35
Center for Behavior, Institutions and the Environment CBIE Working Paper Series #CBIE-2015-010 A Framework for Mapping and Comparing Behavioral Theories in Models of Social-Ecological Systems Maja Schluter Stockholm Resilience Centre Andres Baeza National Socio-Environmental Synthesis Center (SESYNC) Gunnar Dressler UFZ, Helmholtz Centre for Environmental Research e UFZ Karin Frank UFZ, Helmholtz Centre for Environmental Research e UFZ Jurgen Groeneveld UFZ, Helmholtz Centre for Environmental Research e UFZ Wander Jager University College Groningen Marco A. Janssen School of Sustainability Ryan R.J. McAllister CSIRO Birgit Muller UFZ, Helmholtz Centre for Environmental Research e UFZ Kirill Orach Stockholm Resilience Centre Nina Schwarz UFZ, Helmholtz Centre for Environmental Research e UFZ Nanda Wijermans Stockholm Resilience Centre December 16, 2015

A Framework for Mapping and Comparing Behavioral Theories in

  • Upload
    vokien

  • View
    219

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: A Framework for Mapping and Comparing Behavioral Theories in

Center for Behavior, Institutions and the Environment

CBIE Working Paper Series

#CBIE-2015-010

A Framework for Mapping and Comparing Behavioral Theories in Modelsof Social-Ecological Systems

Maja SchluterStockholm Resilience Centre

Andres BaezaNational Socio-Environmental Synthesis Center (SESYNC)

Gunnar DresslerUFZ, Helmholtz Centre for Environmental Research e UFZ

Karin FrankUFZ, Helmholtz Centre for Environmental Research e UFZ

Jurgen GroeneveldUFZ, Helmholtz Centre for Environmental Research e UFZ

Wander JagerUniversity College Groningen

Marco A. JanssenSchool of Sustainability

Ryan R.J. McAllisterCSIRO

Birgit MullerUFZ, Helmholtz Centre for Environmental Research e UFZ

Kirill OrachStockholm Resilience Centre

Nina SchwarzUFZ, Helmholtz Centre for Environmental Research e UFZ

Nanda WijermansStockholm Resilience Centre

December 16, 2015

Page 2: A Framework for Mapping and Comparing Behavioral Theories in

The Center for Behavior, Institutions and the Environment is a research center located within the Biosocial ComplexityInititive at ASU. CBIE can be found on the internet at: http://csid.asu.edu. CBIE can be reached via email [email protected].

c©2015 M. Schluter. All rights reserved.

2

Page 3: A Framework for Mapping and Comparing Behavioral Theories in

A Framework for Mapping and Comparing Behavioral Theories in Models ofSocial-Ecological Systems

Maja Schlutera, Andres Baezab, Gunnar Dresslerc Karin Frankd Jurgen Groenevelde Wander Jagere

Marco A. Janssene Ryan R.J. McAllistere Birgit Mullere Kirill Orache Nina Schwarze NandaWijermanse

aStockholm Resilience Centre;bNational Socio-Environmental Synthesis Center (SESYNC);cUFZ, Helmholtz Centre for Environmental Research e UFZ;dUniversity College Groningen;eSchool of Sustainability;fCSIRO;

Corresponding author:Maja SchluterStockholm Resilience Centre, Stockholm University, Krftriket 2b, 10691 Stockholm, [email protected]

Abstract:Formal models are commonly used in natural resource management (NRM) to studyhuman-environment interactions and inform policy making. In the majority of applications, humanbehavior is represented by the rational actor model despite growing empirical evidence of itsshortcomings in NRM contexts. While the importance of taking into account the complexity of humanbehavior is increasingly recognized it remains a major challenge to integrate it into formal models.The challenges are multiple: i) there exists many theories scattered across the social sciences, ii) mosttheories cover only a certain aspect of decision-making, iii) they vary in their degree of formalization,iv) causal mechanisms are often not specified. With this paper we provide a framework to facilitate abroader inclusion of theories on human decision making in formal NRM models. It serves as a tool andcommon language to describe, compare and communicate alternative theories. In doing so, we notonly enhance understanding of commonalities and differences between theories, but also support a firststep in tackling the challenges mentioned above. This approach may enable modelers to find andformalize relevant theories, and be more explicit and inclusive about theories of human decisionmaking in the analysis of social-ecological systems.

Page 4: A Framework for Mapping and Comparing Behavioral Theories in

1

A framework for mapping and comparing behavioral

theories in models of social-ecological systems Maja Schlütera, Andres Baezab, Gunnar Dresslerc, Karin Frankc, Jürgen Groeneveldc, Wander Jagerd,

Marco A. Janssene, Ryan R.J. McAllisterf, Birgit Müllerc, Kirill Oracha, Nina Schwarzc, Nanda

Wijermansa

a Stockholm Resilience Centre, Stockholm University, Kräftriket 2b, 10691 Stockholm, Sweden,

[email protected], [email protected], [email protected]

b National Socio-Environmental Synthesis Center (SESYNC), 1 Park Place, Suite 300, Annapolis, MD

21401, USA, [email protected]

c UFZ, Helmholtz Centre for Environmental Research e UFZ, Department of Ecological Modelling,

Permoser Str. 15, 04138 Leipzig, Germany, [email protected], [email protected],

[email protected], [email protected], [email protected]

d University College Groningen, Hoendiepskade 23-24, 9718 BG Groningen, The

Netherlands,[email protected]

e School of Sustainability, Arizona State University, PO Box 875502, AZ 85287-5502Tempe, USA,

[email protected]

f CSIRO PO Box 2583 Brisbane Q 4001 Australia, [email protected]

Corresponding author

Maja Schlüter

Stockholm Resilience Centre

Stockholm University

Kräftriket 2b

10691 Stockholm, Sweden

[email protected]

Page 5: A Framework for Mapping and Comparing Behavioral Theories in

2

Abstract 1

Formal models are commonly used in natural resource management (NRM) to study human-2

environment interactions and inform policy making. In the majority of applications, human behavior 3

is represented by the rational actor model despite growing empirical evidence of its shortcomings in 4

NRM contexts. While the importance of taking into account the complexity of human behavior is 5

increasingly recognized it remains a major challenge to integrate it into formal models. The 6

challenges are multiple: i) there exists many theories scattered across the social sciences, ii) most 7

theories cover only a certain aspect of decision-making, iii) they vary in their degree of formalization, 8

iv) causal mechanisms are often not specified. With this paper we provide a framework to facilitate a 9

broader inclusion of theories on human decision making in formal NRM models. It serves as a tool 10

and common language to describe, compare and communicate alternative theories. In doing so, we 11

not only enhance understanding of commonalities and differences between theories, but also 12

support a first step in tackling the challenges mentioned above. This approach may enable modelers 13

to find and formalize relevant theories, and be more explicit and inclusive about theories of human 14

decision making in the analysis of social-ecological systems. 15

16

1. Introduction 17

Formal models have been used extensively to study the interactions between humans and their 18

environment, as well as inform policy making (e.g., Meadows et al, 1972; Clark, 1976; Nordhaus, 19

1994). In natural resource management (NRM), modelling has advanced our understanding of the 20

dynamics of natural resources, their response to management interventions and environmental 21

change, as well as their vulnerabilities and regenerative capacities. This has informed policy 22

decisions on harvest quotas, CO2 emission budgets, agri-environmental schemes as well as the 23

identification of biodiversity hotspots and corridors for inclusion in protection programs 24

(Karagannakios, 1996; Meinshausen et al, 2009; Myers et al., 2000; Simberloff and Cox, 1987). The 25

focus on understanding natural resource dynamics and their optimal management has, however, 26

neglected humans and their behavior as a key uncertainty for sustainable management (Fulton et al. 27

2011). Given that natural resource use systems are social-ecological systems in which humans shape 28

and depend on their biophysical environment (Berkes and Folke 1998), their adaptive responses to 29

policy and environmental change cannot be neglected (e.g., Palmer and Smith 2014). Therefore, 30

modelling approaches need to explicitly combine ecological dynamics and human behavior to 31

address the interactions between the different domains. However, integrating human behavior into 32

formal models on natural resource use and management is still a major challenge (Janssen and 33

Jager, 2000; Fulton et al. 2011, Milner-Gulland 2012, Schlüter et al. 2012). 34

Common approaches for integrating human behavior into formal models of social-ecological systems 35

couple economic theory with resource dynamics (e.g., Clark, 1976; Nordhaus, 1994), capture human 36

aggregated responses in feedback loops (e.g., Meadows et al., 1972), or use ad hoc assumptions 37

(Smajgl and Barreteau, 2014). While the former is prescriptive in that it aims to determine the 38

optimal resource management strategy or the optimal policy option given a set of constraints, the 39

latter two aim to describe actual system dynamics by explicitly incorporating human behavior. The 40

first approach is often based on very simple assumptions about human decision-making, namely the 41

concept of the selfish rational actor, also referred to as homo economicus. The frequent use of the 42

Page 6: A Framework for Mapping and Comparing Behavioral Theories in

3

rational actor in modelling human behavior and decision-making in NRM is not surprising since it is 43

the standard model in economic theory and is straightforward enough to include in mathematical 44

formulations. However, the key assumptions of the rational actor—that she has perfect knowledge 45

and stable preferences, is selfish and makes calculations to identify an optimal decision that 46

maximizes utility—are in contrast with empirical observations of how people actually make decisions 47

concerning natural resource use (Siebenhuner, 2000; Van den Bergh et al., 2000). Also the 48

assumption that these “deviations from optimal behavior” can be considered as “noise,” and hence 49

would cancel out in large populations does not hold because much of these deviations are 50

systematic. For example, in real life, people have their cultural habits, learn from other people, and 51

often obtain utility from interacting with and helping other people (e.g., see Gintis 2000; Fehr and 52

