13
Beyond Managerial Opportunism: Supplier Power and Managerial Compliance in a Franchised Marketing Channel - Jonathan E. Brill TEMPLE UNIVERSITY A groundbreaking contribution to transaction cost analysis was advanced byJohn (1984) who recognized that managerial opportunism is a behavioral variable requiring theoretical explanation, not an exogenous constraint to be assumed and imposed upon the marketing channel network. However, it is argued that severalfeatures ofJohn’sfina1 modeipredictingopportunism seem problematic. An alternative model, one that explains supplier power and managerial opportunism-the latter being viewed as an aspect of the broader and more common social psychological construct o/compliance-is proposed and operatlonulrzed using]ohn’s (1984) indicator measures. Then, using John’s (1984) published data, this model is subjected to stathtical testing and modt$cation through analysis ojcovariance structures. Results suggest that the proposed model is superior tojohn’s with respect to goodness-of+ and other important modeling criteria. Conclusions, manage& implications, study limitations, and directions jorficture research are discussed. J BUSN RES 1994. 30.211-223 ncluded among the central constructs posited by the theory of economics of organization structure known as transaction cost analysis (Williamson, 1975, 1981) is managerial-oppor- tunism. Opportunism in the context of transaction cost theory is to be distinguished from strategic opportunism. Whereas the latter describes a manager’s “ability to remain focused on long- term objectives while staying flexible enough to solve day-to-day problems and recognize new c?portunities” (Isenberg, 1987, p.92) managerial opportunism refers to the behavior whereby managers distort or conceal information, or refrain from acting as promised, expected, or obliged in hope or anticipation of re:tizing a benefit for themselves or their firm at the expense of another. Not all managerial efforts to realize advantage constitute opportunistic behavior, however. Consistent with Williamson’s (1975, p. 6) definition of “self-interest seeking with guile,” duplicity must play a central role in shaping the behavior. Managerial opportunism is undesirable, then, because it involves the consumption of sidck resources that might have been used to further the objecnves of the channel network or a particular dyadic relationship within it. Address correspondence roJonathan E Br~ll. Ph D ,303Ol Wedgewood Drwe. Solon. Ohw 44 139 Journal of Busmess Research 30, 21 I-223 (1994) 0 Elsewer Science Inc , 655 Avenue of the Americas, New York, NY 10010 Like any theoretical perspective, transaction cost analysis in not without weakness. Robins (1987). for one, has discussed several assumptions incorporated by this perspective that do not appear to deserve the axiomatic status they are given. That managers are inherently opportunistic should also be added to such a discussion. Indeed, in a groundbreaking study, John (1984) noted that the transaction cost research program has adopted this view in the face of a large body of research which suggests that opportunism is not inherently characteristic of human behavioral interactions, especially when relationships continue over time. Beginning from this basis, John (1984) pro- posed and tested a theoretical model based upon arguments that power and organizational structure are important antece- dents of managerial opportunism. By recognizing the need to understand opportunism’s antecedents and by offering a plau- sible explanation for when and to what extent opportunistic behavior can be expected in marketing channel relationships involving franchised systems of retail distribution, John (1984) has made an important contribution to the transaction cost an!- ysis theory. Nevertheless, several aspects of John’s (1984) modei seem worthy of further examination and raise important questions. Two of the paths between the latent variables included in the structural equation predicting opportunism, the path between coercive influence attributions and opportunism and that be- tween bureaucratic structure and opportunism, are not signifi- cant. Another structural pathway - that between coercive in- fluence attributions and attitudinal orientation-is also not statistically significant. (Refer to Figure 2 in John, 1984, p.285, for details). The presence of these multiple non-significant paths between latent constructs certainly challenges one’s confidence in the structure of John’s model. A second, and perhaps even more important, issue is the models treatment of supplier power. John’s (1984) model posits that French and Raven’s (1959) five bases of social power are distinct despite wide recognition that these categories of in- fluence are overlapping. not murudy exclusive (e.g., see Kipnis. richmtdt, and Wilkinson, 1980; Raven, 1974). Also disconcert- ing is that the model posits that some of these bases affect managerial attitudes whereas others affect managerial behaviors, a hypothesis first suggested by Raven and Krugkmski (197@). when convincing empirical evidence supporting this typothe- ISSN 0148.2963f9467.00

1564r777898y

  • Upload
    psong92

  • View
    212

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

DESCRIPTION

refrhnh

Citation preview

  • Beyond Managerial Opportunism: Supplier Power and Managerial Compliance in a Franchised Marketing Channel -

    Jonathan E. Brill TEMPLE UNIVERSITY

    A groundbreaking contribution to transaction cost analysis was advanced

    byJohn (1984) who recognized that managerial opportunism is a behavioral

    variable requiring theoretical explanation, not an exogenous constraint to

    be assumed and imposed upon the marketing channel network. However,

    it is argued that severalfeatures ofJohnsfina1 modeipredictingopportunism

    seem problematic. An alternative model, one that explains supplier power

    and managerial opportunism-the latter being viewed as an aspect of the

    broader and more common social psychological construct o/compliance-is

    proposed and operatlonulrzed using]ohns (1984) indicator measures. Then,

    using Johns (1984) published data, this model is subjected to stathtical testing

    and modt$cation through analysis ojcovariance structures. Results suggest

    that the proposed model is superior tojohns with respect to goodness-of+ and other important modeling criteria. Conclusions, manage& implications,

    study limitations, and directions jorficture research are discussed. J BUSN RES 1994. 30.211-223

    ncluded among the central constructs posited by the theory of economics of organization structure known as transaction cost analysis (Williamson, 1975, 1981) is managerial-oppor-

    tunism. Opportunism in the context of transaction cost theory is to be distinguished from strategic opportunism. Whereas the latter describes a managers ability to remain focused on long- term objectives while staying flexible enough to solve day-to-day problems and recognize new c?portunities (Isenberg, 1987, p.92) managerial opportunism refers to the behavior whereby managers distort or conceal information, or refrain from acting as promised, expected, or obliged in hope or anticipation of re:tizing a benefit for themselves or their firm at the expense of another. Not all managerial efforts to realize advantage constitute opportunistic behavior, however. Consistent with Williamsons (1975, p. 6) definition of self-interest seeking with guile, duplicity must play a central role in shaping the behavior. Managerial opportunism is undesirable, then, because it involves the consumption of sidck resources that might have been used to further the objecnves of the channel network or a particular dyadic relationship within it.

