

    REGIONS)

    Note: The Southern regions are defined as: East Anglia, East Midlands, South East including Greater

    London, and South West

    11

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    12/57

    CHART 3B: RATIO OF COURT ORDERS TO ACTIONS, IMPLEMENTED ORDERS TO

    COURT ORDERS AND CHANGE IN NOMINAL HOUSE PRICES (NORTHERN

    REGIONS)

    Note: The Northern regions are defined as: North, North West, Yorkshire & Humberside, West Midlands and

    Wales

    Our econometric model is used to argue that, taking into account the deterioration in the

    economic environment and the lags, there appears to have been a fall in the ratio of orders to

    actions, particularly in 1991-4. This is interpreted as a relaxation of court policy. However,

    this feature of the data is not obvious to the naked eye examining Chart 3A and 3B: it only

    becomes apparent when controlling for the other forces acting on court orders. The empirical

    evidence is set out in Section 5 and its appendix.

    That there has been a shift in court policy is visually more obvious in examining the ratio of

    implemented orders to total orders since 1990, the period over which the data have been

    available, also shown in Charts 3A and 3B. This generally shows a decline since 1990,

    despite the deterioration in the economic environment. The increasing use of suspended court

    orders over this period can be taken to be a sign of a more lenient attitude by the courts

    particularly in 1991 and 1992 when house price falls and rises in unemployment were at their

    most severe. Charts 3A and 3B also show the rate of change of nominal house prices, clearly

    revealing the negative shocks occurring in 1991-2 in the Southern regions.

    The unemployment rate data throw further light both on the timing and the extent of the

    recent recession in different regions. Chart 4 shows that in Southern regions, unemployment

    12

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    13/57

    rates reached their low point in 1988, while in Northern regions this occurred in 1989.

    Furthermore, while in most of the Southern regions, the rise by 1993 led to unemployment

    levels similar to or higher than in 1986, in all Northern regions, the 1993 peak was still

    substantially below 1986 levels. Thus, regional differentials in unemployment rates narrowed

    sharply in the 1990s.

    CHART 4: UNEMPLOYMENT AND VAT DEREGISTRATION RATES

    Note: The Southern regions are defined as: East Anglia, East Midlands, South East including Greater

    London, and South West and the Northern regions are defined as: North, North West, Yorkshire & Humberside,

    West Midlands and Wales

    The peak year for business failures, as measured by de-registrations of firms from the VAT

    register shown in Chart 4, came one year earlier, in 1992, in all regions, though the peak was

    a little higher in Southern regions.

    4. ECONOMETRIC MODELS OF MORTGAGE POSSESSIONS

    In our view, the probability of possession is the result of the simultaneous occurrence of two

    factors: a vulnerable debt/equity position and a trigger factor including elements such as an

    unfavourable cash-flow position and unfavourable expectations for an improvement. A

    rational borrower would not default on a mortgage just because of cash-flow problems if the

    equity cushion relative to debt was sufficient to allow trading down or out.

    13

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    14/57

    Similarly, someone able to meet mortgage payments is unlikely to seek possession: UK

    borrowers who default face a high probability of being pursued for their unpaid debt in the

    future and of being denied access to credit for at least some years. The theoretical

    background to this is set out in more detail in the Appendix to this section.

    This is a more general view of mortgage possession than the option pricing approach popular

    in the US literature. (see Kau et al (1992), applied to UK data by Ncube and Satchell, (1994)

    and discussed by Dale (1995).) The Box below summarizes the key points of the option

    pricing approach and objections to applying this approach in the UK.

    14

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    15/57

    THE OPTION PRICING VIEW OF MORTGAGE POSSESSION

    Assumptions

    (a) as in many US states, the borrower's liability ends when he or she gives up the

    property deeds to the lender.

    (b) The possession decision is in the hands of the borrower.

    (c) There are no transactions costs.

    (d) There are no restrictions in access to credit: thus no risk of acquiring bad credit

    record.

    (e) rationality and good information.

    Conclusions

    Given assumptions (a) to (e), the rational borrower calculates the present value of

    mortgage payments and defaults if this exceeds the value of the house by some margin.

    This margin is not zero because by defaulting now, the borrower would give up the

    option of recovery or of defaulting in the future which has some value. Option pricing

    theory, assuming that house prices and interest rates follow simple statistical processes, is

    used to compute this margin.

    Objections

    Vandell (1995) reviews this US literature and the empirical evidence and argues that this

    approach is defective in a number of ways since it omits transactions costs, credit market

    imperfections, trigger events such as divorce or shocks to cash flows such as

    unemployment, and also omits the behaviour of mortgage lenders.

    Moreover, assumption (a) is violated in the UK: borrowers remain liable for their debt

    even after possession and lenders or their insurance companies can pursue borrowers for

    the negative equity and costs that remain after the possessed house has been sold off.

    Nevertheless, a precarious net equity position is undoubtedly an important element in the

    probability of possession and can be defined by the mortgage debt/equity ratio exceeding

    some threshold, where mortgage debt includes arrears. However, the probability of

    possession also depends on a trigger function which depends on current cash flows and

    shocks to income and house prices. Specifically, we assume the trigger rises with the debt

    15

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    16/57

    service ratio and the change in the unemployment rate and falls with positive house price

    shocks as measured by the rate of change or the rate of acceleration in house prices.

    One can think of default arising from the intersection of the events `debt/equity ratio exceeds

    some threshold' and `trigger exceeds another threshold'. We use standard probability

    argumentsto arrive at an expression for individual default probabilities and hence aggregate

    default rates by region. The economic fundamentals are represented by debt/equity ratios and

    the trigger effects mentioned above. See the appendix to this section for a fuller explanation

    of these points.

    16

    We model three aspects of the legal process dealing with mortgage default using County

    Court data by region: the ratio of implemented to total court orders, the ratio of total court

    orders to actions and the rate of actions itself. In each case, the outcome should depend on the

    economic fundamentals varying by region and by time, as discussed above, and on time

    effects for 1991 to 1996, the same across regions, capturing potential shifts in policy and the

    delayed reaction of courts and lenders to the possessions crisis. In addition, the equation for

    every region includes a factor specific to that region as a 'fixed effect' to capture long-run

    differences between regions such as differences in age and occupational structure, the

    ownership of financial assets and inequality within regions. See the appendix to this section,

    eq(5), for an illustration of the actions equation. Worse economic fundamentals should raise

    the court actions rate, decided by lenders, but also the ratio of implemented orders and the

    rate of court orders, determined by the courts, given actions brought. With worse economic

    fundamentals, the probability of a household avoiding eventual default falls so that, ceteris

    paribus, a higher proportion of actions brought results in court orders granted and

    implemented (rather than suspended) ones at that.

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    17/57

    To the list of economic fundamentals discussed above, we also added proxies for lending

    quality. For example, one of these was derived from changes in the market share of

    centralized mortgage lenders in the previous five years. Ford et al (1995) provide evidence on

    the higher default rates of mortgages from this source. Poor lending quality in the past should

    be associated with higher default rates. This effect shows up only in the equation for the rate

    of court actions. The previous year's rate of VAT deregistration as a proxy for small business

    failure was also found to affect the rate of court actions, but not the ratio of implemented to

    total court orders or the ratio of orders to actions.