Gintis 2007, Fehr and Schmidt 1999). Such behavioral drivers and processes are expected to have 53

consequences for the dynamics and performance of social-ecological systems at large. 54

The importance of including the relevant complexity of human behavior in the study of human-55

environmental interactions has been alluded to in recent publications (e.g., Janssen and Jager, 2000; 56

Worldbank, 2015). The World Bank’s report on “Mind, Society and Behavior” (Worldbank, 2015) 57

explicitly acknowledges the importance of capturing the most advanced understanding of how 58

humans think and how context shapes thinking for the design and implementation of policies. 59

Others argue that the current focus on a small set of theories of human decision-making in policy 60

assessment (such as climate policy) limits the relevance of those exercises (Victor, 2015). Since 61

formal models are used to inform policy making, the lack of inclusion of social science expertise can 62

considerably limit both the usefulness of formal models and the effectiveness of policies. 63

There is an abundance of theories in the social sciences that describe and test how people behave in 64

various contexts. For example, in social and cognitive psychology, research has focused on processes 65

of decision-making (e.g., Todd, Gigerenzer & the ABC Research Group 2012), social influence (e.g 66

Cialdini and Goldstein, 2004), information processing (e.g., Anderson 1990), time discounting (e.g., 67

Hardisty et al, 2012), and reinforcement learning (Skinner, 1953), just to mention a few. Theories 68

have been developed on the gains and losses of group decision-making and situational and 69

procedural contexts that affect outcomes (for an overview see e.g., Kerr and Tindale, 2004). In 70

behavioral economics, the focus is directed at heuristics and biases, prospect theory and the framing 71

of decisions (see e.g., Kahneman, 2003). However, this impressive body of knowledge has barely 72

found its way into the field of natural resource management in general and social-ecological systems 73

modelling of resource management contexts in particular. 74

Modelers who aim to introduce alternative theories on human behavior and decision-making in their 75

models of natural resource management, however, face several challenges (see section 2 for a more 76

detailed discussion): (i) the vast amount of theories on human decision-making, some of which are 77

even competing, makes orientation in the field very difficult. Moreover, the available knowledge is 78

fragmented across different disciplines and disciplinary languages. Theories can have different foci, 79

such as emphasizing the importance of selected social or environmental aspects. (ii) As a 80

consequence, some theories on human decision-making address very detailed aspects of decision-81

making, while others are very broad and comprehensive. Modelers need to recognize this diversity 82

in scope and aims and may even have to combine several theories in order to model the process of 83

human decision-making in a comprehensive way. (iii) Depending on their methodological 84

background (experimental, conceptual, empirical), theories on human decision-making vary also 85

with respect to the degree of formalization. This implies that modelers will have to specify elements 86

Page 7: A Framework for Mapping and Comparing Behavioral Theories in

4

and/or processes of these theories to varying extents. (iv) Modeling social-ecological systems means 87

simulating these systems over time, requiring the specification and representation of causalities in 88

the models. Many theories on human decision-making tend to focus on correlations and thus lack an 89

understanding of causal mechanisms that can be translated into a dynamic model. Modelers, thus, 90

have to make assumptions about causalities when using such theories in their models. Overall, these 91

issues make the selection of relevant theories for natural resource management situations and their 92

formalization in social-ecological models and comparison very challenging. 93

This manuscript is a modest step toward providing a framework to address these challenges and 94

facilitate a broader inclusion of knowledge on human decision-making in formal models of SES. The 95

aim is to support the identification, operationalization and integration of alternative behavioral 96

theories into formal models of natural resource management. More specifically we aim to 97

encourage modelers to think more systematically about the implementation of human decision-98

making in their models and make use of the diversity of human decision-making theories from the 99

social sciences where possible. The purpose of this framework is therefore threefold: 100

● to provide a tool and common language for mapping, describing, organizing, comparing and 101

communicating theories of human decision-making and by doing so 102

● to enhance understanding of commonalities and differences such that modelers can make 103

informed choices of which theory is relevant for a given context and research question, and 104

● to support the operationalization of behavioral theories in formal models by providing 105

guidance on relevant factors and processes of decision-making and facilitating a more 106

systematic implementation procedure 107

To provide a framework that meets these purposes is an ambitious goal. In order to make concrete 108

progress, we narrowed down the type of decisions we were focusing on. The result is a focus on 109

resource users (representing individuals, households or villages) making decisions on when, where, 110

how and how much to appropriate from a resource— these are decisions on what crop to plant, 111

where to fish and how many trees to cut. We do not include, for now, higher- level collective choice 112

decisions, such as changing institutional rules, but we do include decisions on compliance to rules 113

and social norms. 114

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows: In section 2, we discuss the challenges modelers 115

face when formally modelling human behavior. In section 3, we introduce the framework and apply 116

it to a number of concrete theories from various social sciences in section 4. In section 5, we discuss 117

the framework and conclude by considering how we may use this framework to implement different 118

theories in simulation models, compare them and inform policy analysis. 119

120

2. The challenge of formally modelling human decision-making 121

Modelers need to overcome a number of challenges if they want to include theories on human 122

decision-making in their dynamic models. As outlined above these relate to the need to navigate a 123

vast amount of theories scattered across many fields; to deal with different foci, levels of 124

comprehensiveness and formalization; and to assign causality where a theory may remain rather 125

unspecific. In the following we briefly discuss these challenges in more detail. 126

Page 8: A Framework for Mapping and Comparing Behavioral Theories in

5

The first challenge is finding relevant theories and navigating the vast amount of available theories 127

and knowledge about human decision-making. Various social sciences (economics, psychology, 128

anthropology, sociology, political science, etc.) study human behavior in diverse and sometimes 129

specialized contexts, using various theoretical approaches and terminology. In fact, each discipline or 130

even sub-discipline experiences a range of alternative theories that aim to explain very specific 131

aspects of human behavior. For example, explaining why people cooperate in one-shot prisoner’s 132

dilemma experiments can depend on cultural factors, emotions, cognition, and neural or hormonal 133

processes (Henrich et al., 2001; Hopfensitz and Reuben, 2009; Moll and Tomasello, 2007; Rilling et 134

al., 2002; Eisenegger et al., 2011). This has lead to many specific theories that relate to partial 135

processes of human decision-making and behavior, next to a few generic (overlapping) theories. The 136

Theory of Planned Behavior (Ajzen, 1991), for instance, is a more generic theory describing how 137

behavioral beliefs and attitudes, normative beliefs and subjective norms, together with control 138

beliefs lead to an intention to perform a behavior and influence the actual execution of that 139

behavior. Hence this theory describes a full process, ranging from the formation of beliefs towards 140

the performance of behavior. An example of a specific theory would be the Elaboration Likelihood 141

Model (Petty and Cacioppo, 1984). This theory addresses the process of persuasion. It discriminates 142

between central processing, where involved and capable people process arguments in shaping their 143

beliefs, and a peripheral route, where less involved and less capable people evaluate cues—such as 144

the attractiveness of the source—in in shaping beliefs. This fragmentation of knowledge makes it 145

challenging to know the implications of different theories for different context interacting with each 146

other at a system level. 147

A second challenge is that, from a modeler’s perspective, decision-making theories are often not 148

complete. Formalizing a theory often uncovers logical gaps in the theory that must be filled in order 149

to make a simulation work. Assumptions thus have to be made by the modeler that were not given 150

by the theory (Sawyer, 2004). For example, when modelling human decision-making according to the 151

Theory of Planned Behavior (Ajzen, 1991) one needs to specify the subjective norm, which refers to 152

an individual's perception about how significant others (e.g., parents, spouse, friends, teachers) 153

would judge the behavior under consideration. For the modeler the theory does not specify this in a 154

way that allows for formalization. It remains open what other agents are “significant others” and 155

what their level of significance is. The theory does not specify what principle should guide the 156

formalization of the significance of other agents. Obviously, more specific theories can serve as a 157

guide in this formalization, such as perspectives on interpersonal attraction. Variables can be 158

identified (such as similarity, expertise, physical attractiveness, familiarity) that have an effect on 159

who is considered to be a significant other, and, obviously, this differs among people, among 160

situations, and over time, confronting the modeler with a vast unlimited horizon. This requires that a 161

modeler identify the main drivers to be modelled, and make “crude assumptions” on the modelling 162

details and then carefully check the robustness of model results to these assumptions. These 163

challenges are not unique to formalizing of theories of human behavior. In fact most theories in the 164

life and social sciences experience some ambiguities when translated into formal equations. This is in 165

contrast to many theories in economics and physics that are described through mathematical 166

equations. 167

The third challenge is introducing causality. Simulating human interactions with the environment 168

over time requires the specification of causal relationships about how psychological, social and 169

environmental factors influence an agent’s decision-making. Many of the theories, however, do not 170