    Address correspondence ro Jonathan E Br~ll. Ph D ,303Ol Wedgewood Drwe. Solon. Ohw 44 139

    Journal of Busmess Research 30, 21 I-223 (1994) 0 Elsewer Science Inc , 655 Avenue of the Americas, New York, NY 10010

    Like any theoretical perspective, transaction cost analysis in not without weakness. Robins (1987). for one, has discussed several assumptions incorporated by this perspective that do not appear to deserve the axiomatic status they are given. That managers are inherently opportunistic should also be added to such a discussion. Indeed, in a groundbreaking study, John (1984) noted that the transaction cost research program has adopted this view in the face of a large body of research which suggests that opportunism is not inherently characteristic of human behavioral interactions, especially when relationships continue over time. Beginning from this basis, John (1984) pro- posed and tested a theoretical model based upon arguments that power and organizational structure are important antece- dents of managerial opportunism. By recognizing the need to understand opportunisms antecedents and by offering a plau- sible explanation for when and to what extent opportunistic behavior can be expected in marketing channel relationships involving franchised systems of retail distribution, John (1984) has made an important contribution to the transaction cost an!- ysis theory.

    Nevertheless, several aspects of Johns (1984) modei seem worthy of further examination and raise important questions. Two of the paths between the latent variables included in the structural equation predicting opportunism, the path between coercive influence attributions and opportunism and that be- tween bureaucratic structure and opportunism, are not signifi- cant. Another structural pathway - that between coercive in- fluence attributions and attitudinal orientation-is also not statistically significant. (Refer to Figure 2 in John, 1984, p.285, for details). The presence of these multiple non-significant paths between latent constructs certainly challenges ones confidence in the structure of Johns model.

    A second, and perhaps even more important, issue is the models treatment of supplier power. Johns (1984) model posits that French and Ravens (1959) five bases of social power are distinct despite wide recognition that these categories of in- fluence are overlapping. not murudy exclusive (e.g., see Kipnis. richmtdt, and Wilkinson, 1980; Raven, 1974). Also disconcert- ing is that the model posits that some of these bases affect managerial attitudes whereas others affect managerial behaviors, a hypothesis first suggested by Raven and Krugkmski (197@). when convincing empirical evidence supporting this typothe-

    ISSN 0148.2963f9467.00

  • 212 J Bum Res ?994:30:211-223

    J. E. Brill

    sis has yet to be reported. Indeed, Johns (1984) model tests this hypothesis, and it is found to exhibit a relatively poor fi: with the data, In the absence of stronger evidence, then, it seems rp?- sonable to consider other plausible models where the Raven and Kruglanski (1970) hypothesis is not incorporated in the explanation of opportunism.

    Finally, Johns (1984) model predicts opportunism in a be- havioral vacuum, failing to link it conceptually to other behav- ioral constructs that have been established in social psychol- ogy. This seems odd in view of the fact that John (1984) himself has not only cited lack of cooperation, such as the non-perfor- mance of promises or obligations, as an example of opportunism (p.ER), but also has argued that aggressive retaliarnry actions in workplace tend to manifest themselves in opportunistic be- haviors Because cooperation and aggressiveness are familiar concepts in social research, these observations suggest that a more general model, one in which opporrunism is viewed as an aspect of a broader class of behavior, may be possible.

    Consistent with these issues, the initial motivation for the present study was to use Johns (lJ84) data set to develop and test an alternative model that would explain managerial oppor- tunism and supplier power while viewing opportunism as an outcome or aspect of a more familiar social psychological con- struct, compliance. Recognizing that John (1984) collected data from managers of oil company gasoline service station franchises, this study seeks to understand the antecedents of these vari- ables in the context of a franchised marketing channel system. Though this study is limited in this way, other studies concerned with supplier power have provided evidence that marketing the- ories may hold across both franchise and nonfranchise chan- nel systems (Hunt and Nevin, 1974; cf. Lusch, 1977). By featur- ing a model in which compliance predicts supplier power and managerial opportunism, the latter being an element of trans- action cost analysis ontology, this study contributes to market- ing knowledge by providing a connection between transaction cost analysis and theories of social power, a traditional con- struct in marketing channels research.

    Theoretical Development

    Compliance refers simply to the overt behavioral adherence to rules or norms (Festinger, 1953; Freedman, Wallington, and Bless, 1967; Froming and Carver, 1981; Gray and Robl>rts- Gray, 1979; Kiesler and Kiesler. 1969). It is to be distinguished from conformity, which may be defined as compliance eciom- panied by attitudinal acceptance of these norms (Allen, 1965; Festinger, 1953; Kiesler and Kiesler, 1969; Zajonc, 1968). Cer- tainly, behavioral adherence to norms may be observed with varying degrees. so a useful way of conceptualizing the compli- ance construct is to think of it as a contirlllous variable, one that ranges from adherence without any apparent resistance or objection whatsoever to the extreme opposite of this, ag- gressive or combative resistance. Included at more modcratc

    positions alongthis contmuum would be acts of foot-dragging.

    avoidance or evasion, and misrepresentation or deceit. In the context of the business manager, this conceptualization makes it &ar that cc,uperation and oanortunism may be considered 1 exarr& or aspects of compiiant behavior, with cooperation representing a position located along the high compliance half of the continuum and opportunism lying nearer the oppo- site end.

    The application of a general systems approach to theory con- struction suggests that managerial compliance may be seen to have its antecedents in the environmentai variables that con- front the manager. General systems theory (Bo*llding, 1956; Miller, 1955; von Bertalanffy, 1950) posits that the environ- ment has profound influences on the behavior of all systems existing within it. This is necessarily so because the environ- ment defines the range of all possible inputs (either informa- tion or matter-energy) that might enter and interact with its systems and the systems within them, and places limits on what activities constitute acceptable system outputs (Berrien, 1968; Miller, 1978; von Bertalanffy, 1968). In short, the environment represents a set of restrictions, and the chailenge to the researcher wishing to explain managerial behaviors such as compliance is to identify those dimensions of the managers world that place limitations on him or her. In the context of interfirm relationships in a marketing channel, this idea leads to the concept of relational restrictiveness, the constraints faced by managers that define and limit: (1) the information they re- ceive in making decisions, (2) the roles they are expected to perform, and (3) the behavioral responses to these inputs they exhibit or are permitted to exhibit in these roles.