    17

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    18/57

    Appendix to Section 4: Theoretical Background

    A precarious net equity position is undoubtedly an important element in the probability of

    possession and, when c is small, can be defined by

    ln (mortgage debt/equity) > c (1)

    where mortgage debt includes arrears. However, the probability of possession also depends on a

    trigger function which depends on current cash flows and shocks to income and house prices.

    Suppose

    trigger = f(debt service ratio, ur, lnhp) (2)

    and the debt service ratio,

    (mortgage debt)r

    dsr = -------------------- (3)

    y

    where r is the tax adjusted mortgage interest rate and y is personal disposable income, ur is the

    unemployment rate and hp is an index of house prices.5 The change in the unemployment rate

    ur is taken as a measure of income shortfalls and the rate of change of house prices lnhp as a

    proxy for shocks in the equity position. The debt service ratio and the change in the

    unemployment rate are expected to have a positive effect on the trigger, while the rate of change

    of house prices should have a negative effect.

    18

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    19/57

    Formally speaking, one can think of default rising from the intersection of the events

    ln(mortgage debt/equity) > c and trigger > c0. Then:

    Prob(default) = Prob(bad debt/equity) x Prob(bad trigger given bad debt/equity)

    (4)

    If the two events, 'bad debt/equity' and 'bad trigger' were independent,

    Prob (default) = Prob (bad debt/equity) x Prob (bad trigger)

    In practice, the two events will be positively correlated. In any event, we will be taking an

    approximation of (4) using the log mortgage debt/equity ratio and the variables in the trigger

    function by translating these probabilities for individual households into relative frequencies of

    regional populations of households.

    We have regional data on average house prices and average mortgages but not on the distribution

    of debt/equity ratios from which the vulnerable tail of the distribution could be analysed. Instead

    we rely on the existence of a relatively stable relationship between the vulnerable tail and the

    mean of the distribution.

    To make this more concrete, consider the distribution of log debt/equity illustrated in Figure 1.

    Define the vulnerable tail as being the part of the distribution where log debt/equity exceeds c.

    Note that the point 0 marks the point where debt equals equity. The area under the vulnerable

    tail of the distribution with mean M1 is shaded in grey. Now, suppose there is a fall in average

    house prices which shifts the distribution, denoted by the dotted line, to the right, so that the new

    mean is M2. The area under the vulnerable tail is now the bigger hatched area. Generally, as the

    mean M moves to the right, the vulnerable tail area increases. We now suppose that the log of

    19

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    20/57

    the vulnerable tail area can be approximated as a linear function of log mean debt/equity6, on

    which we actually have data.

    The theory above has been developed for mortgage possession considered broadly. In practice,

    possession can be initiated by mortgage borrowers or by lenders. Given information

    asymmetries between them and different objectives the possession probability given by (4) will

    not have exactly the same relationship with economic fundamentals for borrower or lender

    initiated possessions. However, one would still expect the same set of economic fundamentals to

    be operative in both cases. Most court actions fall into the latter category, but not all. As Ford et

    al (1995) observe, for households in possession to obtain access to local authority housing,

    possession has typically to be the result of court proceedings. In some cases, therefore, court

    actions may follow at the initial request of the borrower. However, it is safe to assume that the

    number of actions is not under the direct influence of the courts, though it may depend on the

    perceived probability of success, which may depend on court policies in the recent past.

    Thus we hypothesize that in the ith region the log percentage of court actions can be expressed

    by the following equation which can be stated in words as follows:

    log(court actions rate)it = constant + regional fixed effecti + time effectt

    + a1log (debt equity)it-1 + a2 debt service ratioit

    + a8 change in unemployment rateit + a4 VAT deregistration rateit-1

    - a5 rate of change of house pricesit - a6 rate of change of house pricesit-1

    + a7 indicator of poor lending qualityt-1

    20

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    21/57

    In symbols, this translates

    logpait = a0 + biDregioni + ctDyeart

    + a1 ldeit-1 + a2dsrit + a3urit + a4 VATit-1

    - a5lhpit -a6lhpit-1+ m5dsclt-1 (5)

    where

    Dregioni is a dummy variable which is 1 for region i and 0 for other regions

    Dyeart is a dummy variable which is 1 for year t from 1991 onwards and 0 for other years

    ldeit-1 is last year's value of the log (deb/equity) ratio

    dsrit is the debt service ratio in region i in year t

    urit is the change in the unemployment rate

    VATit-1 is last year's VAT deregistration rate in region i, a proxy for

    the small business failure rate

    lhpit is the change in the log house price index

    m5dsclt-1 is the 5 year moving average of the lagged change in the share

    of centralized mortgage lenders in total mortgages outstanding, a proxy

    for lending quality.7

    Equation (5) was arrived at by testing down from a more general specification including current

    and lagged values of the debt equity ratio, up to 2 lags in the debt service ratio, up to 2 lags in the

    unemployment rate and in the rate of change of house prices. This should be a general enough

    specification to be able to proxy reasonably well expectations by lenders of house prices, interest

    rates and incomes which could be relevant to the decision to bring a possession action.

    21

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    22/57

    As noted in Section 2(b) above, the time effects in eq.(5) are likely to represent a mix of

    influences: policy shifts by lenders, adjustment lags by lenders and a 'discouraged actions' effect

    as a result of a policy shift by the courts, resulting in a lower success rate for actions brought.

    It is also conceivable that the time effects partly reflect a composition shift in the population of

    households at risk of possession. Suppose, for example, that lenders brought actions against the

    most disastrous cases first. This would suggest high rates of possession at first, followed by

    some tailing off after the worst cases had been eliminated from the population at risk. One test of

    this interpretation involves testing the alternative hypothesis that the time effects are

    homogenous across regions. Since regions differ considerably, particularly in the timing and size

    of house price changes but debt/equity ratios, these composition effects should occur at different

    times in different regions but we can reject this. Another test of the change in composition

    hypothesis comes from noting that it implies a positive time effect in 1990 to compensate for

    later negative ones. We test this pattern in Section 5 and in Section 7 on UK aggregate data.

    Something like a pure court policy shift is likely to be directly measured by the estimated time

    effects in the equations for the rate of court orders, po, given the rate of actions brought. Court

    orders are at the discretion of the courts and not of the mortgage lenders bringing the actions.

    Since court procedures take time, we must build in a lagged reaction of orders to actions. But it is

    possible to accept the restriction that, in the long run, orders move in proportion to actions,

    provided one controls for the effect of changes in the economic fundamentals: worse economic

    fundamentals raise the ratio of orders to actions. The restriction can be imposed via an

    'equilibrium correction model' (see Hendry (1995)) linking logpo and logpa:

    22

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    23/57

    logpoit = b1logpait + b2(logpait-1 - logpoit-1) (6)

    + effects from region and year dummies and economic fundamentals

    Note that b2 < 1 and b1=0 would indicate partial adjustment of orders to last year's actions rate,

    while b2 < 1 and b1=b2 would indicate partial adjustment to this year's actions rate. Eq.(6)

    encompasses both.