Page 9: A Framework for Mapping and Comparing Behavioral Theories in

6

specify causal mechanisms since they are based on empirical correlations and focus on the 171

relationship between factors at one moment in time. Modelers thus need to make explicit 172

assumptions on processes and mechanisms, for example, how the provision of factual information 173

about the actual behavior of individuals within a community, such as the average energy 174

consumption in a neighborhood or the amount of alcoholic consumption in a student population, 175

affect decision-making (Cialdini and Goldstein, 2004). To translate this into causal relations for a 176

model, we need to specify functional forms on how information about the behavior of others 177

changes the likelihood of certain choices. This relationship can be explained in various ways, for 178

example, by the fact that people want to conform to others or that the option that is dominant in 179

the community becomes more salient. Ambiguities or lack of knowledge on how variables relate to 180

each other and determine the development of the system over time make it very important to be 181

explicit about assumptions made and their implications for model results. 182

In sum, the challenge of modelers is to identify and transform relevant theories on human decision-183

making into crisp causal relationships, while the best available knowledge is fragmented, context 184

dependent and descriptive. Given these challenges it is no surprise many models rely on rational 185

choice, which is based on a clear, unified theory that has and can be easily formulated in 186

mathematical equations. But rational choice theory does not represent our empirical knowledge on 187

human decision-making. By providing a framework to communicate the knowledge from various 188

relevant theories we want to support a first step in tackling these challenges and enable the 189

modelling community to find, filter and formalize relevant theories. This may enable them to be 190

more explicit and inclusive about the various theories of human decision-making in the analysis of 191

social-ecological systems. 192

193

3. A framework of human behavior in natural resource use contexts 194

We took an iterative approach in developing the framework that involved formulating its elements, 195

mapping theories and revising the formulation. We based its formulation on insights from a review 196

of reviews of human decision-making in social-ecological systems (Cooke et al. 2009; Meyfroidt, 197

2013; Scarlett et al. 2013; Van Vugt and Griskevicius, 2014) and in agent-based models (Carley and 198

Newell, 1994; Bousquet and Le Page, 2004; Hare and Deadman, 2004; Matthews et al. 2007; 199

Heckbert et al. 2010; An, 2012; Balke and Gilbert, 2014) as well as experience with our own 200

implementations of different decision-making models in agent-based models of natural resource 201

management. Definitions given below for the components of the framework draw upon general 202

definitions, e.g., given by the Merriam Webster dictionary, to avoid biasing the framework towards 203

one specific scientific discipline. 204

A framework that supports communicating and comparing different theories of human decision-205

making needs to be generic enough to capture the majority of theories and at the same time allow 206

for a meaningful distinction between them. With this aim in mind we decomposed the decision-207

making process within an individual into three major parts: 1) what comes in (perception), what goes 208

out (behavior) and what happens in between (i.e., rules’ and representations that lead to the 209

selection and execution of a behavior) (Figure 1). In Figure 1, the outer box represents the social and 210

biophysical environment and thereby the decision context of an individual. The individual herself 211

(inner box) is represented by the structural elements (state and perceived behavioral options) and 212

processes involved in decision-making. Decision-making involves both conscious and unconscious 213

Page 10: A Framework for Mapping and Comparing Behavioral Theories in

7

processes that lie in the interface of the individual and the environment (perception and behavior) 214

and internal processes (evaluation and selection). We argue that different theories of behavior can 215

be described as alternative configurations (presence and/or specification) of the structural elements, 216

processes and context of an individual. 217

The seven elements that make up our framework are defined and further detailed in Table 1. They 218

are connected through flows of information or processes that make up the decision-making process 219

as indicated by the solid arrows in Figure 1. An agent perceives the state of its environment, 220

evaluates the information and possibly updates its state. The state and the perceived behavioral 221

options enter the selection process, where the behavioral option that fulfills given 222

goals/needs/satisfaction criteria is identified. The behavior is executed and affects the state of the 223

social and bio-physical environment. For simplicity we focus on the main interactions between the 224

elements, however, other ones are possible and likely. It is also important to note that not every 225

theory includes or specifies all of the steps and that they do not necessarily follow this sequence. 226

The dashed arrows represent the influence of one element on another. The state of an agent for 227

instance may influence the perceived behavioral options, by either constraining an originally broader 228

set of perceived behavioral options (e.g., due to limited available assets) or by enabling the agents to 229

choose from additional behavioral options (e.g., due to new knowledge). The set of perceived 230

behavioral options can also change over time as the result of learning, forgetting or changes in 231

attention. Furthermore, the state may impact on the selection process by activating a different 232

selection process (e.g. due to being dissatisfied). Finally, the perceived behavioral options may 233

influence the search process regarding the search routines that can be executed on a given set (e.g., 234

an optimization is not useful for a set with only one option). 235

Page 11: A Framework for Mapping and Comparing Behavioral Theories in

8

236

Figure 1. The framework of individual decision-making, allowing for the comparison of selected 237

behavioral theories to model human behavior. Solid arrows and corresponding ellipses indicate 238

processes, boxes represent structural elements. Dashed arrows represent an influence of one 239

element on another, e.g. the state influencing the set of perceived behavioral options. 240

Page 12: A Framework for Mapping and Comparing Behavioral Theories in

9

Table 1: Definition and specifications of the different elements of the framework. Definitions are adapted from the Merriam Webster dictionary.

Element Definition Specification/Examples

Context

Social & Biophysical Environment

The environment the individual and her behavior are embedded in

Social Env: actors and institutions1 that might affect individual decision-making through information exchange,

coordination, satisfying need for belonging, etc. Biophysical Env: the biophysical properties and dynamics of elements such as a resource, a population or an ecosystem relevant for a particular decision context. Actors’ behavior can affect the amount, quality and location of a resource or population or the integrity of an ecosystem such as its food-web or habitat quality.

Structural Elements

State The internal state of an individual Attributes of an individual that influence the behavior selection process and possibly the perceived behavioral options. There are four classes of attributes: needs/goals, knowledge, assets, values

State: Needs/Goals

Physiological, psychological or material requirements for the well-being of an individual

Needs are motivational goals/factors for behavior. Theories often include one or several of the following: utility, financial income, safety, reputation. Maslow developed a hierarchy of needs: physiological, safety, social, esteem and self-actualization needs (Maslow, 1943). Max-Neef classified subsistence, protection, affection, understanding, participation, leisure, creation, identity, freedom as basic human needs (Max-Neef, 1991).

State: Knowledge

The information and understanding an individual has about her social-ecological environment and her own behavior within this context

A) Declarative or factual: knowledge about the state and dynamics of the ecological system, the relation between actions and outcomes, memory of the outcomes of past actions or past system states; B) Procedural: knowledge about behaviors and the skills/abilities to perform; C) Relational: knowledge about the behavior and opinions of other relevant actors , e.g. knowledge about other actors the individual knows and what they typically do

State: Assets

Resources and other advantageous characteristics of an individual

A) Personal (e.g., skills), B) Social (e.g., social networks, trust); C) Financial assets. Note that knowledge or value aspects can also be considered assets in some theories.

State: Values

Something (as a principle or quality) intrinsically valuable or desirable, i.e. not directly linked to the well-being of an individual or her motivational goals

Values reflect deep, slowly changing beliefs, e.g. a conservation value reflecting how an agent values the conservation of nature per se without any direct monetary benefits or the value of future benefits (discount rate). Note that depending on the context and on the theory, considering others could be either a need or a value. Similarly, preferences can be related to either values or needs.

Perceived behavioral options

The set of options the individual perceives and thus can choose from

Continuous, e.g. the amount of time an agent allocates between labor and leisure; or discrete, e.g. a set of behaviors the agent can choose from.

Processes

Perception The process by which an individual senses the surrounding social and

Complete: the individual receives all possible information from the environment that is relevant to a decision; or Incomplete: i.e., the individual does not receive all information and as such is bounded in her knowledge

1 in the sense of formal and informal rules/norms

Page 13: A Framework for Mapping and Comparing Behavioral Theories in

10

biophysical environment

Evaluation The process by which an individual determines the significance, worth, or condition of the perceived state of the social and bio-physical environment

For example evaluation of the outcome of a past decision with respect to the returns provided, of fairness or equity of distribution of benefits within a group/society, or of the compliance with a social norm in the population.

Selection The process by which an individual chooses her behavior from the set of perceived behavioral options taking its state into account

Consists of either one or a multiple of different types of selection processes, e.g. ● Random: randomly select one of the possible options ● Optimization: evaluating all options and choosing the one with highest expected outcome ● Satisficing: evaluating options until a behavior is found that is expected to satisfy ● Imitation: selecting the most popular behavior of your friends, or larger community. ● Social Comparison: evaluating options observed among others similar to you and selecting the one with the

highest possible expected outcome. ● Habitual (2 selection processes): 1. Automatic: (If satisfied) Repeating the behavior performed earlier otherwise

switch to 2. Deliberate: (If not satisfied) any other selection process to select, explore and evaluate another behavior.

Behavior the action that an individual executes as a result of the decision process

Behavior impacts the socio-environmental system and, in addition to perception, is the second interface between an individual and its environment. Selected behaviors may fail to be executed if the behavior is physically impossible.