    To be sure, much research attention has focused on associat- ing variables representing dimensions of relational restrictive- ness with various aspects of managerial compliance. In these studies, relational restrictiveness most often has been repre- sented by one or more variables measuring aspects of tureau- cratic structure present within the managers organization. Typ- ical operationalizations rely upon the three dimensions of bureaucracy inferred from the Weberian model: centralization, the loci of authority in operations and participation in deasion- making; formalization, the degree of specification in operational procedures; and control, the extent of surveillance and rule en- forcement imposed. These measures are believed to be inter- correlated positively (Dewar and Werbel, 1979; Hage and Ai- ken, 1967) and are widely used and advocated for organizational research (Aldrich, 1976; Child, 1972; Marrett, 1971).

    In this tradition, the association between compliance and relational restrictiveness is evidenced by studies associating high levels of centralization with increased incidences of aggressive behavior (Berkowitz, 1965) and lower levels of communication and information sharing (Simpson and Galley, 1962). A more obvious connection has been reported by Julian (1966) who found hospital patients to be less compliant when restrictive cont;,Jl:, at A cuerclve tacncs are used in the administration of hospttal rules and procedures. Such observations may be In- terpreted to sugcst that the presence of lunltat~ons on hchavior serves as a source of frustration, lostcring resentment and

  • Beyond Managerial Opportunism j Gum i&s 213 1~4:30:2 1 I-223

    provoking a disposition toward rebellious behaviors. In the con- text of the franchise manager, then, the following hypothesis

    portunistic behavior. In addition, Smith (1977) found a posi- tive relationship between compiiance to attendance rules and

    may be seen to follow: levels of job sa:isfaction and company identification.

    i4: increased levels of relational restrictiveness imposed by suppliers on franchisees are associated with reduced compliance among franchise managers.

    The construct known as morale represents a class of attitudi- nal variables that also has been assoctated with relational restric- tiveness. Though morale has been a somewhat elusive concept to define, Lawton (1972) has suggested that morale consistently is represented by three attributes in people. These include a general sense of satisfaction or self-worth, a feeling that ones personal needs and sense of identity are in congruence with his or her environment, and an acceptance of ones circum- stances that are not subject to ones control or influence. Hence, high morale reflects successful organizational socialization whereby the franchise manager accepts and is assimilated into the culture of the franchise network.

    As with measures of comp!ianre: several variables tapping morale typically have been linked to relational restrictiveness in studies concerned with bureaucratic structure. For example, high centralization has been linked to decreased feelings of work involvement and organizational fit (Simpson and Gulley, 1962). Likewise, Aiken and Hage (1966) found high levels of centrali- zation and formalization to be associated with alienation from work (i.e., the feelings of dissatisfaction with career and profes- sional development and of disappointment in ones ability to fulfill professional expectations) and with alienation from others in the workplace. Such findings are consistent with the idea that restrictions placed upon the franchise manager have a ten- dency to reduce his or her morale: by removing opportunities for the manager to exercise judgment, relational restrictiveness reduces the managers feelings of authority and responsibility for business outcomes which, in turn, may be seen to become manifest in feelings of reduced self-worth and sense of individual identity. In view of this evidence and the accompanying ratio- nale, then, the following hypothesis is suggested:

    HZ: Increased !eveis of relational restrictiveness imposed by suppliers on franchisees are associated with reduced morale among franchise managers.

    Managerial morale may also be seen to be related to mana- gerial compliance. Theories of organizational socialization (e.g., see Caplow, 1964; Feldman, 1976,198l; Schein, 1968; Van Maa- nen. 1975) suggest a link whereby an organizations members adopt organizational norms increasingly as their job-related at- titudes become increasmgly congruent with those prescribed by the organizational culture. Support for this proposition is found in empirical studies as well. In jlt observational study comparing two organizations, Dutton and Walton (1966) con- cluded that attitudinal congruence in objectives among inter- departmental personnel leads to increased cconeration and com- pliance, whereas incongruent attitudes promote the wlthholdmg of mlormarlon, a form of (non)compliant and specifically op-

    The lmderlying nature of the linkages among managerial compliance, relational restrictiveness, and morale may be under- stood through a model whereby morale is seen to mediate the influences of relational restrictiveness on compliance. Support for this idea comes from severai writers concerned with under- standing managerial behavior within organizations. Etzioni ( 1961) has proposed a general theory of managerial behavior which posits that environmental influences on behavior are mediated by attitudes. In more specific and directly related dis- cussions, it has been suggested that higher degrees of formah- zation and centralization lead to frustration and dissatisfaction which, in turn. create an aanosphere of suspicion, distrust, and low morale that results in reduced cooperation (Dewar and Werbel, 1979) and reduced compliance manifest by an increase in aggressive behaviors that are typically opportunistic (John, 1984). Consistent with this thinking, and placed in the context of a contractual franchise agreement where the manger must surrender some degree of business autonomy and operational control, lower levels of morale may be seen to result in reduced compliance. Noncompliant behaviors, such as cooperation pro-

    __-- vided begrudgingly or managerial .+portunism, may be seen as a behavioral response whereby managers compensate for their feelings of identity loss and reduced self-worth. That is, noncomp!isnce provides the manager ways of demonstrating his or her ability-however limited or benign it may be-to af- fect business outcome, and these are used by the manager to help restore his or her sense of self-worth and idennty. Thus, managerial morale may be seen as the agent that first diagnoses the relevant environmental influences and then prescribes the appropriate level of compliance to be exhibited given the pecu- liarities of the work situation. Hence,

    H3: The relationship between relational restrictiveness im- posed by the suppher and managerial compliance among franchisees is mediated by mora!e experienced by the franchise managers.

    Supplier Power Another construct traditionally of interest in the study of

    marketing channel relationships is social power, particularly the power of suppliers. Much of this work has been reviewed and synthesized by Gaski (1984). and several studies have in- vestigated the role of power as it specifically pertains to fran- chise channel relationships. For example, using French and Ravens (1959) typology, Hunt and Nevin (1974) first examined the question of which power bases are used by franchisers to achieve cooperation from franchisees, and then empirically tested the differential effects of the use oteach power base upon franchisee satisfaction In addition, Frazier and Summers (1986) have studied the use of various power-based influence strate- gies m the automotive sales industry. This stream of research has stimulated efforts aimed at construcring more general the-

  • 214 J Busn Res 1994:30:21 l-223

    1. E. Brill

    ories of sources of power in channel systems (Gaski, 19%; cf. Howell. 19871.