    The other evidence for a shift in court policy can be found in the data for the ratio of

    implemented to total court orders, rio ie., 1-ratio of suspended to total court orders. This can be

    derived from the estimated time effects in an equation similar to (5) above but formulated for the

    ratio of implemented orders. We turn to the evidence in Section 5 and its appendix.

    23

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    24/57

    5. EMPIRICAL FINDINGS FOR REGIONAL DATA

    Full empirical evidence is set out in the appendix to this section. A summary now follows:

    The Ratio of Implemented to Total Court Orders

    We find that worse fundamentals, as seen in a higher debt/equity ratio, an increase in the

    unemployment rate, a high debt/service ratio and negative house price shocks, all

    significantly raise the ratio of implemented court orders. For example, a rise in the debt

    service ratio from 0.4 to 0.5, such as might be caused by the tax adjusted mortgage interest

    rate rising from 8% to 10%, after two years results in a 21% rise in the ratio of implemented

    to total orders, even ignoring the knock-on effects on unemployment and house prices.

    In terms of policy shifts, it appears that in 1991 and 1992, the ratio of implemented court

    orders was around 19% lower than would have been expected purely on the basis of the

    economic fundamentals. By 1993, this apparent softening of policy had fallen to 6% and had

    virtually disappeared by 1994. Though the precision of these findings must be qualified by

    the fact that these data only begin in 1990, they are consistent with the view that court

    procedures softened. The regional fixed effects suggest that the Southern regions tend to have

    slightly lower ratios than one might have expected given the economic fundamentals.

    Court Orders Given Court Actions

    24

    The model incorporates a lagged reaction of court orders to court actions resulting from

    typical delays in court procedures. The economic fundamentals found significant here are the

    debt/equity ratio, the change in the unemployment rate, the change in the debt service ratio

    and the rate of acceleration of house prices. A 10% rise in the debt/equity ratio results in the

    long run in a rise of around 6% in the ratio of court orders to actions.

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    25/57

    In terms of policy shifts, there was a drop in court orders relative to actions of around 14 or

    17% in 1991-92 compared with what might have been expected given economic

    fundamentals. The effect then fades in 1993-94 to one fourth of this magnitude and we can

    accept the hypothesis that it has disappeared by 1995. The fixed effects here suggest little

    systematic difference between southern and northern regions.

    The appendix to this section suggests that, while the general pattern is robust, the precise

    estimates of the policy shift effects have some sensitivity to the econometric specification.

    Modelling the Rate of Court Actions

    The rate of court actions responds strongly to last years debt/equity position (a 10% increase

    in the latter causing a 5 to 6% increase in the former) and in addition to the current change in

    nominal house prices (a 10% decrease raising the current court action rate by 14% and to

    high debt service ratios in the current year (a rise from 0.4 to 0.5 in the debt service ratio

    results in a 12% rise in the rate of court actions). There are also smaller effects from

    unemployment shocks and the previous years rate of VAT deregistration (for example, if

    this rises from 12% to 13% there would be a 5 to 6% rise in the court actions rate). 8 The

    proxy for lending quality based on the change in market lenders in the previous five years has

    a significantly positive effect. It suggests that the aftermath of lower lending quality of the

    late 1980s involved a rise of about 18% in the court actions rate.

    25

    The pattern of the time effects proxying various aspects of a policy shift by lenders and their

    reaction to the policy shift in the courts suggest an effect beginning at around 30% in 1992

    and gradually diminishing to around 8% in 1996. Thus, even in 1996, court action rates were

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    26/57

    about 8% below what would have been expected given the economic fundamentals. The

    decline between a 17% effect in 1995 and the 8% effect in 1996 may also reflect the

    tightening of DSS rules for benefit claimants discussed above. Thus, this evidence is

    consistent with a shift in policy by lenders after the November-December 1991 implicit

    contract between the Government and the lenders, and the view that lenders were generally

    still sticking with their agreement not to put into possession DSS claimants whose mortgage

    payments were being made direct to mortgage lenders. Assuming the proportion of such

    cases in the total of households at risk has declined, one would expect this effect to fade over

    time, as suggested by our estimates.

    This pattern of time effects is broadly similar in an alternative, less well fitting equation, that

    results when the lending quality is omitted. However, there are then notable readjustments of

    the effects attributed to the economic fundamentals. For example, the debt service ratio and

    the change in the unemployment rate become more important while the effect attributed to

    house price changes falls. The details are discussed in the appendix to this section.

    For court action rates, the regional fixed effects suggest strongly that, given economic

    fundamentals, the southern regions experienced systematically lower court action rates and

    Wales, in particular, systematically higher court action rates than the (other) English regions.

    There could be a number of reasons for this, including the greater ownership of financial

    assets, and the greater preponderance of non-manual workers in the southern regions. It is

    well-known that such workers tend to be lifted more easily out of cash-flow problems by

    higher earnings increases than manual workers.

    26

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    27/57

    Earlier we discussed the hypothesis that lenders may have held off from possession actions

    when house prices fell more than 10% below the 1988-90 average, since given selling costs

    and discounts, the lenders would then be sharing losses with the insurers. A variable

    measuring the number of quarters in each year when prices were more than 10% below the

    1988-90 average was constructed. This would have had a negative effect had the hypothesis

    been valid. However, its effect is positive in practice implying that economic fundamentals

    overwhelmed such a strategic response by the lenders. We also tested the hypothesis that

    policy shifts were significantly different across the North/South divide and were able to reject

    this hypothesis. This also casts doubt on the change in composition hypothesis discussed in

    Section 2(b) and Section 5 which attributes the decline in possessions to the early weeding

    out of the most at risk cases. The hypothesis also implies a positive time effect in 1990 (and

    perhaps 1991) followed by negative ones. This pattern can be rejected.

    27

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    28/57

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    29/57

    Worse economic fundamentals in the form of the two year average of the debt service ratio, the

    change in the unemployment rate and the log debt/equity ratio and the rate of change of house

    prices all raise the ratio of implemented orders. The region dummies do not show very

    systematic regional variations, though Wales and Yorkshire and Humberside (the reference

    region) followed by the North West show the highest ratios of implemented orders, while the

    South West followed by the South East show the lowest.

    The time effects for 1991-96 proved significant only for 1991, 1992 and 1993. They suggest that

    policy was softest w.r.t. suspended orders in 1991 and progressively tightened in 1992 and 1993,

    returning to 'normal'levels by 1994.