Page 14: A Framework for Mapping and Comparing Behavioral Theories in

11

4. Positioning different behavioral theories in the framework 241

We will now apply the framework to a selection of well-known theories of decision-making from 242

different disciplines. By doing so we demonstrate its potential use and highlight how theories differ 243

from each other, but also indicate challenges of mapping different theories. We selected the 244

example theories with the aim to span a broad range of theories with respect to their application in 245

different fields (economics, psychology) and their comprehensiveness in covering different drivers of 246

human behavior (individual, social, environmental). Rational actor and bounded rationality are 247

theories widely used in natural resource management. Prospect theory is a rather specialized 248

psychological theory about individual perceptions of gains and losses used in economics. 249

Reinforcement learning is a behavioral theory of how very basic processes of reward shape future 250

behavior. The theory of planned behavior is a comprehensive theory widely used in environmental 251

psychology to explain pro-environmental behavior. And, finally, the theory of descriptive norms 252

focusses on the role of the social context. 253

For the mapping we went through the concepts and relationships of each theory and the elements 254

of the framework in an iterative way to relate a concept from the theory with a framework element. 255

We for example identified self-interest as a value of the rational actor (state), utility maximization as 256

its needs (state) and optimization as the selection process (Figure 2). When a theory specifies a 257

certain element the specific details of the theory with respect to this element are included in the 258

figure. Elements that are not mentioned in the theory still remain in the mapping figure; however, 259

they do not include any details (e.g. evaluation in the rational actor model, Figure 2). 260

Page 15: A Framework for Mapping and Comparing Behavioral Theories in

12

4.1. Rational actor 261

262

Figure 2: The rational actor mapped to the framework. 263

The rational actor theory (homo economicus) takes root in neoclassical economics. Scholars cite 264

works of economic philosophers Thomas Hobbes and Adam Smith as the earliest foundations of the 265

rational behavior theory (Monroe, 2001). For the rational actor - who is sometimes also referred to 266

as the “economic man” - rationality first and foremost means maximization of personal utility 267

(Simon, 1978). Selfish maximization implies that a rational actor always chooses the behavioral 268

option that results in highest personal utility gain (Frank, 1987). She is not only self-interested and 269

maximizing, but also goal-oriented; she has agency, stable and organized preferences, advanced and 270

even perfect knowledge of the environment and unlimited cognitive abilities for calculating 271

outcomes of all possible behavioral options (Monroe, 2001). 272

The principle of rationality as self-interested utility maximization and the rational actor model itself 273

have been frequently applied in economics and political science, as well as in psychology, 274

international relations and other social sciences. As stated in the introduction to the paper, the 275

rational actor has been and still is used widely for modelling human decision-making in natural 276

resource use - especially when dealing with the so called “tragedy of the commons” or guiding 277

environmental policy (Jager et al., 2000; van den Bergh et al., 2000). 278

When applying our framework to the rational actor model, the state reflects self-interested needs of 279

the homo economicus, a certain utility function, clear and stable values (or preferences), an 280

individual skillset and a complete knowledge about the social-ecological system. The agent is aware 281

Page 16: A Framework for Mapping and Comparing Behavioral Theories in

13

of all behavioral options available to her and thus the “perceived” behavioral options include all 282

possible options. The options are nevertheless still restricted by the agent’s skillset. We identify 283

optimization as the selection process of the homo economicus model. When optimizing, a selfish 284

rational agent selects the behavioral option that maximizes her own utility, given the possible costs 285

and constraints. Since the rational agent is “all-knowing”, with unrestricted cognitive capacity, she is 286

always able to calculate and select the optimal option. Her actions then affect the social-ecological 287

system. If the rational actor considers a long-term time horizon (and therefore has perfect 288

knowledge about outcomes that occur), the feedback from the system in this time step does not 289

carry any information that is new for this actor. However, in some cases, a rational actor can be 290

modelled with complete information only about outcomes of current actions and therefore would 291

need to perceive additional knowledge from the system in order to decide on behavior during the 292

next time step. The perception of the rational actor is not restricted by cognitive capacity, and she is 293

fully aware of her impacts on the system and payoffs resulting from her actions. 294

4.2. Bounded rationality 295

296

Figure 3: Bounded rationality mapped to the framework. 297

The theory of bounded rationality was proposed by Simon (1957) who argued that the model of 298

economic man does little in terms of describing how actors behave rationally under real-world 299

constraints such as uncertainty and limitations in the capacity of human mind (van den Bergh, 2000; 300

Monroe, 2001). Simon’s model retains some key assumption of rationality (goal-oriented, conscious 301

self-interest), however suggests introducing constraints on information-processing ability of a 302

Page 17: A Framework for Mapping and Comparing Behavioral Theories in

14

rational actor (Simon, 1972; Monroe, 2001). Specifically, the actor is “bounded” by her own 303

cognitive capacity as well as the environment and has incomplete or uncertain information about 304

the world. Finally, the goal of the boundedly rational actor is not limited to utility maximization. 305

According to Simon (1957) the actor may choose a course of action that is “good enough” instead of 306

continuing to search for the best one. In this case the actor is still being rational, but engages in 307

satisficing, rather than maximizing behavior. Apart from maximizing and satisficing, a boundedly 308

rational actor may choose behavior according to heuristics - simple ‘rules of thumb’ that can be 309

adapted to the environment and do not involve calculation of possible outcomes (Gigerenzer and 310

Selten, 2001). 311

Models of boundedly rational behavior have found use in a broad variety of disciplines, starting from 312

economics - to address economic decision-making of individuals and organizational behavior; for 313

studying political behavior, voting decisions and linking individual behavior to macro-politics in 314

political science. The frequent use of boundedly rational actors in agent-based modelling of social-315

ecological systems is not explicitly mentioned since the theory does not specify the many different 316

ways to implement boundedly rational actors. 317

Bounded rationality can be represented within the framework as a modification of the rational actor 318

model. As mentioned above, apart from utility maximization, a boundedly rational actor’s goal may 319

be getting just enough to be satisfied. Most importantly, it has incomplete or uncertain knowledge 320

about possible behavioral options and their outcomes as well as system processes (e.g., rate of 321

resource renewal). When considering possible behavioral options, the boundedly rational actor may 322

look for the optimal one (albeit using imperfect information and considering search costs), select the 323

one that potentially fits a certain satisfaction criteria or apply known heuristics. Information the 324

actor perceives from the system may be incomplete (e.g., due to cognitive, physical or financial 325

constraints). When evaluating new information, a boundedly rational agent may adjust preferences, 326

gain new knowledge or update and learn heuristics. 327

Page 18: A Framework for Mapping and Comparing Behavioral Theories in

15

4.3. Theory of planned behavior 328

329

Figure 4: Theory of planned behavior mapped to the framework. 330

The theory of planned behavior (Ajzen 1991) assumes that behavior is mediated by intentions and 331

perceived behavioral control. Intentions are based on three beliefs: behavioral beliefs (attitudes), 332

normative beliefs (subjective norm), and control beliefs (perceived behavioral control). Attitudes are 333

aggregated beliefs about the strength of the effect of the behavior (e.g., how important resting a 334

pasture is for nature conservation) and their normative value (e.g., whether conserving nature is bad 335

or good). Subjective norms are aggregates of the beliefs of approval/disapproval of the behavior by 336

important individuals or groups and the motivation to comply with important others; perceived 337

behavioral controls are aggregates of the beliefs about a control factor (e.g., money) and the 338

perceived power of the control factor (e.g., is money important). 339

The theory of planned behavior has been used extensively in different contexts, such in 340

environmental psychology, among others, to explain pro-environmental behavior or lack thereof. It 341

is mostly applied in empirical studies to measure the three beliefs and to relate them to intentions 342

as well as to behavior. However, recently there are some modelling studies that use the theory to 343

study the adoption of new practices or technologies (Schwarz & Ernst, 2008; Kiesing et al. 2012). 344

When mapping the theory on our framework, attitudes, subjective norms and perceived behavioral 345

control are placed in the state. Attitudes relate to the knowledge (belief of the effect and its 346

strength) and values or needs (evaluation, e.g., good or bad). The subjective norm relates to the 347

knowledge of the agent (beliefs about the approval or disapproval of the respective behavior by 348

Page 19: A Framework for Mapping and Comparing Behavioral Theories in

16

others and their importance for the agent). The control factors correspond to the assets, while the 349

perceived power of a control factor is part of the knowledge. Attitudes, subjective norms and 350

perceived behavioral control act as a filter that determines the intentions for the different perceived 351

behavioral options. The selection process is a function (which needs to be specified by the modeler) 352

that links behavioral options to performed behavior, mediated by the perceived behavioral control. 353

Options that have a higher intention and that are perceived as being in the control of the actor are 354

more likely to get executed by the agent. 355

4.4. Habitual/reinforcement learning 356

357

Figure 5: Habitual Decision-making/Reinforcement learning (psychology) mapped to the framework. 358

Habit - "is a behavior we do often, almost without thinking" (Graybiel, 2008, p. 359). For example, 359

always eating potatoes, meat and vegetables, not considering a pasta or stir fry. Habits are "learned, 360

repetitive, sequential, context-triggered behaviors" (Graybiel, 2008, p. 363). They perform the best 361

in relatively stable situations, and save on cognitive effort (e.g., Jager, 2003). Reinforcement learning 362

is an approach to describe/represent habitual behavior. It addresses a relevant principle in 363

behavioral learning that originates in the classical (Pavlov, 1927) and operant (Skinner, 1953) 364

conditioning theories. These behaviorist approaches indicate that if an organism receives a reward 365

after performing new behavior, the chances increase that this behavior will be repeated. Theories on 366

habits/reinforcement learning are - in contrast to many other theories - explicitly incorporating 367

feedback, i.e., the positive outcomes of performed behavior result in reinforcement of this behavior 368

in a next time-step. This cyclicity is an essential component of habitual/reinforcement learning. 369

Page 20: A Framework for Mapping and Comparing Behavioral Theories in

17

When mapping the key concepts of reinforcement learning onto the framework the importance of 370

cyclical processes of action and rewards is reflected in the focus on the selection (of action/behavior) 371

and evaluation (reward) processes. The theory includes two selection processes whose choice is 372

influenced by the state of the agent, namely the satisfaction of its needs. If a person's state is 373

satisfactory, the selection of behavior will be automatic, and relies on a script that defines the 374

behavior to perform under this condition (Abelson, 1981). The script is part of the agent’s 375

knowledge. A script can address a single behavior-outcome link (e.g., irrigating when the soil is dry), 376

but also more complicated structures of behavior-outcome relations are possible (e.g., a farmer may 377

have a repertoire of habitual responses to different conditions of weather, season and state of the 378

crop). The performance of a behavior is evaluated concerning the satisfaction of different needs 379