    AS n~red by others (e.g.. Frazier, 1983). as salient feature of the marketing channels literature is the rather consistent man- ner in which power has been conceptualized. Interorganizational and channel researchers (e.g., El-Ansary and Stun, 1972; Et- gr, 1977; Hunt and Nevin, 1974) have adopted the view that power is an objective resource or inherent characteristtc of a social actor, This perspective-one in which power typically is defined as a potential force with definite magnitude that is not only peculiar to a social actor, but also may be applied at will by that actor for the purpose of directing behavior of another-appears to be borne from the writings of theorists such as Dahl(1957) and French and Raven (1959).

    not possess power, Rather$anrhisors are cmgowered only when and to the extent that the franchise manager attributes power to them. Furthermore, because attributicns necessarily are derived from social cues and experiences, supplier power may be pre- dicted from-and, conceptually, it must be explained in terms of-the theoretical social and structural variables invoked. Hence, in the present study, supplier power may be seen as an outcome of relational restrictiveness, managerial morale, and managerial compliance.

    This aspect of the marketing literature seems most curious, however, inasmuch as this conceptualization of power is but one of two that are dominant in the broader social science liter- ature. Indeed, several scholars (e.g., Cartwright, 1959; Pahng, 1989) have lamented that the concept of power has been the subject of rather heated debate. In opposition to the power as a resource conceptualization stands the alternative that power is a subjective phenomenon (Bacharach and Bawler, 1976,198l; Pruitt, i981). !n this view, power is the consequence of attri- butions made by involved socia! actors. It is therefore an aspect of a relationship and peculiar to it, not a characteristic of the actor.

    This alternative view, power as a perception, is adopted it-1 the present study. While detailed discussion jastifying this de- parture from the objective resource conceptualization is beyond the scope of this manuscript, many of the arguments supportive of power as an attribution have been covered elsewhere (e.g., see BrZl, 1992; Cross, 1969; Pahng, ;989>. For now, it may suffice to make two points. First, in channels research, power has been measured using attributions of influence rather con- sistently (e.g., El-Ansary and Stern, 1972; Etgar, 1977, 1978; Hunt and Nevin, 1974; John, 1984; Lusch and Brown, 1982; Wilkinson, 1974); and, second, unlike the power as a chcrac- teristic resource perspective, the power as an attribution per- spective is not burdened with the problem of justifying why it is appropriate to measure an objective resource with attribu- tions. Though El-Ansary and Stern (i972) have discussed this question and provide arguments to support the use of subjec- tive measures, adopting the view that power is a perceptual phenomenon certainly has the advantage of being theoretically more parsimonious simply because this conceptual challenge is avoided completely. Hence, power may be conceptualized and defined as the perceived ability or potential of a social actor to influentc or control the behavior of another within a pen r&p timhip CJ~ context (Brill, 1992, p. 836, emphasis in the origi- n;il) and presumed measurable using attributions made by an involved social pa:ty engaged in the exchange relationship.

    In focusing on the relationship between relational restrictive- ness and supplier power, it seems wise to reflect that, in all social relationships characterized by economic considerations, the ascendancy of one exchange parmer over another is a con- sequence of the status conferred upon the first party by the second party who desires use or ownership privileges over the economic resources commanded by the first party. That is, fran- chisees confer deference to their supplier, the franchiser, be- cause *hey depend on the franchiser for the inputs used in oper- ations. To be sure, some aspects of the ascendancy granted are purely social in nature, governed by the sociai rules and customs of proper business conduct in the society. Others, however, are governed by the operational and procedural rules, in a sense the social and political structure, specified for the intecfirm rela- tionship in the franchise contract agreement. For example, the more specific and restrictive the terms of this agreement are. the more legitimate influence the franchiser has which, in turn, can be exprcted to result in greater power attributed to the fran- chisor by the franchise manager. This expected positive corre- lation has been observed by Etgar (1976) who found insur- ance providers with stronger power bases to have increased influence in the business practices of agents. However, this find- ing was in the context of a noncontractual channel arrange- ment, so the present hypothesis extends this to the realm of franchise systems.

    Hq: Increased relational restrictiveness leads to perceptions of increased supplier power.

    Supplier power may also be seen as a consequence of man- agerial morale. The essence of a franchise contract is that one party, the franchisee, agrees to subordinate itself to another, the franchiser. Because of this property, then, the franchise man- ager must necessarily attribute power to the supplier. It follows that those who are sansfied with their membership status are likely to recognize and embrace the reasons for the business relationship. That is, managers with high morale, those satisfied with and accepting of their social and organizational circum- sances or business role, may be expected to perceive and ac- knowledge the franchisers power. Thus,

    Hs: Higher levels of managerial morale lead to increased at- tributions of supplitr power.

    Given this perspective, the concept of supplier power is ap- It seems natural to associate comphance with power. What propriately viewed only as a social structural phenomenon, an IS perhaps less obvious. however, IS the nature of the relation. attributed aspect of a relationship between the franchisee and franchiser. It follows from this that suppliers cannot and do

    ship. Consistent with Bonoma; (I 976) analysis of bargained cxchangc (e.g., market exchange) rclauonships, the existence

  • Beyond rvlsnagerial Qpportmism 1 %usn Res 215 1994:3&t* f-223

    of a bargained re~~onship suggests a mixed power system where there is some degree of equality between exchange part- ners. In such systems, it is this equality that fosters the forma- tion of behavioral norms and the setting of rules, and these are adhered to by the parties involved because each party recog- nizes that compliant behaviors are in its own best interests. Thus higher leve!s of _ compliance, frequent cooperation, and few attempts at dc s.eption (e.g., opportunism) suggest greater interdependency and equality among the parries involved, and this may be seen to translate ir,to less social power being attrib- uted to the exchange partner.

    H6: Increased levels of managerial compliance lead to re- duced levels of power attributed to the supplier (fran- chisor).

    While the hypothesized negativity in this relationship may seem co~nterinmi~ve to some, it is worth noting that this predic- tion is plausible only when power is viewed as an attribution. Those wh3 cornpLy do so because they see benefits to their cooperation; managers high in compiiance, then, are not par- ticularly likely to attribute then past compliant behaviors to supplier power, but rather to their acceptance and internaliza- tion of the social norms (i.e., see their compliance as voluntary choice). It is only when power is conceptualized as an objec- tive resource that it becomes necessary to expect that supplier power and managerial compliance be positively related.