    Specification (7) was tested in two ways. First, against a more general specification of the

    economic fundamentals and time effects for 1994 to 1996. An F-test of (7) against a more

    general alternative involving 3 more time effects and 4 more parameters for the economic

    fundamentals (adding ldeit, urit, dlhpit-1 and dsrit-1 effects) gives F7,40 = 0.422 [p=0.88] which is

    insignificant at the 5% level. A second test involved adding interaction effects between the 3

    time effects and a dummy for southern regions. This checks that the claimed homogeneity of

    time effects across regions is statistically acceptable. Since economic circumstances differed

    considerably between southern and northern regions, this is quite a powerful specification test.

    The F-test here gives F3,44 = 0.774, which is also insignificant [p=0.51] at the 5% level.

    It is conceivable that lhpit is endogenous in that a shock to rioit might feed back within the year

    to depress house prices further. A simple check on this is to instrument lhpit using the fitted

    values from a parsimonious system of regional house price equations. The potential OLS bias is

    29

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    30/57

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    31/57

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    32/57

    logpoit = 0.16 +0.45 logpait +0.74(logpait-1 - logpoit-1)

    (2.3) (6.5) (10.3)

    +0.04DEA +0.02DEM +0.10DNN +0.05DNW

    (0.01) (0.6) (2.7) (1.7)

    +0.03DSE -0.05DSW +0.02DWW -0.01DWM

    (1.4) (1.4) (0.4) (0.4)

    +0.33ldeit-1 +0.045 urit -1.85av2lhpit

    (3.8) (2.5) (9.7)

    -0.20D91 -0.21D92 -0.10D93 -0.08D94

    (3.3) (3.0) (2.4) (2.6) (9)

    s.e. = 0.0624 R2 = 0.951, DW = 2.32

    The most interesting difference between eq(8) and eq(9) is in the pattern of time effects reflecting

    the softening of policy and the decay of this policy shift. Eq(9) suggests a peak in 1992 and then

    a monotonic decay, which looks marginally more plausible than the pattern of point estimates in

    eq(8). Given the limitations of the evidence on court policy shifts from the ratio of implemented

    orders in subsection (a) above, the evidence in (8) and (9) is fairly consistent with that in (7).

    Both specifications suggest little systematic regional variation in the ratio of orders to actions

    between regions, though the North stands out slightly as having a high ratio where the South

    West has a low ratio of orders to actions.

    c. The court actions rate

    The specification was discussed in the appendix to Section 4, see eq(5). As noted there, the time

    effects here reflect a mix of policy shifts and adjustment lags by lenders, in part reacting to court

    policy shifts. The results are as follows:

    logpait = 2.00

    32

    (7.2)

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    33/57

    -0.19DEA -0.04DEM -0.06DNN +0.13DNW

    (3.9) (1.3) (1.7) (3.2)

    -0.20DSE -0.20DSW +0.30DWW +0.15DWM

    (3.3) (4.6) (6.7) (5.2)

    +0.55ldeit-1 +0.03 Durit +1.23dsrit

    (5.9) (2.3) (4.8)

    -1.54 lhpit -0.53 lhpit-1 +5.02VATit-1 +16.2m5dsclit-1

    (10.2) (3.9) (2.6) (3.1)

    -0.27D92 -0.27D93 -0.25D94 -0.19D95 -0.08D96

    (8.4) (5.3) (5.4) (3.5) (1.1) (10)

    s.e. = 0.0583, R2 = 0.969, DW = 1.88, sample 1987-1996, 90 observations

    This specification of the three has the most comprehensive set of significant economic

    fundamentals including VAT deregistration and the proxy for past lending quality. Testing this

    specification against an even more comprehensive one containing also the current log debt/equity

    ratio, the unemployment rate, the lagged debt service ratio, a lagged dependent variable and a

    1991 dummy gives an F-test, F5,62 = 1.00 [p=0.43] which is not significant at the 5% level.9

    Testing against an alternative that permits the time effects to be different for southern regions

    gives an F-test F5,64 = 1.56 [p=0.18] which is also not significant at the 5% level.

    Again, a check on the endogeneity oflhpit contradicts the hypothesis of an endogeneity bias.

    The point estimate of the instrumented coefficient is marginally more negative and a Hausman

    test confirms the absence of bias [p=0.77].

    The regional dummies suggest a systematic North/South pattern of differences: compared with

    the reference region, of Yorkshire and Humberside, East Anglia, the South East and the South

    33

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    34/57

    West all have substantially lower court actions rates, while Wales, the West Midlands and the

    North West have substantially higher court actions rates than economic fundamentals would

    have predicted.

    These regional fixed effects capture long-run differences between regions, for example, in age

    and occupational structure, income-age profiles, income riskiness, and the ownership of financial

    assets and hence in the relationships between the average and the size of the vulnerable tail for

    the distributions of debt/equity and debt service ratios. Thus, for example, the lower court action

    rates in the southern regions may reflect the greater ownership of financial assets there, see

    Regional Trends, the higher proportion of white collar workers and the somewhat younger age

    structure. It is well known that income-age profiles peak later for non-manual workers than for

    manual workers. Since younger households typically have greater debt exposure, the fact that in

    southern regions, many of these households can expect substantial age related income increases

    means that for given average debt/equity and debt service ratios, it is likely that a higher

    proportion of southern households would find themselves lifted away from the mortgage default

    margin. This would help to account for the lower court action rates in southern regions, given

    the measured economic fundamentals included in our equation.

    This is all still consistent, however, with a higher 1991 peak for the court actions rate in southern

    regions than in the rest of the economy: that, of course, is explained by the greater deterioration

    in economic fundamentals in the southern regions.

    34

    As noted earlier, the time effects for court actions are likely to reflect in part the impact that

    'softer' court policies would have had on the propensity of mortgage lenders to bring actions.

    The lower the probability of success, the less likely is an action to be brought. This 'discouraged

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    35/57

    action' effect is likely to lag behind the shift in court policies. Indeed, we find no detectable

    effect in 1991 of a softening of lenders policies as reflected in the court actions rate. Recall also

    that the implicit contract between the mortgage lenders and the government to reduce

    possessions rates in return for various government concessions was negotiated in

    November/December of 1991 so that hardly any of the consequences would have shown up in

    the 1991 figures.

    An alternative interpretation of the negative time effects in 1992-5 discussed in Section 2(b)

    suggested that they may have been the result of a shift in the composition of borrowers at risk in

    which lenders dealt with the most disastrous cases first. This would then have led to a tailing off

    of the proportion of actions brought with the worst cases eliminated from the population at risk.

    This hypothesis, however, implies given the late 1989 peak in house prices, a corresponding

    increase in 1990 and/or 1991 above levels warranted by observed economic fundamentals, in the

    rate of court actions brought. To test this we included a 1990 and a 1991 year dummy with

    respective coefficients -0.01(t=0.2), -0.07(t=0.6). The hypothesis can therefore be rejected in

    favour of our policy softening alternative.

    These estimates suggest a steady decline in the softening of lenders policies, though the effect

    had still not quite faded out in 1996, with the point estimate suggesting an effect about one

    quarter of the 1992 effect. This is consistent with the hypothesis that those who bought in 1988-

    91, the cohort likely to have been most subject to mortgage default, are making up a lower and

    lower proportion of new cases.