(evaluation). When agents repeatedly go through the cycle from perception and evaluation to 380

behavior, choices that satisfy are reinforced. The more often new behavior is being performed, and 381

the more consistent the person experiences reinforcement, the stronger the script gets, and the 382

more stable/strong the new habitual behavior becomes. 383

When no reinforcement follows after performing the habit, after some time the need satisfaction 384

will drop below a certain critical level (e.g., linked to the person’s ambition level), causing the person 385

to switch towards deliberating about alternative behaviors. For example, one or a few times fishing 386

with a very disappointing catch is not likely to change the behavior of a fisher. However, after a few 387

instances the fisher will start thinking about possible causes and alternative behaviors. This 388

deliberation will also include the longer-term outcomes and goals, which are not being considered 389

while in automatic mode. Note that the habitual/reinforcement learning does not specify the 390

deliberative processes when a habit is being reconsidered. Here different theories can be applied 391

depending on the context of deliberation, such as the other theories addressed in this paper (i.e.,: 392

the rational actor, prospect theory, theory of planned behavior or descriptive norms). 393

394

Page 21: A Framework for Mapping and Comparing Behavioral Theories in

18

4.5. Descriptive norm 395

396

Figure 6: Descriptive norm mapped to the framework. 397

Within different social science disciplines social norms are studied as a key element affecting 398

decision-making (Kallgren et al. 2000; Berkowitz, 1972; Fishbein & Ajzen, 1975; Kerr, 1995; Staub, 399

1972; Triandis, 1977; Bandura 1977; Borsari and Carey, 2003; Cialdini et al. 1990). A common 400

distinction is descriptive versus injunctive norms (Cialdini et al., 1990). Descriptive norms refer to the 401

influence of perceiving what other people actually do, while injunctive norms refer to what one’s 402

perception is about socially acceptable behavior. Observing the behavior of what other people do 403

may, under certain circumstances, have an impact on a person’s behavior. This observation may take 404

place in an almost subconscious manner, where the observed behavior becomes more salient for 405

selection, or this observation may be more deliberately processed, as where other people’s behavior 406

serves as a cue in deciding the proper action to take in a particular situation. 407

Experimental research has demonstrated that descriptive norms influence environmentally related 408

behavior, such as littering (Cialdini, 2003), reuse of towels in hotels (Goldstein et al. 2008), voting 409

behavior (Gerber & Rogers, 2009) and energy use (Schultz et al. 2007). Except for the work of Feola 410

and Binder (2010) the authors do not know of the explicit use of descriptive norms in models of 411

social-ecological systems. 412

When placing the descriptive norm within the framework we can directly relate it to perception and 413

behavior options and observe how it affects behavior through the decision-making process by 414

making the dominant behavior of others more salient. Perception is the process of observing the 415

Page 22: A Framework for Mapping and Comparing Behavioral Theories in

19

actions of others, either by direct information or by receiving information on other people’s 416

behavior. People learn the descriptive norm based on repeated observations (Kashima et al, 2013). 417

During the evaluation, the observations of the behaviors of others are evaluated and the dominant 418

behavior of others is determined. This makes it more likely that this dominant behavior is selected. 419

Values within the state component are important in understanding how a person may react to a 420

descriptive norm. Here a distinction can be made between conformism, non-conformism and anti-421

conformism (see e.g. Levine & Hogg, 2009). A non-conformist is not much affected by the observed 422

behavior of other people in contrast to the conformist and anti-conformist. Here the conformist is 423

likely to comply to the group behavior, and the anti-conformist wants to deviate from the group 424

behavior. The perceived dominant behavior of others influences the saliency (activation) of the 425

perceived behavioral options. Also, following the majority behavior can result in a higher social 426

need satisfaction in the state for conformists, and a lower social need satisfaction for anti-427

conformists. The dominant behavior becomes more salient for those who are more socially 428

susceptible, and is therefore more likely to be selected by conformists, and less likely by anti-429

conformists. 430

431

4.6. Prospect theory 432

433

Figure 7: Prospect theory mapped to the framework 434

Prospect theory introduces important aspects from cognitive psychology to the rational actor model, 435

particularly with respect to how people make decisions between alternative options that involve 436

Page 23: A Framework for Mapping and Comparing Behavioral Theories in

20

probabilistic events. The central assumption in prospect theory is that people bias a rational 437

decision because the context (social or physical setting of a decision situation) shapes their aversion 438

to risk (Kahneman and Tversky, 2000). Prospect theory generally assumes a degree of risk aversion, 439

whereby actors bias decisions toward avoiding loss over chancing a gain (Hastie and Dawes, 2001). 440

When the stakes are small however, actors tend to “gamble” and seek more risk (Lefebvre et al., 441

2010). 442

The theory has been used to understand human decisions in multiple arenas, such as international 443

relations (Goldgeier and Tetlock, 2001; Levy, 1992), financial risk management (Fiegenbaum, 1990), 444

and insurance markets (Sydnor, 2010). Recently the theory has been applied to problems related to 445

NRM in variable environments (Rajagopalan et al., 2009). 446

When mapping Prospect theory onto the framework, much emphasis is put on the evaluation 447

process as this is where the probability of events is evaluated as well as the values of an agent such 448

as its risk attitude. In the context of prospect theory people evaluate possible future outcomes 449

differently based on the probability of the events. Each of these events occurs with a certain 450

probability that may, or may not, be perceived by the decision-maker. Commonly, people 451

underestimate chances of rare events eventuating, for example extreme storms that have a 452

probability of occurring once every 100 years. In contrast, people can overestimate the implication 453

of such rare events. An example is the perceived risks from Ebola virus vs. influenza in the USA. 454

While an Ebola case occurs with much less probability people tend to weigh the risks more heavily 455

and this may influence the expected value of the possible actions. 456

Furthermore people’s values play a major role in defining the perceived behavioral options. Agents’ 457

attitude toward risky behavior will weigh gains and losses differently, but just how will depend both 458

on the person, and how large the potential loses or gains are. What defines a loss vs. a gain is a 459

threshold, or more precisely a reference point that is a reflection of people's expectations or beliefs 460

about past outcomes. It is important to note that the function that defines the risk attitude can 461

represent different types of behavior, such as risk aversion, relentless or indifference to the 462

perceived risk (Wakker, 2010). 463

While a range of factors influence how an individual weighs loses and gains, in a modelling context, 464

once the total value function for each behavioral option can be defined, the selection of behavior is 465

thereafter based on selecting the optimal return, and hence prospect theory can be operationalized 466

as a specialized version of the rational actor model. 467

4.7. Summary of mapping of all theories on framework 468

Table 1 summarizes the main attributes of the different theories as identified from the mapping 469

process. 470

471

472

Page 24: A Framework for Mapping and Comparing Behavioral Theories in

21

Table 1: Summary of the mapping of the theories 473

Theory Perception Evaluation Selection State Perceived behavioral options

Rational actor all information needed for decision available

not specified optimization self-interest/utility/ preferences

all are known

Bounded rationality

constrained by cognitive capability or bio-physical reality

can include learning

optimization satisficing heuristics

preferences limited knowledge about available options

Prospect Theory

probabilities of events

weighting of different possible outcomes

optimization risk attitude reference point

filtered by risk perception and attitude

Theory of Planned Behavior

social network approval/ disapproval of behavior by others

intention with highest value becomes most important

beliefs, strength of beliefs, others’ importance, resources, opportunities

intentions

Descriptive Norm

behavior of others

dominant behavior

dominant behavior becomes more salient

social need social susceptibility

behaviors and dominant behaviors of others

Habitual/ Reinforcement Learning

not specified need satisfaction

automatic or deliberate

needs scripts

scripts

474

475

5. Discussion 476

Managing natural resources is managing people. Despite the widespread recognition of the 477

importance of complex human behavior for sustainable resource management, many formal models 478

are still based on the over-simplifying assumptions of the rational actor. This is particularly critical 479

when models are used for real world policy support where humans may behave very differently than 480

assumed in these models. Empirical and experimental research in psychology, behavioral economics, 481

sociology, or anthropology on the other hand has developed many alternative theories of human 482

behavior. We argue that this gap between our representations of human behavior in formal models 483

and the rich evidence of the nuances of human decision-making in the real world is to some extent 484

due to the plethora of theories developed scattered within and among the different disciplines 485

(some of which are generic while others are very specific), the different terminologies used in 486

different fields, and the lack of understanding of causal mechanisms that explain how factors 487

interact over time in determining decisions and behaviors. When implementing a behavioral theory 488

in a formal model a modeler thus faces the challenge to identify a relevant theory, potentially 489

dealing with incompleteness in the representation of the decision-making process and the lack of 490

specification of causal relationships. 491

In this paper, we proposed a framework for operationalizing theories of human decision-making in 492

natural resource management contexts to tackle some of these challenges. The framework supports 493