    In light of the preceding discussion, the latent variable struc- ture of the model depicted in Figure I is suggested. The signs corresponding to the specified regression paths are included to reflect the h~o~es~ed directionali~ among the constructs.

    !t is worth noting that it is not necessary that the direct path from relational restrictiveness to comphance be found signifi- cant for Hypotheses #1 and #j to be supported. Hypothesis #I suggests only that there is a negative association between these constructs; it is Hypothesis #3 that suggests that this reta- tionship is causal in nature. For Hypotl~esib #3 to be supported, it is only necessary that tie paths from relational restrictiveness to morale and from morale to compliance be found significant Whether the path from re&onal restrictiveness to compliance is significant simply determines the strength of the hypothesized mediation by morale: if it is significant, morale is said to be a weak mediator; if it is not, mediation is strong.

    Certainly, too, it is recognized that predictor variables other than those included in this proposed model might affect man- agerial compliance and/or suppiier power. While the inclusion of such variables would be desirable, the present study still represents a wo~while contribution to knowledge in that it tests part of a larger and more cumprehensive alternative theo- retical model of compliant marragerial behaviors, including op- portunism and cooperation, and supplier power. Neve&eless. inasmuch as ignoring other potemiatly important variables is recognized as a limitation of this research, this issue will be discussed in greater detail at a later point.

    Methodology and Results

    John (1984) conducted a self-administered postal survey among top rntinagers of gasoline service station franchises of oil com- panies. Survey packages were mailed to a total of 1,000 dealers in March 1980. After two weeks, a fo~ow-up mailing was sent

  • 216 J Busn Res 1994:30:211-223

    1. E. Brill

    to nonresponders. This procedure yielded 151 completed ques- tionnaires featcring only incidental item nonresponse. While the 15% survey response rate is low by modern standards, John (1984) has provided data comparing the sample and population on gallons of gasoline sold (49,234 vs. 45,830), number of years involved with the franchiser (13.03 vs.13.04), years as a gaso- line dealer (15.38 vs. 14.73), and number of service bays in service (2.40 vs. 2.30). With only small differences observed for these characteristics, there is evidence that the sample is representative of the population, and nonresponse bias is likely to be acceptably small.

    Measures Twelve measures consisting of multiple-item scales were com- piled from the data. The content matter of each scale, along with the variable name assigned to it, is indicated in Table 1. Selected scale characteristics, including reliabilities, and the intercorre- lations among these measures as previously reported by John (1984) are presented in Table 2.

    The scale measures were assigned as indicators corresponding to the models latent variables in accordance with judgments bnsed on theory and consideration of the descriptive informa- tion provided by John (1984). The specific reasoning that led to the indicator assignment decisions for each latent construct is described below.

    RELATIONALRESTRKTIVENESS. Relational restrictiveness already has been defined as the set of variables that place limitauons on the manager. As such, appropriate measures would reflect

    the degree of control or direction that the supplier is able to exert upon the operations of the franchisee. Hence, the rela- tional restrictiveness construct should capture: (1) the suppliers ability to deny resources or show favoritism to the franchisee so as to encourage desired responses or discourage unwanted behaviors, and (2) the procedural controls or rules and organiza- tional structure that may be imposed upon the franchisee by the supplier.

    Examinatic,n of the description of the REWARD and COER- CIVE scales as wg ll as the example items that had been provided by John (1984) indicate that these scales tap the first of these two aspects of relational restrictiveness. Operant learning the- ory (e.g., see Skinner, 1966) suggests that both posi:ive rein- forcements (e.g., reward) and negative reinforcements (e.g., coer- cion! direct behavior. Similady, inspection of the example items provided for the LECITMAT scale suggests that this measure is strongly correlated with the supplier imposed rules aspect of relational restrictiveness, The measures corresponding to the three Weberian dimensions of bureaucracy-CENTRAL, FOR- MAL, and CONTROLS-also have been included among tie in- dicators of relational restrictiveness. The definitions provided earlier make it seem clear that centralization, formalization, and control (i.e., surveillance and rule enforcement) are construc- tions reflecting the procedural and operational rules aspect of relational restrictiveness. And, as noted earlier, this assignment decision is consistent with common practice in the channels and interorganizational research literatures. Since these mea- sures reflect limitations on behavior, all should be anticipated to correlate positively with relational restrictiveness.

    MANAGERIAL MORALE. According to the information provided by John (1984), job satisfaction and perceptions of role con-

    Table 1. Scaie Definitions of Indicator Variables Used in the Analysis

    Scale Name Description of Scale Content Name Assigned by J&n (1984)

    OPTUN~M COOPRATN

    ROLERT

    SATSFCTN

    FORMAL CENTRAL CONTROLS

    COERCIVE

    REWARD

    REFERENT

    EXPERT

    LECITMAT

    Self reported frequency of opportunistic behavior by franchise manager Self reported intentions to cooperate (i.e., perform required role behavior)

    by manager Perceptions regarding the convergence in beliefs about salient business issues

    among the supplier and the manager (respondent) Perceived satisfaction experienced by the manager (respondent? from his/her

    interaction with the supplier Reported formaI~tion of operating procedures Reported centralization of authority in the supplier-retailer relationship l&ported extent of ruk enforcement and surverllance experienced by the

    retail operation Coercive power attributed to the supplier by the franchise manager

    (respondent) Reward power attributed to the supplier by the franchise manager

    (respondent) Referent power attributed to the supplier by the franchise manager

    (respondent) Expert power attributed to the supplier by the franchise manager

    (respondent) Lcgitlmate power nrtrlhutcd to rhe supplier by the franchise manager

    (respondent)

    Opportuntsm Conative orientation

    Cn&dvs orientation

    Affective orientation

    Formalization Centralization Control

    Coercive influence

    Reward influence

    Referent influence

    Fxpert influence

    Legitnnstc mffucnzc

  • Beyond Managerib Opportunism J Busn Res 217 1994:30:2 1 l-223

    gruen.cc as they perui;; ;o the franchise manager in his or her interface with the franchiser are captured by the SATSFCIN and ROLEFIT measures, respectively. These scales seem ideal for measurement of the morale construct in the proposed model in view of Lawtons (1977, p. 6) observation that, in its original conceptualization, morale subsumed the concepts of both job sat&action and the motivation to conform to organizatiorzl re- quirements. . . . * For this reason, the SATSFCTN and ROLEFIT measures have been used to operationalize the morale construa and they are expected to correlate positively with it and each other.