    35

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    36/57

    If we omit the proxy for poor lending quality, the lagged dependent variable becomes significant

    and we obtain a more gradual fading out, with the 1996 effect only just under one half of the

    1992 effect, see eq.(11):

    logpait = 1.06 + 0.30logpait-1

    (2.8) (4.5)

    -0.18DEA -0.04DEM -0.02DNN +0.07DNW

    (3.3) (1.2) (0.4) (1.5)

    -0.31DSE -0.24DSW +0.26DWW +0.09DWM

    (5.8) (5.2) (5.3) (2.5)

    +0.40ldeit-1 + 0.06 urit

    (3.1) (5.3)

    +1.83dsrit - 1.09 lhpit +5.20VATit-1

    (8.4) (7.5) (2.5)

    -0.31D92 -0.23D93 -0.29D94 -0.18D95 -0.13D96

    (8.1) (4.2) (5.8) (3.1) (2.1)

    (11)s.e. = 0.0640, R2 = 0.962, DW = 2.34

    sample 1987-1996 90 observations

    Whether one accepts the implications of eq(11) - slow fade out - or of eq(10) - fast fade out of

    policy softening - depends on whether one regards the lending quality proxy in eq(10) as

    plausible. Certainly eq(10) fits better.

    36

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    37/57

    6. FORECAST - SCENARIOS FOR 1997

    This section considers some forecast scenarios for 1997. An analysis of aggregate quarterly

    data suggests that the UK possessions rate is forecast better from data on the court actions rate

    (for England and Wales) in the previous four quarters, together with some economic

    fundamentals, than from data on the court orders rate combined with economic fundamentals.

    Since our earlier discussion suggests that court orders depend on court actions, forecasting court

    actions is the key. We now consider three forecast scenarios applied to each of our respective

    specifications (10) and (11) detailed in the Appendix to Section 5. These are included to make

    the point that differences in the econometric specification do have forecast implications.

    Specification (10) has somewhat weaker interest rate and unemployment effects and somewhat

    stronger house price effects than specification (11). Specification (11) also suggests that it takes

    a little longer for these effects to feed through.

    The common features of the scenarios set out here are the assumption of a 1.2% fall in the

    unemployment rates in South East, the South West and East Anglia and a 1% fall elsewhere,

    nominal personal disposable income per head rising by 7.4% in these Southern regions and

    6.4% elsewhere, the same change in the VAT deregistration rate as in the previous year, and

    the assumption, as far as policy by the lenders is concerned, that the court actions rate is 5%

    below the rate implied by economic fundamentals (as opposed to 8% in 1996). We have

    assumed the tightening of the DSS rules is already reflected in the 1996 time effect so that

    there is no additional effect in 1997.

    37

    Scenario I is a moderately optimistic one with stable interest rates and a significant house

    price recovery. Scenario II is a pessimistic one. Scenario III is the most optimistic both

    about interest rates and house prices. Table 3 summarizes the key points.

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    38/57

    Scenario I Scenario II Scenario III

    Adjusted mortgage

    interest rate in 1997

    same as 1996 1 percentage

    point higher

    same as 1996

    House price increase

    in South East, East

    Anglia, South West

    12% 10% 17%

    House price increase

    in rest of England

    and Wales

    7% 6% 12%

    38

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    39/57

    Table A.1 Regional Court Action Rates for Mortgage Possession: Forecasts and Historical

    Data (Percentages)

    Scenario Scenario Scenario

    I II III

    I II III

    I II III

    1991 1995 1996 1997 1997 1997

    East Anglia 1.76 0.77 0.76 0.65 0.71 0.61

    East Midlands 1.86 0.90 0.82 0.81 0.86 0.75

    South East 2.45 0.93 0.85 0.71 0.78 0.66

    South West 2.05 0.85 0.76 0.68 0.73 0.63

    North 1.47 0.70 0.79 0.67 0.70 0.62

    North West 1.98 1.10 1.05 0.92 0.97 0.85

    Wales 2.21 1.14 1.04 0.82 0.86 0.76

    West Midlands 2.08 0.94 0.86 0.87 0.92 0.81

    Yorks &

    Humberside

    1.74 0.86 0.87 0.81 0.85 0.75

    Southern Regions 2.24 0.90 0.82 0.71 0.78 0.66

    Northern Regions 1.90 0.95 0.93 0.84 0.88 0.78

    England & Wales 2.10 0.92 0.87 0.77 0.82 0.71

    Source: see text

    39

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    40/57

    Note: results based on equation 10. These results are marginally different from Table 4 in

    the Housing Finance paper for reasons discussed in footnote 9.

    Table A.2 Regional Court Action Rates for Mortgage Possession Forecasts and HistoricalData (Percentages)

    Scenario Scenario Scenario

    I II III

    1991 1995 1996 1997 1997 1997

    East Anglia 1.76 0.77 0.76 0.70 0.76 0.66

    East Midlands 1.86 0.90 0.82 0.87 0.94 0.82

    South East 2.45 0.93 0.85 0.71 0.79 0.68

    South West 2.05 0.85 0.76 0.70 0.77 0.66

    North 1.47 0.70 0.79 0.74 0.79 0.70

    North West 1.98 1.10 1.05 0.99 1.06 0.94

    Wales 2.21 1.14 1.04 0.92 0.98 0.87

    West Midlands 2.08 0.94 0.86 0.91 0.97 0.86

    Yorks &

    Humberside

    1.74 0.86 0.87 0.88 0.95 0.84

    Southern Regions 2.24 0.90 0.82 0.73 0.81 0.69

    Northern Regions 1.90 0.95 0.93 0.90 0.97 0.86

    England & Wales 2.10 0.92 0.87 0.81 0.88 0.77

    Source: see text

    Note: results based on equation 11.

    40

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    41/57

    The differences in specification of equations 10 and 11 noted above most relevant for

    forecasting into 1997 are two: eq(10) displays smaller effects from the debt service ratio while

    eq(11) displays more persistence, via the role of the lagged dependent variable. The latter is

    the main reason why the fall in court action rates between 1996 and 1997 in Scenario I is larger

    in Table A.1 (from eq(10)) than in Table A.2 (from eq(11)).

    With a larger debt service ratio effect in eq(11), Table A.2 then shows a sharper rise in court

    action rates going from Scenario I to Scenario II than does Table A.1. Note that Table A.2

    suggest that even a 1 percentage point rise in the average mortgage rate for 1997 compared

    with 1996, would be sufficient to undo the benefits operating via higher incomes, lower

    unemployment and the upward momentum in house prices: for England and Wales,

    particularly for northern regions, the court actions rate is predicted to rise. Although Table

    A.1 has less negative implications, even it suggests that the magnitude of interest rate rises

    which the July 2nd Budget has put in prospect may well negate the effects of other

    improvements in economic conditions, particularly in northern Britain. However, much will

    depend on the size of the ripple effect that rises in house prices in London and the more

    affluent parts of the South East will have on other regions. Scenario III, which assumes the

    strongest house price rises, shows the differences both at the regional level and for England

    and Wales in comparison with Scenario I.