Page 25: A Framework for Mapping and Comparing Behavioral Theories in

22

mapping, describing, organizing and comparing different behavioral theories as a first step towards 494

choosing and implementing them in formal models of social-ecological systems. Each theory uses a 495

vocabulary that is specific to the discipline it belongs to. Our framework provides a generic language 496

that can be used to describe multiple theories using the seven elements of the framework – social 497

and biophysical context, perception, evaluation, state, perceived behavioral options, selection 498

process, and behavior. This facilitates mapping and comparison of different theories with respect to 499

their structure and dynamics and their implications for understanding natural resource 500

management. Furthermore it can be used to communicate how a theory was formalized to 501

implement it into an agent-based model. We do not claim that the framework can capture all 502

theories of human decision-making in a natural resource use context, but we hope that, as a first 503

step, it will be useful to capture many relevant theories and in the long run supports a broader 504

inclusion of these theories in social-ecological models. 505

5.1. Mapping theories to clarify their focus and underlying assumptions 506

Our experience with the mapping of the six selected theories showed that it was possible - with a bit 507

of flexibility in the interpretation of the elements - to map each theory onto the elements. The 508

comprehensive process of specifying the elements of a behavioral theory facilitates communication 509

about the assumptions of the theory and can help clarify the meaning of the diversity of concepts 510

used in different theories. It also makes explicit the focus of a theory, e.g. which of the elements are 511

considered important determinants of behavior (Table 2 – “Focus”). The mapping highlights which 512

ones are represented and which ones not, how they are represented and how they may interact 513

over time to determine the behavior of the actor. As such it can facilitate the identification of 514

commonalities and differences between theories. For instance, a theory may focus on the role of 515

actor characteristics (state), the options an actor can choose from (perceived behavioral options) or 516

the way she makes her choices (selection process). For instance, our mapping of the rational actor 517

clearly shows that, in this theory, actors maximize their needs (e.g. expected utility) by exploring all 518

available options. In contrast, in the descriptive norm theory, decisions are almost exclusively 519

influenced by the perception of the behavior of others in the social environment. In some theories 520

the needs and goals of the actor are driving a decision (e.g., bounded rationality, prospect theory) 521

while others don’t specify any needs and goals (e.g. theory of planned behavior, descriptive norm). 522

The theory of planned behavior is very specific on elements of the state of an agent such as its 523

attitudes, subjective norm and perceived behavioral control, even specifying the components that 524

determine its value. Yet it remains very unspecific on the actual selection process that selects among 525

different intentions. 526

The mapping also reveals where a theory lacks detail or relevant information on particular aspects of 527

the decision -making processes needed to implement it in a formal model (Table 2 – “degree of 528

completeness”). In the rational actor model, for instance, changes of behavior over time are not 529

made explicit, i.e., the informational feedback from the social and biophysical environment is not 530

specified. In the theory of planned behavior all components of attitudes, subjective norms and 531

perceived behavioral control could possibly change over time if aspects of that are perceived and 532

evaluated dynamically. However, the theory itself does not state so. In the boundedly rational actor 533

the selection process is not specified, rather several processes may be used. The 534

habitual/reinforcement learning theory does not describe how an agent decides deliberately when it 535

explores a new behavior. Gaps in a theory may however open up opportunities to link it with 536

Page 26: A Framework for Mapping and Comparing Behavioral Theories in

23

another theory that specifies the missing process. For instance one could combine the habitual 537

model with the descriptive norms model to represent deliberate decision-making such that an agent 538

follows the norm when it explores and carries out its habitual behavior when it is in an automated 539

mode. The framework can thus facilitate a process of integrating different theoretical perspectives. 540

5.2. Limitations of the framework 541

The mapping of the theories, however, also revealed limitations of the framework or difficulties in its 542

application. It does not capture well the processes that go beyond a single time step such as 543

learning. This becomes particularly problematic when the decision of an agent depends on the 544

decision- making process in the previous time step as is the case in the habitual model. Here the 545

decision of an agent to explore new behavior can only happen when it did not receive positive 546

reinforcement after repeatedly performing the habit. Hence processes related to learning and 547

habitual behavior can only be understood in terms of repeatedly running through the framework 548

cycle. The dynamics of behavior and behavioral change are a result of iterations of the decision- 549

making processes over time (i.e., running the model). For example, learning emerges as a change in 550

selected variables of the state such as knowledge or values or as a change in the behavioral options 551

resulting from new information or the observation of the behaviors of others (social learning). 552

For some theories it was difficult to map specific terms of a theory onto the framework vocabulary. 553

In general, flexibility is required to relate a theory- specific concept to the concepts of the 554

framework. The term “preferences” for instance could be mapped as needs and goals or values 555

depending on the theory or application context. The concept “intentions” from the theory of 556

planned behavior does not have a direct equivalent in the framework but can be mapped onto the 557

behavioral options. It also does not specify whether the intention with the highest values is always 558

executed. When mapping and later implementing a theory in a formal model the modeler has to 559

make many assumptions on causal relationships, particularly when the theory is based on 560

correlations as in the case of the theory of planned behavior. Finally, as the framework focusses on 561

individual decision-making it cannot deal with processes or theories that include group or collective 562

decision-making. 563

564

Page 27: A Framework for Mapping and Comparing Behavioral Theories in

24

5.3. Operationalizing behavioral theories in SES models 565

A comparison of the six theories analyzed here revealed their strengths and weaknesses with 566

respect to the elements of decision-making that are well represented and those that are missing. 567

Table 2 summarizes an assessment of the different theories with respect to additional criteria that 568

may be relevant for the choice of one or several theories to be implemented in a social-ecological 569

model such as the degree of formalization, degree of completeness, the representation of dynamics. 570

One can see, for instance, that only one theory explicitly includes details on the change of decision-571

making over time (dynamics) and that most theories except for the rational and the boundedly 572

rational actor have so far not been used much in formal models. 573

When choosing a theory for implementation in a formal model it is important that the selected 574

theory represents those aspects of human decision-making in detail that are considered crucial for 575

the particular context or research focus of the model. If for instance for a given context cooperation 576

between users of a natural resource is critical, then theories focusing on interactions with others will 577

automatically be relevant for the modeler. A choice may also be influenced by the degree of 578

formalization of a theory since as a theory that is already highly formalized will be easier to 579

implement into a model and less assumptions on missing elements will have to be made. Finally the 580

degree of completeness of a theory can also be important since as a theory that already covers many 581

aspects means that modelers do have to make less assumptions than for theories that focus on 582

single elements and leave out others. The framework can help identify which aspects a theory 583

focusses on (Table 2) and which details it includes. 584

When operationalizing a theory for use in a social-ecological model, one has to make choices on 585

causal mechanisms. In the case of the theory of planned behavior, for instance, one has to decide 586

how the behavioral, normative and control beliefs are aggregated to determine intentions and how 587

an intention leads to behavior. These choices are necessarily more or less well-founded assumptions 588

that will vary between different model implementations. The framework can thus be very valuable in 589

encouraging modelers to make these assumptions explicit and their effects comparable between 590

different models. It also stimulates a critical reflection on whether the degree to which one has to 591

make assumptions on causality limits the usefulness of a particular theory for SES modelling. Such a 592

process can thus help identify theories that are most relevant. 593

Furthermore the structure of the framework makes modelers aware of the different elements of 594

decision-making that need to be tackled in any kind of implementation in a formal model. By going 595

through the framework in a systematic manner a modeler will have to think about the relevance of 596

each element, even if a theory does not specify it. For instance, a theory may not be explicit about 597

what information an agent can perceive from the biophysical and social environment. For example, 598

the implementation of the rational actor model shows that one needs to specify a feedback from the 599

biophysical environment if the agent makes decisions over time. The ideal model of the theory 600

cannot be implemented (next to that the agent will always be a boundedly rational actor). The 601

mapping will alert the modeler to the fact that she needs to investigate whether this is an important 602

aspect for the particular decision and decision context to be modelled. This process can be 603

complementary to the use of the ODD+D protocol (Müller et al. 2013) in guiding the development of 604

the decision model. The framework however goes beyond ODD+D in that it structures the decision- 605

making process in more detail into specific elements and specifies how they interact. This enables a 606

more systematic and comparable development of a decision- making model. 607

Page 28: A Framework for Mapping and Comparing Behavioral Theories in

25

Table 2: Assessment of the different theories with respect to their use in formal modelling of SES. 608

Theory Focus (element(s) of the framework that is/are most important)

Degree of formalization

Degree of completeness (are all elements described)

Representation of dynamics

Frequency of use in models of natural resource management

Rational actor Goal-oriented needs

optimization (selection)

High (equations) Medium No High

Bounded rationality

Imperfect perception and selection

Medium (no equations given, but clearly described)

High No High

Prospect Theory (E)valuation of

the probability of different events

High (equations) Medium No Medium

Theory of Planned Behavior

Elements of the state that

determine intentions

Medium High No Low

Descriptive Norms

Perception of

the behavior of others and evaluation of

dominant one

Low High No Low

Habitual/Reinforcement Learning

Two different types of selection processes

(automatic versus deliberative)

Low Medium Yes Low

609

5.4. Final remarks 610

There is an increasing recognition of the importance of including a broader knowledge base of our 611

understanding of human behavior in the study of social-ecological systems. The inclusion of this 612

knowledge in formal models faces major challenges due to the required specifications of 613

assumptions that are not addressed in the original theories. Our proposed framework is a modest 614

step to facilitate this translation process. The next step for this research endeavor will be the 615

systematic implementation of a set of behavioral theories in models of social-ecological systems. 616

Implementing different behavioral theories into a formal model allows for a sensitivity analysis of 617

human behavior within a natural resource management context. We see the value of this sensitivity 618

analysis initially as a conceptual understanding of how different behavioral theories affect the 619

dynamics of social-ecological systems. Moreover, including different behavioral theories on decision-620

making in formal models of social-ecological systems enables the ability to assess the consequences 621

of a mismatch in behavioral theories for designing policies. For example, one may optimize a tax 622

policy to meet some environmental management goals assuming rational choice of selfish actors. 623