    MANAGERIAL COMPUNCE. Farher discussion has already es_ tablished that cooperation and opportunism are behaviors that may be conceptualized as lying along the continuum represent- ing compliant behaviors. Inasmuch as John (1984) indicates that his opportunism scale (OPTUNISM) taps the frequency of oppornmistic behavior, it seems reasonable to adopt this measure as an indicator of the managerial compliance construct in the proposed model. However, given that the COOPRATN scale has been repreqnted as a measure of the conative dimen- sion of managerial attitudes in Johns (1984) study, a sound argument that it is appropriate to use this scale as a behavioral, rather than attitudinal, measure is essential.

    Support for this position comes from two sources. One is the scale item examples themselves, which have been provided by John (1984, p. 288): I do not volunteer much information regarding my business to my supplier and There are some things that I will do only if my supplier checks up and insists on it. Only the latter item clear!y refers to intended behavior; the respondent is asked to indicate what he or she wil! do. In contrast, the first item may be interpreted as a report of either actual or intended behavior. because this statement is phrased in the present tense, rather than in the future tense, it is possible to imagine that this item reflects a report of a current behavioral pattern, not simply intended behavior. Indeed, had the items used the past tense-i.e., -1 have not volunteered much infor- mation regarding my business to my supplier and There are some things that I have not done unless my supplier checked up and insisted on it- it would have been difficult to view these as anything other than behavioral measures.

    A second source of support comes from attitude theory. In his study, John (1984) adopted the cognitive-affective-conauve model of attitude structure formalized by Rosenberg and HOV- land (1960). This model views attitude as a latent construct that cannot be directly observed and, instead, must be inferred from behavioral responses. Ajzen (1989) has warned that, although it is widely recognized that these behavioral responses may be either verbal, nonverbal, or both, many fail to appreciate this in practice. Instead. researchers tend to use evaluative verbal responses as measures of attitudes and overt behaviors as mea- sures of behavior. The consequence is that almost all models claiming to predtct behaviors from attitudes are more accurately conceptualized as models predicting the nonverbal manifesta- tions of attitudes from the verbal manifestations of these same

  • 218 1 Busn Res 1994:30:211-223

    J. E. Brill

    attitudes. This confusion arises largely as a consequence that the conanve dimension of attitude structure is a behavioral com- ponent; indeed, Rosenberg and Hovland (19601 titled their et&j- sic chapter Cogdive, Affective, and Behavioral Components of Attitudes. Hence, all reports of behavior are more accurately thought of as indicators of the behavioral component of atti- tude, rather than as underlying constructions of behavior. The point is that researchers consistently invoke a crucial but typi- cally unstated theoretical assumption: behavioral outcomes are so tightly coupled to the behavioral component of attitude that, in the practice of model building, they may be treated as con- gruent constructions.

    In this tradition, the behavioral components of attimde evi- denced by the evaluative expressions and reports of managers regarding their exhibitions of opportunistic and cooperative behaviors have been assigned as representations of the un- derlying behavioral construction of comp~ance. Hence, CQOPRATN and OPTUNISM may be properly used as indica- tors of managerial compliance. And, because cooperation is a highly compliant behavior, COOPRATN is expected to corre- late positively with managerial compliance. In contrast, since opportunism is a noncompliant activity, the OPTUNKM inpi- cator is expected to exhibit a negative relationship to the com- pliance construct and to covary negatively with COOPRATN.

    SUPPLIER POWER. The use of French and Ravens (19.59) five bases of power-referent influence, expert iniluence, legitimate infuence, reward influence, and coercive influence-to opera- tionaltie the power construct has been a common practice in the literature (e,g., Hunt and Nevin, 1974; Lusch, 1977; Rosen- berg and Stern, 1971). Consistent with this approach, the five scale measures correspunding to this ~xonomy of social power bases appearing inJohns (1984) data-REFERENT, EXPERT, LEGITMAT, REWARD, and COERCIVE-have been used as in- dicators of the supplier construct in the present study. How- ever, instead of dividing these iive measures among two or more constructs (e.g., coercive power and noncoercive power) as is frequently seen in practice, all have been related to a single con- struct, supplier power.

    There is considerable justification for this departure. First, though uncommon in channels research, precedent for concep- tualizii power as a single dimension does exist (e.g., see Wilkin- son, 1981). Second, and perhaps most compelling, is that when the French and Raven (1959) taxonomy is used, the assignment of indicator measures to multiple power constructions may be seen to be largely arbitrary. As many have observed (e.g., Ripnis, Schmidt, and Wilkinson, 1980; Raven, 19741, these five in- fluence bases are neither mutually exclusive nor logically dis- tinct. To prove this, one need only consider two power bases, coercive in~uence and reward influence, and recognize that the failure to provide reward by one party might rightly be consid- ered coercion by another. Consequently, conceiving power as a single entity seems a reasonable decision.

    The d~rectionalities in the relationships between suppliet

    power and its indicators should not be expected to be consis- tent, however. While power is expected to be positively related to compliance, coercive influence can be expected to be attrib- uted only when compliance is not given voluntarily. In con- trast, attributions regarding the other forms of influence are not inconsistent with volunrary behavior. Therefore, regres- sion weights from supplier power to these indicators can be expected to be opposite in direction from that to COERCIVE. This expectation is consistent with past studies that have found coercive and nonc~rcive power sources to have opposing rela- tionships with other variables (see Gaski, 1984, for a review).

    The parameters of the hypothesized model were estimated using AMOS (Arbuckle, 19881, an alternative structural modelingpro- gram to the better known USREL u~r~kog and S&born, 1984, 1989) and EQS (Bender, 1985) analysis packages. Recognition of the reliability of AMOS computations relative to other well- known programs, such as LISREL and EQS, has been estab- lished by its use in several recently published studies (e.g., see Pruchno, et al., 1990).