    41

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    42/57

    7. UK EVIDENCE ON THE POSSESSIONS-ARREARS RELATIONSHIP

    Chart 1 above demonstrated the shift that took place in the 1990s in the relationship between

    CML data on the rate of possessions and the proportion of mortgages 12 months or more in

    arrear. Previous work by Breedon and Joyce (1992), Brookes, Dicks and Pradhan (1994) and

    Allen and Milne (1994) has modelled the CML (Council of Mortgage Lenders) data on

    possessions in terms of arrears and other determinants. These authors impose the constraint that

    in the long run, the flow of possessions moves in proportion to the number of households in long

    term arrears, defined variously as over 6 months or over 12 months. Chart 1 which plots the rate

    of possession, pp, plotted against the ratio, p12m, of households 12 months or more in arrear to

    the number of mortgages, shows that in 1991 possessions peaked and then declined while the

    stock of arrears continued to climb before turning down also. As discussed below, this cannot be

    explained by the measurement error in the arrears data which arises when interest rates change.

    Chart 1 also plots log p10f, the fitted value of the proportion of mortgages over 10% in arrear

    against the log of the possession rate.

    Econometric analysis confirms this visual impression. Using a quarterly interpolation of the

    biannual CML data, we were able to find a simple relationship between the rate of possessions,

    the arrears rate, the debt service ratio, the unemployment rate and the change in house prices

    once time dummies for 1991-1997, reflecting policy shifts, are included. In the long run, the

    ratio of possessions to long-term arrears cases rises by around 50% for an increase in the debt

    service ratio of 25%, equivalent to a rise in the after tax interest rate from 8% to 10%. An

    increase in the unemployment rate from 8% to 10% in the long run also implies an increase in

    the ratio of possessions to arrears of around 50%.

    42

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    43/57

    The time effects show a clear hump shaped pattern beginning in 1991, peaking in 1993 and

    declining steadily to 1997. Their magnitude, particularly if they were given a steady state

    interpretation (see appendix), is clearly larger than of the corresponding time effects in regional

    court orders and court actions equations, respectively reflecting court policy shifts and policy

    shifts by mortgage lenders. To some degree this is likely to reflect the fact that policy shifts by

    both sets of agents are reflected in possessions outcomes. But a bigger factor is that the softening

    of lenders policy that occurred after the end-1991 implicit contract with the government, not

    only reduced possessions but increased the count of numbers in arrears. Indeed, the latter would

    be the logical consequence of the former. Econometric models of the arrears rate confirm a

    pattern of positive time effects between 1992 and 1996, also with a hump-shaped time profile.

    This must mean a double element in the gap between possessions and arrears.

    The combination of the aggregate time series evidence on possessions and arrears also fails to

    support the hypothesis that the decline in the possessions rate from 1991 was caused by the early

    weeding out by lenders of the most at risk cases. This would have resulted in respectively

    positive and negative time effects in 1990 or even 1991 in the possessions and arrears equations

    followed by the reversal of these effects in subsequent years. But these 1990-1991 effects are

    absent.

    43

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    44/57

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    45/57

    between possessions and court orders. In the regional orders and actions equations reported in

    the appendix to Section 5 we tested and rejected the possibility of within the year feedback from

    court orders and actions to house prices. In a quarterly context, feedback seems even less likely,

    and so we do not test for it. The time dummies capturing shifts in policy by courts and by

    lenders and possibly implementation lags by the latter enter in a moving average form - for

    example, md91 is equal to 0.25 in 1990Q4, 0.75 in 1991Q1, 1 in both 1992Q2 and 1991Q3, 0.75

    in 1991Q4 and 0.25 in 1992Q1. This form has the effect of centering the total annual effect

    correctly at mid-year. The policy shift effect as estimated takes a hump-shaped form, building

    up to its strongest (negative) effect in 1993 and declining to 1997. These effects are large and

    highly significant. A proxy for lending quality, defined as in the appendix to Section 5, based on

    long moving averages of the change in the market share of centralized mortgage lenders proved

    insignificant. This suggests that the proportion of 12 month arrears cases sufficiently reflects the

    decline in lending quality that probably took place in the late 1980s.

    In order to examine parameter stability, the model was also estimated up to 1990Q3 (omitting the

    policy shifts obviously). The estimated parameters are remarkably stable, with a slightly higher

    feedback term and a slightly lower effect of the lagged house price change.

    logppt = 1.00 + 0.33(logp12mt-1 - logppt-2) + 1.39dsrt(3.2) (4.6) (5.8)

    + 0.058urt-2 - 2.33lhpt - 1.09lhpt-1

    (4.7) (6.5) (3.1) (13)

    s.e = 0.0432, R2 = 0.897, DW = 1.68

    Sample period 1983Q1 - 1990Q3.

    45

    The chi-squared statistics for respectively 1st, 2nd, 3rd and 4th order residual autocorrelation are

    0.08, 0.66, 0.24, 1.51, which again confirms the lack of residual autocorrelation.

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    46/57

    This remarkably simple model implies that in the long run, the rate of possessions moves in

    proportion to the rate of 12 month arrears. However, if the debt service ratio or unemployment

    are high or if house prices are falling, then possessions will be higher than implied by arrears

    alone.

    The feature of eq(12) that deserves further discussion is the remarkably large coefficients on the

    time dummies, for example -0.50 for the 1993 dummy. Had this been a permanent effect, it

    would have implied a long-run reduction of the log possessions rate, given the 12 month arrears

    rate, of 0.50/0.27 = 1.85, since the coefficient on the equilibrium correction term is 0.27. This is

    far bigger than the time dummy effects for the log court actions rate estimated in eq(10) or

    eq(11).

    46

    As noted in the main text of Section 7, a key component of the explanation of this apparently

    surprising finding lies in the nature of what a policy softening by mortgage lenders implies for

    the number of mortgages classified to be over 12 month in arrear. The crucial part of the implicit

    contract between the government and the mortgage lenders in November/December 1991 was

    that the lenders would refrain from exercising possession in cases where DSS mortgage

    payments were being made directly to mortgage lenders. This would have led to many cases

    creeping into the 12 months in arrear category without experiencing the possessions proceedings

    that would previously have ensued.10 Thus, the policy softening should have led to a significant

    increase in the proportion of mortgages 12 months in arrear. Indeed, an econometric model for

    the 12 months in arrear rate shows significantly positive time dummy effects in 1992-95. Thus

    the gap between the possessions rate and the arrears rate widened more than between the

    possessions rate and measures of economic fundamentals such as the debt/equity ratio, debt

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    47/57

    service ratio etc., but excluding the arrears rate. The econometric evidence on the arrears rate

    suggests that about two thirds of the widening gap between the possessions rate and the arrears

    rate is due to the post-1991 shift in the arrears rate.