Implementing alternative behavioral theories, we can test the consequences of this policy if actors 624

Page 29: A Framework for Mapping and Comparing Behavioral Theories in

26

are not rational and selfish, but make decisions according to other behavioral theories. Such an 625

analysis enables assessing the robustness of the performance of policy options to different 626

assumptions of human behavior. 627

628

6. Acknowledgements 629

We acknowledge the financial support from the National Socio-Environmental Synthesis Center in 630

Annapolis, US (SESYNC), the Helmholtz Centre for Environmental Research (UFZ) in Leipzig, 631

Germany, and German Centre for Integrative Biodiversity Research (iDiv), Leipzig for meetings of 632

our working group. MS acknowledges funding by the European Research Council under the 633

European Union’s Seventh Framework Programme (FP/2007-2013)/ERC grant agreement no. 283950 634

SES-LINK and a core grant to the Stockholm Resilience Centre by Mistra. BM and GD were supported 635

by the German Federal Ministry of Education and Research (BMBF—01LN1315A) within the Junior 636

Research Group POLISES. We also acknowledge the valuable feedback of the audience on 637

presentations on this paper at UFZ and iDiv, and the students from the summer school class July 638

2015 on “How to model human decision-making in social-ecological agent-based models” in Kohren-639

Sahlis, Germany. 640

641

7. References 642

Abelson, R.P. (1981). Psychological status of the script concept. American Psychologist, 36, 715-729. 643

Ajzen, I. (1991). The theory of planned behavior. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision 644

Processes, 50, 179–211. 645

An, L. (2012). Modelling human decisions in coupled human and natural systems: Review of agent-646

based models., Ecological Modelling, 229, 25-36. 647

Anderson, J.R. (1990). Cognitive psychology and its implications (3rd ed.). A series of books in 648

psychology. New York, NY, US: W H Freeman/Times Books/ Henry Holt & Co.. xvi 519 pp. 649

Balke, T. & Gilbert , N. (2014). How do agents make decisions? A Survey. Journal of Artificial Societies 650

and Social Simulation, 17 (4), 13. 651

Bandura, A. (1977). Social learning theory. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall. 652

Berkes, F., Folke, C. (Eds.) (1998). Linking Social and Ecological Systems: Management Practices and 653

Social Mechanisms for Building Resilience. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 654

Berkowitz, L. (1972). Social norms, feelings, and other factors affecting helping and altruism. In L. 655

Berkowitz (Ed.), Advances in experimental social psychology (Vol. 6, 63-108). San Diego, 656

CA: Academic Press. 657

Borsari, B., Carey, K.B. (2003). Descriptive and injunctive norms in college drinking: A meta-analytic 658

integration. Journal of Studies on Alcohol, 64(3), 331-341. 659

Bousquet, F., Le Page C. (2004). Multi-agent simulations and ecosystems management: a review. 660

Ecological Modelling, 176, 313-332. 661

Page 30: A Framework for Mapping and Comparing Behavioral Theories in

27

Carley, K., Newell, A. (1994). The Nature of the social agent. Journal of Mathematical Sociology, 662

19(4), 221-262. 663

Cialdini, R.B., Kallgren, C.A. & Reno, R.R. (1990). A focus theory of normative conduct: A theoretical 664

refinement and re-evaluation of the role of norms in human behaviors. Journal of Personality and 665

Social Psychology, 58, 1015–1026. 666

Cialdini, R. B., Goldstein, N. J. (2004). Social influence: Compliance and conformity. Annual Review of 667

Psychology, 55 (1), 591–621. 668

Cialdini, R.B. (2003). Crafting normative messages to protect the environment. Current Directions in 669

Psychological Science, 12(4), 105-109. 670

Clark, C.W. (1976) Mathematical Bioeconomics: The optimal management of renewable resources. 671

New York, NY: John Wiley & Sons. 672

Cooke, I.R., Queenborough, S.A., Mattison, E.H.A., Bailey, A.P., Sandars, D.L., Graves, A.R., Morris, J., 673

Atkinson, P.W., Trawick, P., Freckleton, R.P., Watkinson, A.R. & Sutherland, W.J. (2009). 674

Integrating socio-economics and ecology: A taxonomy of quantitative methods and a review of 675

their use in agro-ecology., Journal of Applied Ecology, 46, 269-277. 676

Eisenegger, C., Haushofer, J. & Fehr, E. (2011). The role of testosterone in social interaction. Trends 677

in Cognitive Science, 15, 263–271 678

Fehr, E. & Gintis, H. (2007). Human motivation and social cooperation: Experimental and analytical 679

foundations. Annual Review of Sociology, 33, 43-64. 680

Fehr, E. & Schmidt, K.M. (1999) A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation. Quarterly Journal 681

of Economics, 114, 817-868. 682

Feola, G. & Binder, C. R. (2010). Towards an improved understanding of farmers' behavior: The 683

integrative agent-centered (IAC) framework. Ecological Economics, 69(12), 2323-2333. 684

Fiegenbaum, A. (1990). Prospect theory and the risk-return association: An empirical examination in 685

85 industries. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 14(2), 187-203. 686

Fishbein, M. & Ajzen, I. (1975). Belief, Attitude, Intention, and Behavior: An Introduction to Theory 687

and Research. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley. 688

Frank, R.H. (1987). If Homo-Economicus could choose his own utility function, would he want one 689

with a conscience. American Economic Review, 77, 593-604. 690

Fulton, E.A., Smith, A. D. M., Smith, D. C., & van Putten, I.E. (2011). Human Behavior: The Key Source 691

of Uncertainty in Fisheries Management. Fish and Fisheries, 12, 2–17. 692

Gerber, A.S., Rogers, T. (2009). Descriptive Social Norms and Motivation to Vote: Everybody’s Voting 693

and so Should You. The Journal of Politics, 71(1), 178–191. 694

Gigerenzer G. & Selten R. (Eds.) (2001) Bounded Rationality: The Adaptive Toolbox. Cambridge, 695

Massachusetts, USA: MIT Press. 696

Gintis, H. (2000). Strong reciprocity and human sociality. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 206(2), 169-697

179. 698

Page 31: A Framework for Mapping and Comparing Behavioral Theories in

28

Goldgeier, J. M., & Tetlock, P. E. (2001). Psychology and international relations theory. Annual 699

Review of Political Science, 4(1), 67-92. 700

Goldstein, N.J., R.B. Cialdini, V. Griskevicius. (2008). A room with a viewpoint: Using social norms to 701

motivate environmental conservation in hotels. Journal of Consumer Research, 35(3), 472-482. 702

Graybiel, A.M. (2008). Habits, rituals, and the evaluative brain. Annual Review of Neuroscience, 31, 703

359–387. 704

Hardisty, D., Orlove,B., Krantz, D.H., Small, A.A., Milch, K.F., & Osgood, D.E. (2012). About time: An 705

integrative approach to effective environmental policy. Global Environmental Change, 22 (2012) 706

684–694. 707

Hare, M. & Deadman, P., (2004). Further towards a taxonomy of agent-based simulation models in 708

environmental management. Mathematics and Computers in Simulation, 64, 25–40. 709

Hastie, R. & Dawes, R. M. (2001). Rational choice in an uncertain world : The psychology of judgment 710

and decision making. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. 711

Heckbert, S., Baynes, T. & Reeson, A. (2010). Agent-based modelling in ecological economics. Annals 712

of the New York Academy of Sciences, 1185, 39-63. 713

Henrich, J., Boyd, R., Bowles, S., Camerer, C., Fehr, E., Gintis, H., & McElrath, R. (2001). Cooperation, 714

reciprocity and punishment in fifteen small-scale societies. American Economic Review, 91, 73- – 715

78. 716

Hopfensitz, A. & Reuben, E. (2009). The importance of emotions for the effectiveness of social 717

punishment. Economic Journal, 119, 1534-1559. 718

Jager, W. (2003). Breaking “’bad habits”: A dynamical perspective on habit formation and change. in: 719

Hendrick, L., Jager, W. & Steg, L. (Eds.) Human decision making and environmental perception: 720

Understanding and assisting human decision making in real-life settings. Liber Amicorum for 721

Charles Vlek. Groningen: University of Groningen. 722

Jager, W., Janssen, M.A., De Vries, H.J.M., De Greef, J., Vlek, C.A.J., (2000). Behavior in commons 723

dilemmas: homo economicus and homo psychologicus in an ecological–economic model. 724

Ecological Economics, 35 (3), 357–379. 725

Janssen, M.A. & Jager, W. (2000). The human actor in ecological-economic models. Ecological 726

Economics, 35(3), 307-310. 727

Kahneman, D. (2003). Maps of bounded rationality: Psychology for behavioral economics. The 728

American Economic Review, 93 (5), 1449-1475. 729

Kahneman, D. & Tversky, A. (Eds.) (2000). Choices, values, and frames. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge 730

University Press. 731

Kallgren, C.A., Reno, R.R., Cialdini, R.B. (2000). A Focus Theory of Normative Conduct: When Norms 732

Do and Do not Affect Behavior. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 26(8), 1002–1012. 733

Karagiannakos, A. (1996). Total allowable Catch (TAC) and quota management system in the 734

European Union. Marine Policy, 20(3), 235-248. 735

Page 32: A Framework for Mapping and Comparing Behavioral Theories in

29

Kashima, Y., Wilson, S., Lusher, D., Pearson, L. J. & Pearson, C. (2013). The acquisition of perceived 736

descriptive norms as social category learning in social networks. Social Networks, 35(4), 711–719. 737