    Like these other programs, AMOS first uses a maximum likelihood procedure to estimate the free parameters of the model, next computes covariances among the measures based on these estimates, and then compares these computations with the sample covariances. This makes the use of AMOS and simi- lar programs advan~geous for several reasons. First, a sum- mary statistic with a chi-square distribution is generated from the comparison of the computed and observed covariances. This statistic may be used to test the null hypothesis that the model is consistent with the observed data, statistically significant values of chi-square suggesting that this hypothesis is not sup- ported. Second, the measurement of structural equation systems of the proposed model are simul~neously estimated. Hence, when an adequate correspondence or fit between the pro- posed model and& data is found, the method provides evi- dence supporting claims of the convergent, discriminant, and nomolo~~ validity for the models indicator measures (Bagozzi and Phillips, 1982). In instances where this evidence is rein- forced by conceptual arguments supporting the assignment of indicators (such as those presented above), claims regarding measurement validity are especially strong. Finally, the analy- sis of covariance structures allows the estimation of regression coefficients of structural paths incorporatingvariables with cor- related error terms (Hannan and Tuma, 1979; Markus, 1979).

    The sample size ofJohns (1984) data set may be considered adequate for the application of analysis of covariance structures to the proposed model. Lawley and Maxweil ( 197 1) have sug- gested that the number of cases examined should be at least 50 more than n(n t !!!2 where n is the number of manikt (i.e., observed) variables included in the model. The sample popu- lation of 151 respondent easily exceeds the i 28 minimum sug- gested by t-he observation of 12 scale measures.

  • Beyond Managerial Opportunism JBusnRes 219 1994:30:21 l-223

    Results and Anallyis Results from the analysis of the proposed model (Figure 1) yielded a relatively poor fit (x2 - 84.&l, 6.j - 35, p < 0.001). At this point, the regression path from relational restrictiveness to managerial compliance was not observed to be significant, and so this path was eliminated from the model with only an inconsequential effect on the models overall fit (i.e., x2 - 84.572, d.j = 46, p < 0.001). Still, Hypothesis #l remains supported inasmuch as the estimated correlation between these constructs was found to be significant and negative (r - -.278; SE. of r - .082>, as predicted.

    Inspection of modification indices produced by AMOS sug- gested that the models fit with the data could be improved by allowing selected unobserved error variables associated with indi- cator measures to covary. Specifically, the analysis suggested that Error 2 should covary with both Error 3 and Error 5, Error 3 should covary with Error 4, and Error 4 should covary with Error 5. These modifications were incorporated for many reasons.

    First, the idea of covaryingerror variances is consistent with the previously developed argument that the French and Raven (1959) power bases are arbitrary and overlapping, so it is rea- sonable to imagine that the indicators in question are signifi- candy related to constructions not featured in the model. Sec- ond, plausible arguments can be made not only for each of these covariances, but also for why all the error terms correspond- ing to indicators of suppiier power shou!d not be correlated. For example, because oil companies are not retailers, there is little reason to suppose that .vhatever referent influence they might command from retail managers would have anything to do with managerial perceptions of legitimate authority, reward c: coercive capacities, or expertise in oil production. In con-

    trast., expertise does provide one with legimnacy relative to oper- ational decisions, and the withhoiding c.f expertise ma;- be ~CF as a coercive influence tactic; hence, it is reasonable to accept the proposition that the error terms associafed with these dimensions sbvidd covary. I&wise, one partys ability to re- ward a second party may provide a basis for the second party to legitimize the first partys wishes; therefore, it is plausible to imagine that the corresponding error terms should be cor- related. In contrast, coercive tactics rarely are received gmciot& and those being coerced generally seem to downplay the legiti- mate rights of those who engage in coercive tactics; thus, no covariance between the error terms corresponding to these dimensions should be expected. Similarly, given that a fran- chise manager may believe that receipt of whatever expert as- sistance the franchiser might provide is his or her franchises right as a consequence of its status in the franchise network, the error variances associated with reward and expert influence need not be correlated. Finally, as the withholding of reward may be seen as a coercive tactic, it seems reasonable to imagine that the corresponding error variances are correlated.

    As the suggested modifications can be advocated on theo- retical grounds and the arguments advanced here appear to have self-evident representational validity, AMOSs suggestions were incorporated into the model_ The revised model was sub- sequently tested and found to fit the data quite well Or* - 56.772, d.f. - 42, p = 0.064). Figure 2 presents a diagram of the final model including parameter estimates of all regression weights, the variances of all unobserved variables, and rhe covar- iances among the error variables.

    The correspondence of the theoretical model with the empiri- cal evidence is confirmed by other goodness-of-fit criteria as well (Bender-Bonett NFI - .914; GET - .946; AGR - .899). In kt, these results compare quite favorably with those reported by

    1.49

    Emu14

    (3 Ia

    Figure 2. Fmal Model

  • 220 J bun Res 1994:30:21 l--223

    J. E. Brill

    John (1984) for hi final proposed model (x2 - 101.63, dj. - 43, p< 0.001; Bender-Bonett NFI - .83; GFl - ,851; AGFI - .730). But, most importantly, inasmuch as the above discus- sion has provided a theoretical basis for the model, this ~tatisti~d evidence solidifies the proposed models staNs as a plausible and promising theoretical representation.

    Also noteworthy among these findings is that all strucNrP1 paths were found to be significant at the .05 alpha level and consistent with directional predictions. Likewise, all paths be- tween latent variables and their indicators were found to be consistent with predictions regarding their signs. Furthermore, only path from supplier power to COERCIVE was not found co be slgnticant. Although this is somewhat disappointing, there is little reason for concern; not only has every other hypothesis entailed by the model been supported, but it has been argued that indicator measures for supplier power are somewhat arbl- trary in the first place. Together, then, the results lend strong support for the proposed model and demonstrate the validity implied for its constructs and their corresponding measurements.

    Discussion

    The results of this study have provided support for several the- oretically argued hypotheses regarding the interrelationships among managerial environment, supplier power, managerial morale, and managerial compliance in a franchised marketing channel relatior,ship. Specifically, support was found for two centra! ideas. First, compliant behaviors exhibited by retail fran- chise managers, such as opportunism and cooperation, may be explained as a consequence of the restrictive nature of the fran- chise network agreement with this relationship mediated by managerial morale. Second, the ccnceptualization of supplier/ franchiser power as an attribution-with antecedents in rela- tional restrictions imposed, morale of the franchise manager, and compliant behaviors exhibited by the franchise manager-is consistent with the data. Furthermore, the nature of the relation- ship between power and these variables would appear to be one of mediation, with morale manifestations of compliance weakly mediating thr influence of relational restrictiveness im- posed on the power attributed to the franchiser by the manager. The salient implication, then, is that power is not a resource possessed by suppliers, but rather an aspect of the sup- plier-retailer relationship. These ideas are in sharp contrast with earlier studies that not only have adopted the cciiception that social power is resource possessed by suppliers, but also have posited that various bases of social power have distinct causal relationships with respect to both managerial attitudes and opportunistic behaviors.