    It is conceivable that another component of the explanation of why the 1992-5 time effects are so

    much bigger in eq(12) than eq(10) and eq(11) lies in the well-known measurement biases of the

    months in arrear data. When interest rates rise, monthly payments rise so that the number of

    months a mortgage is classified to be in arrear temporarily falls. Thus arrears levels are

    underestimated when interest rates are high and over-estimated when interest rates are low.

    Since interest rates fell for much of 1991 to 1995, arrears levels would have been overestimated

    relative to 1989-90, thus exaggerating the gap between possessions and arrears rates and helping

    to account for the size of the 1992-95 time dummies.

    Since 1993, the Council of Mortgage Lenders have published a count of the number of arrears

    cases which should be free of this measurement bias based on a percent in arrears concept, eg.,

    5% in arrear, 10% in arrear. Muellbauer (1996) provides estimates back to 1983 of what the

    10% in arrear rates would have been, had they been collected earlier. Imperfect though these

    estimates probably are, they do permit a check on the measurement bias hypothesis. Running

    eq(12) with the estimated log 10% in arrear rate replacing the log 12 months in arrear rate results

    in similar (indeed marginally higher) estimates of the 1992-95 time effects, suggesting that the

    measurement bias hypothesis is not the explanation of the large time effects in eq(12).

    47

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    48/57

    CONCLUSIONS AND OUTLOOK

    We have analysed regional data on court actions, court orders and implemented court orders

    to investigate empirically the influence of variations in the macroeconomic and the regional

    economic environment on these indicators of mortgage default. We have found evidence of

    substantial shifts in these relationships beginning in 1991 and similar across regions,

    reflecting what we term policy shifts'' by Courts and mortgage lenders. As our discussion

    indicates, these shifts are probably a mix of intended changes in behaviour and initial delays

    in setting up systems to deal with the possessions crisis. Our evidence on the UK relationship

    between possessions and long-term arrears also shows these shifts in behaviour. The court

    orders data suggest that by 1995 County Court practices had returned to normal, given the

    court actions submitted to them. In contrast, the data both on regional court actions and on

    UK possessions cases suggest that by 1995 the mortgage lenders were still possessing at rates

    significantly below what one would have expected on the basis of the economic

    fundamentals. This would be consistent with the implicit promise made in 1991 not to

    possess in cases where DSS mortgage payments were being made direct to mortgage lenders.

    The evidence is that this policy softening effect is gradually decaying. The outlook for the

    rate of possessions depends partly on how rapidly this effect decays, on the hard-to-quantify

    effects of the tightening of DSS rules from October 1995 for claimants, as well as on the

    macroeconomic fundamentals.

    48

    At least as far as the latter are concerned, there have been major improvements since 1995

    with the further reduction in interest rates, rising house prices, especially in Southern regions

    and falling unemployment rates. The lags in the response of court actions, court orders and

    possessions rates to these macrofundamentals are considerable. This will mean that the falls

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    49/57

    seen at the end of 1996 will be followed by significant further falls in 1997-98 provided a

    significant rise in interest rates can be avoided.

    49

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    50/57

    Data Appendix

    Data for 1986 to the present on court orders and actions for mortgage possessions in English

    regions and Wales are available from the Lord Chancellor's Department.

    We want to scale these data relative to the number of mortgages outstanding per region. These

    are estimated, following methods pioneered by Anthony Murphy, as follows: from Labour Force

    Survey (LFS) Housing Trailers for 1971, 1981, 1984, 1988 and 1991-93, we obtain estimates of

    the fraction of owner-occupiers with mortgages, omi for region i, at the end of each year.11 We

    can obtain fairly accurate estimates of this fraction for the UK as a whole by dividing, nm UK, the

    number of mortgages outstanding (Housing Finance, Table 29) by ohsUK, the number of owner-

    occupied houses (Housing and Construction Statistics, Table 9.3), where all figures are at year

    end. Let romi be the ratio omi/omUK. By fitting a cubic in time to romi we generate interpolated

    estimates for 1985 to 1995, fromi. We then define the estimated nmI, the number of mortgages in

    region i by

    ohsi

    nmi (nmUK) (fromi) ______

    ohsUK

    Thus, the share of the number of UK mortgages in the ith region equals the share of owner-

    occupied houses scaled by fromi.

    We define, pa, the percentage of mortgages in the ith region in year t subject to Court actions as

    (actit/nmit-1) x 100, where actit is the number of actions in region i, year t, and analogously for

    Court orders, po. In logs, these variables are denoted logpa and logpo, respectively.

    50

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    51/57

    Among the explanatory variables, several rely on estimates of ami, the average mortgage

    outstanding in region i. These estimates use information on rmpi, the ratio of average mortgage

    interest payments per household in each region to that in the UK from the Family Expenditure

    Survey for 1974-95. Data on the average UK mortgage stock could then be scaled by these ratios

    to obtain estimates of average mortgage stocks in each region. These ratios are not ideal for this

    purpose, being subject to large sampling variations, particularly in the less populous regions. We

    use estimated ratios interpolated from cubic equations in time fitted for each region to overcome

    sampling variation. Also, at times when many households are increasing their mortgage arrears,

    actual recorded mortgage payments will understate the size of mortgage debts. Later, when

    households are paying extra to reduce their arrears, mortgage payments will overstate the size of

    mortgage debts. To the extent that this occurs uniformly across regions, these biases will cancel

    out. However, we have reason to believe that mortgage arrears are higher in regions with high

    mortgage possession rates. Our estimates are necessarily crude, therefore.

    We estimate average debt/equity ratios for each region by scaling the average mortgage am it-1 by

    hpit, an estimate of the average second-hand house price. This multiplies the Department of the

    Environment's (D.O.E.) mix adjusted index for the region by the average dwelling price for

    `other dwellings' in 1985 from Housing and Construction Statistics, Table 10.9. We denote the

    log of the debt/equity ratio as ldeit.

    51

    The debt-service ratio is computed as the product of the tax-adjusted mortgage interest rate

    (abmrit) and the average mortgage (amit-1) divided by an estimate of after-tax male earnings (yit)

    scaled by the ratio of average UK male tax adjusted earnings to UK personal disposable income

    per head. Note that this definition of the debt-service ratio omits the repayment element in

    regular mortgage payments. Thus,

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    52/57

    dsrir = (abmrit) (amit-1)/yit

    In turn, abmr is defined as (1-sittrt) (gross Building Society mortgage rate), where trt is the

    standard rate at which tax relief applies and sit is an estimate of the fraction of mortgages under

    the tax relief ceiling. sit varies from region to region. A simple estimate would define sit = 1 if the

    average mortgage is under the tax relief ceiling of 30,000 and s it = 30,000/amit-1 otherwise. But

    this would neglect the inequality of the distribution of mortgages which would, for example,

    ensure that some mortgages were over the ceiling even with an average mortgage of 25,000 say.

    sit incorporates an approximate adjustment12 to reflect this.