Kerr, N.L. (1995). Norms in social dilemmas. In Schroeder, D. A. (Ed.) Social dilemmas: Perspectives 738

on individuals and groups. Westport, CT: Praeger. 739

Kerr, N.L. & Tindale, N.L. (2004). Group performance and decision making. Annual Review of 740

Psychology, 55, 623-655. 741

Kiesling, E., M. Günther, M., Stummer, C. & Wakolbinger, L.M. (2012). Agent-based simulation of 742

innovation diffusion: a review. Central European Journal of Operations Research, 20(2), 183-230. 743

Lefebvre, M., Vieider, F. M. & Villeval, M. C. (2010). Incentive effects on risk attitude in small 744

probability prospects. Economics Letters, 109(2), 115-120. 745

Levy, J. S. (1992). Prospect theory and international relations: Theoretical applications and analytical 746

problems. Political Psychology, 283-310. 747

Levine, J. M., & Hogg, M. A. (2009). Encyclopedia of groups processes and intergroup relations: 748

“Anticonformity” (19-20). Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. 749

Maslow, A. H. (1943). A theory of human motivation. Psychological Review, 50, 370–396. 750

Matthews, R., Gilbert, N., Roach, A., Polhill, J., Gotts, N., (2007). Agent-based land-use models: a 751

review of applications. Landscape Ecology, 22, 1447–1459. 752

Max-Neef, M. ( 1991). Human scale development: conception, application and further reflections. 753

New York, NY: The Apex Press. 754

Meadows, D.H., Meadows, G., Randers, J., and Behrens III, W.B., (1972). The limits to growth. New 755

York: Universe Books. 756

Meinshausen, M., Meinshausen, N., Hare, W., Raper, S.C.B., Frieler, R., Knutti, R., Frame, D.J. & Allen, 757

M.R.(2009). Greenhouse-gas emission targets for limiting global warming to 2 oC., Nature, 458, 758

1158-1162. 759

Meyfroidt, P. (2013). Environmental cognitions, land change, and social-ecological feedbacks: an 760

overview. Journal of Land Use Science, 8(3), 341-367. 761

Milner-Gulland, E.J. (2012). Interactions between human behaviour and ecological systems. 762

Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society of London, Series B, 367, 270–278. 763

Moll, H., & Tomasello, M. (2007). Cooperation and human cognition: The Vygotskian intelligence 764

hypothesis. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society of London, Series B, Biological 765

Sciences, 362, 639–648. 766

Monroe, K.R. (2001). Paradigm Shift: From Rational Choice to Perspective. International Political 767

Science Review, 22(2), 151–172. 768

Müller, B., Bohn, F., Dreßler, G., Groeneveld, J., Klassert, C., Martin, R., et al. (2013). Describing 769

Human Decisions in Agent-Based Models - ODD + D, an Extension of the ODD Protocol. 770

Environmental Modelling & Software, 48, 37–48. 771

Myers, N., Mittermeier, R.A., Mittermeier, C.G., da Fonseca, G.A.B. & Kent, J. (2000). Biodiversity 772

hotspots for conservation priorities. Nature, 403, 853-858. 773

Page 33: A Framework for Mapping and Comparing Behavioral Theories in

30

Nordhaus, W.D. (1994). Managing the global commons: The economics of climate change. 774

Cambridge, MA. and London: MIT Press. 775

Palmer, P.I., Smith, M.J., (2014). Earth systems: Model human adaptation to climate change. Nature, 776

512, 365–366. 777

Pavlov, I.P. (1927). Conditioned reflexes. New York: Oxford University Press. 778

Petty, R. E., & Cacioppo, J. T. (1984). The effects of involvement on responses to argument quantity 779

and quality: Central and peripheral routes to persuasion. Journal of Personality and Social 780

Psychology, 46, 69-81. 781

Rajagopalan, B., Laciana, C. E., Weber, E. U., Katz, R. M., & Letson, D. (2009). Decadal climate 782

variability in the Argentine Pampas: regional impacts of plausible climate scenarios on agricultural 783

systems. Climate Research, 40, 199-210. 784

Rilling, J.K., Gutman, D.A., Zeh, T.R., Pagnoni, G., Berns, G.S. & Kilts, C.D. (2002). A neural basis for 785

social cooperation. Neuron, 35(2), 395-405. 786

Rodhe, H., Sörlin, S., Snyder, P.K., Costanza, R., Svedin, U., Falkenmark, M., Karlberg, L., Corell, R.W., 787

Fabry, V.J., Hansen, J., Walker, B. D., Liverman, D., Richardson, K., Crutzen, P. & Foley, J.A. (2009). 788

A safe operating space for humanity. Nature, 461, 472-475. 789

Sawyer, R. K. (2004). Social explanation and computational simulation. Philosophical Explorations, 790

7(3), 219–231. 791

Scarlett, L., Boyd, J. & Brittain, A. (2013). Catalysts for conservation: Exploring behavioral science 792

insights for natural resource investments., Resources for the Future Report. Washington DC: 793

Resources for the Future Press. 794

Schlüter, M., Mcallister, R.R.J., Arlinghaus, R., Bunnefeld, N., Eisenack, K., Hoelker, F., Milner-795

Gulland, E.J., Mueller, B. (2012). New horizons for managing the environment: a review of 796

coupled social-ecological systems modeling. Natural resource modeling, 25, 219–272. 797

Schultz, P.W., Nolan, J.M., Cialdini, R.B., Goldstein, N.J. & Griskevicius, V. (2007). The constructive, 798

destructive and reconstructive power of social norms. Psychological Science, 18(5), 439-434. 799

Siebenhuner, B. (2000). Homo sustinens: towards a new conception of humans for the science of 800

sustainability. Ecological Economics, 32 (1), 15–25. 801

Simberloff, D. & Cox, J. (1987). Consequences and Costs of conservation corridors. Conservation 802

Biology, 1(1), 63-71. 803

Simon, H. A. (1957). Models of Man, Social and Rational: Mathematical Essays on Rational 804

Human Behavior in a Social Setting. New York: John Wiley and Sons. 805

Simon, H. A. (1972). Theories of bounded rationality. In: McGuire, C.B., Radner, R. & Arrow, K.J., 806

(Eds.) Decision and organization: A volume in honor of Jacob Marschak. North-Holland Pub. Co. 807

Simon, H.A. (1978). Rationality as Process and as Product of Thought. American Economic 808

Review, 68(2), 1–16. 809

Skinner, B.F. (1953). The behavior of organisms. New York: Appleton-Century-Crofts. 810

Page 34: A Framework for Mapping and Comparing Behavioral Theories in

31

Smajgl, A., Barreteau, O. (Eds.), 2014. Empirical Agent-Based Modelling - Challenges and 811

Solutions. New York, NY: Springer. 812

Staub, E. (1972). Instigation to Goodness: The Role of Social Norms and Interpersonal Influence. 813

Journal of Social Issues, 28(3), 131–150. 814

Todd, P. M., Gigerenzer, G. & the ABC Research Group. (2012). Ecological Rationality: Intelligence in 815

the world. New York: Oxford University Press. 816

Sydnor, J. (2010). (Over) insuring modest risks. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 2(4), 817

177-199. 818

Triandis, H.C. (1977). Interpersonal behavior. Belmont, CA: Brooks/Cole Pub. Co. 819

Van den Bergh, J., Ferrer-i-Carbonell, A.,Munda, G., (2000). Alternative models of individual behavior 820

and implications for environmental policy. Ecological Economics 32 (1), 43–61. 821

Van Vugt, M. and Griskevicius, V. (2014). Naturally green: Harnessing Stone Age psychological biases 822

to foster environmental behavior. Social Issues and Policy Review, 8(1), 1-32. 823

Victor, D. (2015). Embed the social sciences in climate policy. Nature, 520, 27-29. 824

Wakker, P.P., (2010). Prospect theory: For risk and ambiguity. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University 825

Press. 826

World Bank (2015). World Development Report 2015: Mind, Society and behavior. Washington, DC: 827

World Bank. 828

Page 35: A Framework for Mapping and Comparing Behavioral Theories in

A framework for mapping and comparing behavioral theories

in models of social-ecological systems Maja Schlütera, Andres Baezab, Gunnar Dresslerc, Karin Frankc, Jürgen Groeneveldc, Wander Jagerd,

Marco A. Janssene, Ryan R.J. McAllisterf, Birgit Müllerc, Kirill Oracha, Nina Schwarzc, Nanda Wijermansa

a Stockholm Resilience Centre, Stockholm University, Kräftriket 2b, 10691 Stockholm, Sweden,

[email protected], [email protected], [email protected]

b National Socio-Environmental Synthesis Center (SESYNC), 1 Park Place, Suite 300, Annapolis, MD

21401, USA, [email protected]

c UFZ, Helmholtz Centre for Environmental Research e UFZ, Department of Ecological Modelling,

Permoser Str. 15, 04138 Leipzig, Germany, [email protected], [email protected],

[email protected], [email protected], [email protected]

d University College Groningen, Hoendiepskade 23-24, 9718 BG Groningen, The

Netherlands,[email protected]

e School of Sustainability, Arizona State University, PO Box 875502, AZ 85287-5502Tempe, USA,

[email protected]

f CSIRO PO Box 2583 Brisbane Q 4001 Australia, [email protected]

Corresponding author

Maja Schlüter

Stockholm Resilience Centre

Stockholm University

Kräftriket 2b

10691 Stockholm, Sweden

[email protected]