43
A Competitive Model of Superstars Timothy Perri Department of Economics Appalachian State University Presented at Virginia Tech January 21, 2006

A Competitive Model of Superstars

Embed Size (px)

DESCRIPTION

A Competitive Model of Superstars. Timothy Perri Department of Economics Appalachian State University Presented at Virginia Tech January 21, 2006.  Sherwin Rosen ( AER , 1981) developed the notion of superstars.  Rosen assumed more talented individuals produce - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Citation preview

Page 1: A Competitive Model of Superstars

A Competitive Model of Superstars

Timothy Perri

Department of Economics

Appalachian State University

Presented at Virginia Tech

January 21, 2006

Page 2: A Competitive Model of Superstars

2

Sherwin Rosen (AER, 1981) developed the notion of superstars.

Rosen assumed more talented individuals produce

higher quality products.

Superstar effects imply earnings are

convex in quality, the highest quality producers earn a

disproportionately large share of market earnings, & the

possibility of only a few sellers in the market.

Page 3: A Competitive Model of Superstars

3

R* = revenue given the profit-maximizing quantity

z = product quality

R*

Page 4: A Competitive Model of Superstars

4

Rosen argued superstar effects are the result of two

phenomena: imperfect substitution among products,

with demand for higher quality increasing more than

proportionally, and technology such that one or a few

sellers could profitably satisfy market demand.

Page 5: A Competitive Model of Superstars

5

Herein, a competitive model is developed in which:

1) there are many potential and active firms;

2) some fraction of the potential producers with the lowest quality level could satisfy market demand;

3) complete arbitrage occurs between prices of goods with different quality; and

4) a few firms with higher quality earn a disproportionately large share of market revenue because their revenue increases with quality at an increasing rate.

Page 6: A Competitive Model of Superstars

6

The usual explanations for superstar

effects---imperfect substitution between

sellers, and some form of joint

consumption, with marginal cost

declining as quality increases---are not

necessary.

Page 7: A Competitive Model of Superstars

7

A firm’s revenue can be positive and

convex in quality when cost increases

in quality at a decreasing rate.

Without the requirements of imperfect

substitution and joint consumption,

there may be many markets that could

contain superstar effects.

Page 8: A Competitive Model of Superstars

8

Evidence

Krueger (JOLE, 2005) identifies significant

superstar effects for music concerts that have

become even larger in recent years. He argues

the time and effort to perform a song should

not have changed much in over time.

Page 9: A Competitive Model of Superstars

9

It is also unlikely the cost of performing a

song depends significantly on the quality

of the musicians. Further, the technology

of reaching more buyers for a live performance

is much different than it is for selling additional CDs .

Page 10: A Competitive Model of Superstars

10

“Pavarotti can, with the same effort, produce

one CD of Tosca or 100 million CDs of Tosca.

...if most view Pavarotti as {even slightly}

better {than Domingo}, he will sell many more

CDs than Domingo and his earnings will be

many times higher...”

(Lazear, p. 188, 2003)

Page 11: A Competitive Model of Superstars

11

Krueger (2005) reports revenue for music concerts from 1982 to 2003. In 1982, the top 5% (in terms of revenue) of artists

earned 62% of concert revenue. For 2003,

the corresponding figure was 84%.

Page 12: A Competitive Model of Superstars

12

An example

In Rosen (1981), imperfect substitution

between quality levels would produce star

surgeons. However, if star surgeons have quality

levels significantly higher than non-star surgeons,

then imperfect substitution is not necessary for stars

to have significantly higher revenue than non-stars.

Page 13: A Competitive Model of Superstars

13

The term “superstar” will be used when

revenue increases & is convex in quality, &

a few sellers earning a large % of market revenue.

Rosen used profit (), but revenue (R) is used herein.

WHY?

Page 14: A Competitive Model of Superstars

14

1st, in my competitive model, low quality

producers earn zero profit stars earn all profit.

2nd, in the special case in Rosen closest to the

model herein, revenue and profit are identically

affected by quality, as is true in my competitive model.

3rd, earnings reported for top performers in entertainment

and sports are not net of cost. The data on concert

earnings from Krueger (2005) involve revenue.

Page 15: A Competitive Model of Superstars

15

Rosen (1981) argued his model involved competition.

However, different quality levels were imperfect

substitutes (with the larger the difference in quality the

worse subs. goods were), & the threat of POTENTIAL

ENTRY disciplined existing producers.

Page 16: A Competitive Model of Superstars

16

Adler (2005) argued there

would not be relatively high earnings

for superstars unless there are

significant quality differences

between sellers.

Page 17: A Competitive Model of Superstars

17

With several sellers of similar quality,

if MC declines with firm output,

competition PAC. One “superstar”

may survive and sell most of market Q,

but it will not have > 0.

Page 18: A Competitive Model of Superstars

18

However, if quality levels are

not similar between firms,

there is no competition in

Rosen’s model.

Page 19: A Competitive Model of Superstars

19

Cost and superstar effects

Let C = a firm’s total cost, q = output, z = quality, & F = fixed cost:

C = zq + F,

where > 1 & could be positive, negative, or 0.

Page 20: A Competitive Model of Superstars

20

A firm’s price is P(z) = kz, with k (> 0)

a positive constant to be determined later.

Rosen (1981) argued superstar effects

occur in a market when “...fewer are

needed to serve it the more capable

they are.” This means marginal cost is

inversely related to quality, or < 0.