    The Building Society mortgage rate comes from Housing Finance, Feb. 1996, Table 26. Up to

    1987, the figures measure the annual average interest rate by dividing recorded payments by the

    average mortgage stock outstanding. These figures reflect premiums or discounts as well as

    delays for some societies between announcements of interest rate changes and their

    implementation. However, the financial years of some societies did not coincide with the

    calendar year in all cases. From 1988, the figures are an annual average of end of month rates,

    which also should reflect discounts and implementation delays. Abbey National and Cheltenham

    and Gloucester are excluded from July 1989 and August 1995 respectively.

    After-tax male earnings by region comes from the New Earnings Survey and are April figures.

    The tax adjustment also varies across regions, estimating tax rates from Regional Accounts data

    on personal disposable income and personal income.

    52

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    53/57

    Regional unemployment rates derive from registration records at Job Centres, refer to all workers

    and come from Economic Trends.

    Regional estimates of the fraction of businesses de-registered for VAT come from Department of

    Employment Gazette, November 1991 and updates were kindly provided by the Department of

    Trade and Industry.

    A measure of credit quality was constructed from data on the share of centralized mortgage

    lenders in the value of total mortgages outstanding in the UK published in the Historical

    Compendium of Housing Finance Statistics. If the change in the share is denoted dscml, the 5

    year moving average is denoted m5dscml and we work with the lagged value of this.

    Quarterly data for Section 7 were obtained as follows. Data on the biannual flow of mortgage

    possessions cases and on the end of December and end of June count of cases where arrears were

    over 12 months are published by the Council of Mortgage Lenders. Interpolating (log-linearly)

    the arrears data is straightforward as one would expect, for example, the September figure on

    average to be half way between the June and December figures. Interpolating the biannual flow

    of possessions data into a quarterly flow is less obvious. Assuming that the two quarters in each

    half year had the same possessions levels or rates would be unrealistic: for example, if

    possessions are trending upwards, the earlier quarter should have a lower level than the later

    quarter. A moving average procedure in which, for example, the quarter 1 figure is given by one

    third of the first half figure plus one sixth of the last half of the previous years figure yields a

    first set of estimates. These are then scaled to ensure that in each half year the sum of the two

    estimated quarterly figures adds up to the recorded figures for the half year.

    53

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    54/57

    The definition of the debt service ratio for quarterly data is similar to that for annual data except

    that the income measure is personal per capita disposable income. Both it and the tax adjusted

    mortgage interest rate are defined at annual rates. The quarterly unemployment rate and

    quarterly rate of change of house prices come from the sources quoted above.

    54

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    55/57

    ENDNOTES

    1. This paper is a revised and extended account of the research behind our paper, with

    the same title in Housing Finance, May 1997. This research was supported by the

    Council of Mortgage Lenders and the ESRC under grant R000 23 4954. We are

    grateful for helpful comments to Fionnuala Earley, Janet Ford, David Hendry, Duncan

    MacLennan, Anthony Murphy, George Speight, Mark Stephens, Peter Williams and

    seminar participants at the Universities of Glasgow and Oxford, at University

    College, Dublin, University College, London and at the CML Conference `Modelling

    Possessions and Arrears', 25 February 1997.

    2. The survey evidence of Ford et al (1995) suggests that the average family size of

    these households was not much smaller than of all households with mortgages.

    3. See Muellbauer and Murphy (1997) for an analysis of its causes.

    4. That is, formally to permit loan-to-value ratios for new lending to exceed 100% by

    significant margins.

    5. Note that this definition excludes the repayment component of debt service cost. For a

    given mortgage life, this moves in the opposite direction from the interest rate, stabilizing

    slightly the true debt service ratio. However, as suggested in Muellbauer (1996), the

    average mortgage life for borrowers facing possession or in arrears has fallen in the

    1990s. This resulted in a substantially smaller reduction in the debt service ratio than

    would have been expected from the fall in interest rates.

    6. Log mean debt/mean equity is the log of a ratio of arithmetic means while mean log

    debt/equity, as illustrated in Figure 1 is the log of a ratio of geometric means. These are

    not identical but will move very closely together for the kinds of distributional shifts

    illustrated in Figure 1.

    7. It is widely believed that in aggressively bidding for market share in the latter half of the

    1980s, the centralized mortgage lenders, who lacked a High Street base, were forced to

    accept higher risk customers or to lend at riskier loan to income or loan to value ratios.At any rate, the evidence from Ford et al (1995) is for a higher rate of possessions

    associated with mortgages from this source.

    8. Note this would imply almost a one for one increase in percentage terms. Lest this

    seem large, note that the trough to peak increase in the VAT deregistration rate was

    only 2percentage points in Southern regions. This suggests that a little under one

    fifth of the rise in the court actions rate in Southern regions can be attributed to the

    rise in small business failure.

    55

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    56/57

    9. An alternative specification with very similar implications returns the lagged dependent

    variable but drops the lagged house price change. This fits a little worse. It was used to

    generate the Table 4 forecasts reported in the Housing Finance paper which explains why

    the scenarios reported below differ marginally.

    10. Note that DSS mortgage payments do not include repayment of arrears or of interest on

    previous arrears or on additional loans collateralized on housing. This explains why even

    when DSS mortgage payments are being made, mortgage arrears levels can continue to

    drift upwards.

    11. Though these data are not available annually, they are based on a larger and probably

    more consistently representative sample than the annual Family Expenditure Survey,

    from which they show systematic divergencies.

    12. Ideally, the adjustment would use the distribution of mortgages in each year in eachregion to count the fraction of mortgages under the tax relief ceiling. We do not have

    such data even at the national level. Instead, we take the distribution of national mortgage

    advances as a proxy for the distribution of mortgages, at least as far as the upper tail is

    concerned. It is used to fit a relationship between the average mortgage advance and the

    fraction under the tax relief ceiling. This relationship is then applied at the regional level,

    given data on the average mortgage in each region, but subject to the constraint that sit

    cannot exceed unity.

    56

  • 8/2/2019 A Regional Analysis of Mortgage Possessions

    57/57

    BIBLIOGRAPHY

    Allen, C and A Milne, (1994),Mismatch in the Housing Market, Urban Studies, 31, 1451-

    1463.

    Breedon, F J and M A Joyce, (1992), House Prices, Arrears and Repossessions: A Three

    Equation Model for the UK,Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, May, 173-179.

    Brookes, M, M Dicks and M Pradhan, (1994), An Empirical Model of Mortgage Arrears

    and Repossessions,Economic Modelling, 11, 2, 134-144.

    Dale, Peter, (1995), Future Mortgage Default,Housing Finance, 25, February, 14-20.

    Ford, J, Problematic Home Ownership, Joseph Rowntree Foundation, September, 1994.

    Ford, J, E Kempson and M Wilson, (1995), QTRMortgage Arrears and Possessions:

    Perspectives from Borrowers, Lenders and the Courts, HMSO: London.

    Hendry, D F, (1995), Dynamic Econometrics, Oxford University Press.

    Kau, J B, D C Keenan, W J Muller and J F Epperson, (1992), A Generalized Valuation

    Model for Fixed-Rate Residential