Page 21: A Competitive Model of Superstars

21

= kzq - zq - F

Find -max. q & substitute into R to get R*, which yields:

1

1

11

1

zk1

1

z

*R

1

2

12

1

1

2

2

zk1

11

z

*R

Page 22: A Competitive Model of Superstars

22

Since > 1, if > ,

z

*R

> 0.

If < 1:

2

2

z

*R

> 0.

Thus, cost could increase in Z (at a

decreasing rate) & still have R* positively

& convexly related to Z.

Page 23: A Competitive Model of Superstars

23

Market equilibrium

Suppose most sellers (non-stars)

have the minimum quality level, z0, and a

few sellers (stars) have higher quality.

Free entry and exit of non-stars occurs.

Assume cost is independent of quality,

which is not necessary for the existence

of superstar effects.

Page 24: A Competitive Model of Superstars

24

Each firm has a U-shaped AC

curve. Entry or exit of non-stars will

force the long-run price of the lowest

quality level, z0, to equal the height of

the minimum point of average cost, P0.

Page 25: A Competitive Model of Superstars

25

Arbitrage :

P(z) = 0

0

Pz

z

where k (introduced earlier) P0/z0.

Arbitrage determines relative Ps, &

free entry/exit of non-stars determines

absolute Ps.

Page 26: A Competitive Model of Superstars

26

Market demand depends on the average quality sold, with inverse market demand:

PD = f(Q, ),

with PD = the demand price for the

average quality in the market ( )

& Q = market output.

z

z

Page 27: A Competitive Model of Superstars

27

Adjustment to market equilibrium

Suppose z0 = 1 & P0 = $10. Minimum

quality sells for $10, & higher quality

(z) sells for P(z) = $10z. Suppose

is initially = 2 & P( ) = $20.

z

z

Page 28: A Competitive Model of Superstars

28

q

$AC

P0 = $10

firm

Page 29: A Competitive Model of Superstars

29

If entry raises to 3,

even if the elasticity of

demand with respect to = 1

(a to b in Figure 1), P( ) will

rise to < $30 because:

1) supply is not vertical, &

2) supply increased to S’.

z

z

z

Page 30: A Competitive Model of Superstars

30

S

D

D’

Q*

S’

Q

P

$20

$30

a

bc

d

Figure 1

Market

Page 31: A Competitive Model of Superstars

31

For ex., if P( ) = $24 after entry,

since /z0 = 3, P(z0) = $8 < AC,

so < 0 for those with z = z0.

z

z

Page 32: A Competitive Model of Superstars

32

Thus, the lowest quality sellers

exit, market supply

decreases, increases, &

market demand increases until,

at the new level of ,

P( ) = P0/z0.

z

z

z z

Page 33: A Competitive Model of Superstars

33

Only if the elasticity of market demand

with respect to z is equal to x (x > 1) would

price as much as . If this elasticity > x,

then P( ) would faster than , low

quality sellers would have > 0, entry

would occur at this quality level, market

demand would , & P( ) .

zz

z

z

Page 34: A Competitive Model of Superstars

34

A Model

Let total cost , C, = q2 + F. AC = q + F/q.

Min. pt. of AC: q = F1/2, so P0 = 2F1/2.

Let inverse mkt. demand be:

PD = [1000 – Q].

In long-run equilibrium, PD = P( ), so solve

inverse mkt. demand for Q:

z

z

Page 35: A Competitive Model of Superstars

35

Q = A – P( )/ = A – P0/z0,

due to arbitrage. The above Q is

the long-run equilibrium point on

mkt. demand: where the market

clears, = 0 for non-stars, &

arbitrage determines P(z).

z z

Page 36: A Competitive Model of Superstars

36

The total # of firms in long-run

equilibrium depends on the distribution

of stars. The # of non-stars, N, adjusts

to maintain zero for non-stars.

Page 37: A Competitive Model of Superstars

37

Given the assumed cost equation,

MC is independent of z, &, since P(z)

is linear in z, a firm with, say, 4 times

the quality of a 2nd firm will have a

profit-maximizing q that is 4 times

that of the 2nd firm.

Page 38: A Competitive Model of Superstars

38

Long run supply comes from adding

each firms MC (depending on the long-

run equilibrium # of firms). Setting

supply & demand = determines N. With

z0 = 1 & P0 = $10, we have:

N = max(0, 2[99 – Qstar/10]),

where Qstar = output of all those with z > z0.

Page 39: A Competitive Model of Superstars

39

Assume QStar < 990, so some sellers with the

lowest quality (z0) exist in long-run equilibrium.

Suppose all stars are identical, & consider some

examples. Note, given MC, q(z0) = 5, z0 = 1, &,

given mkt. demand, Q = 990---independent of .z

Page 40: A Competitive Model of Superstars

40

# of stars

zstars Qstars QNon-stars # of Non-stars

Stars’ % of total # of firms

Stars’ % of Q Stars’ % of R

8 5 200 790 158 5% 20% 56% 8 6 240 750 150 5% 24% 66% 8 9 360 630 126 6% 36% 84%

Page 41: A Competitive Model of Superstars

41

NOTE: in the examples considered in the table,

no one firm sells as much as 5% of the total

amount sold (the case when zStar = 9, so

qStar = 45).

Page 42: A Competitive Model of Superstars

42

What is required for Superstar effects?

With Cost = zq, in the examples above,

I used = 0 & = 2. If 0 < < 1, &

> 2, we would not have -max. q linear

in z, rather 2q*/ z2 < 0.

Page 43: A Competitive Model of Superstars

43

Superstar effects still will exist (but will be

smaller) if:

1) significant quality differences exist between sellers;

2) the elasticity of total cost with respect to quality is less than 1; &

3) total cost does not increase too rapidly as output increases.