    The model offers important implications for franchisers wishing to take steps to maximize cooperation and minimize opportunistic behaviors by franchise mangers. The regression coefficients presented in Figure 2 show that there are negative relationships between cooperation and all measures ot relational restrictiveness. Consequently, lower levels of formalization, cen-

    tralization, surveillance, and fate control (i.e., reward, coercive, and legitimate influences) should be expected to increase co- operation among franchise managers. Likewise, because of the positive relationship between relational restrictiveness and op- portunism, lower levels of thes? variables should be expected to help minimize opportunistic behaviors. In short, the chal- lenge to franchise channel design and management is striking an appropriate balance between the need for imposing these environmental constraints and the negative economic effects associated with the uncooperative and opportunistic behaviors that such controls can be anticipated to elicit.

    Limitations and Directions for Future Research While the results of this study are certainly promising, a cautious approach is nevertheless advisable for at least three reasons. First, the fact that the data are borrowed from a published table makes it impossible to split the sample and cross-validate the results. This is a moot point, however, since the sample 151 is insufficiently large to yield reliable cross-validated results for a model using 12 observed scale measure; guidelines suggested by J_awley and Maxwell (1971) indicate that each subsample should include at least 128 subjects.

    Second, the indicator constructs may not be the most appro- priate measures to use in testing the proposed latent variable model. Of particular concern are the manners in which rela- tional restrictiveness and supplier power have been dimension- alized. The arguments regarding the overlapping naNre of the French and Raven (1959) bases of influence and the use of shared indicators is certainly largely responsible for the need to correlate selected error terms of the measures loading on these constructs. Needed are better strategies for developing conceptually distinct dimensionaliied measures of these two con- structs. Strategies for these enterprises that have been advanced by Benson (1975) and John (1984) in the area of the relational restrictiveness should be considered; also needed are more ap- propriate measures for supplier power.

    In developing a political economy framework for understand- ing channel system behaviors, Benson (1975) developed a con- struct, environmental StruCNre, which he conceived to define and limit the informational and matter-energy inputs that man- agers may receive. Six dimensions were identified: (1) resource concentration/dispersion; (2) power concentration/dispersion; (3) network autonomy/dependence (with respect to the systems in which it is embedded); (4) power-exercising patterns among and by network participants; (5) resource abundance/scarcity; and (6) patterns of control mechanisms used (e.g.? incentive vs. authority influence tactics). Still another dimension of the environment worthy of consideration is asset-specificity, the degree to which the means of production (including established procedures) have been tailored to meet the requirements of an- other channel member such that their utility in serving other potential exchange partners is diminished. As noted by John ( 19841, Williamson ( 1975, 198 1) has hypothesized asset: spcc- ilicity to Increase the propensity of managers to behave oppor- tunistically. In the present model, at best only two of these seven

  • Beyond Mariagerjal Opportunism J Busn Res 221 1994:30:21 l-223

    dim2nsiol;s, autonomy/dependence and patterns of control mechanisms, have been captured by the indicators of rrlatiortil restrictiveness. Clearly a more comprehensive operationaliza- tion reflecting additional relevant dimensions of this construct is possible.

    With respect to the supplier power construct, BriU (1992) has presented conceptual and empirical evidence that power con- sists of two dimensions, perceived ability to resist influence at- tempts by others and perceived ability to influence others. Brills (1992) scales are not directly applicable to the present purpose, however, because they are intended to meaSur2 social power associated with consumers in a retail setting, not suppliers in a business-to-business context. Still, the resistance and influence dimensions suggested for power might be applied to develop scales for the study of supplier-retailer power relationships.

    A third limitation of the present study is that other poten- tially important explanatory constructs have been ignored. For example, the omission of a conflict construe: from the proposed model might be incorporated since power has typically been associated with conflict in the study of marketing channels (e.g., Gaski, 1984; Johnson, 1981; Lusch, 1976; Rosenbergand Stem, 1971; Walker, 1972). Conflict is present when the goals of two parties are disparate and each desires to work toward achiev- ing these disparate goals. And, like pawer, conflict can be con- ceived as an inherent, stable aspect of a social relationship (Pondy, 1967).

    Consistent with this view, conflict pot2ntials might be hypothesized to be causally related to three latent constructs of the present model. First, they may be seen to arise as a con- sequence of managerial compliance that helps define the arena for conflict episodes. Second, they might arise from the attri- butions of supplier power which, in turn, may be perceived to manifest itself in these episodes. Furthermore, conflict poten- tial may be viewed as an antec2dent contributing to managerial morale, thus modifying subsequent power attributions and com- pliant tendenci2s. Subjecting these hypotheses to empirical test- ing through such an extended model using survey measures collected among member firms of franchised and/or non- franchised marketing channels offers a fresh direction for fu- ture research.

    The author expresses his appreciation to C. Anthony DiBenedetto. Rachel A Pruchno, Michael F. Smith.JBR editor Ramon Aldag, and the three anonymous ]BR reviewers for their helpful criticisms and suggestions for improvement on earlier drafts of the manuscript. Special thanks are also extended to James L. Arbuckle for his input and guidance in the data analysis and to George John for sharing the Items used to construct the scale measures

    References Alken. M.. and Hage, J,, Organizational Alienation: A ComparativeAnal-

    ysis. Am. Social. Rev. 31 (August 1966): 497-507

    Alzen, I , Amtude Structure and Behavior. In AWude Smclure und FIN- km A.R, Pratkanis. SJ. Breckler, and A.G.. Greenwald. eds., Lawrence Erlbaum Associauons, Hlilsdale, New Jersey. 1989, pp. 241-274

    Aldrich, HE., Resource DependeF*m and huerorganizazional sons: w Employmen: Sc~+cc Of&s and Social Services k=r Or- ganizations. Admin. Sot. 7 (February 1976): 419-454.

    All2!l, V.L. Situational Facrors in Cotirn3ity. in A&an03 in Expprimpntal w &dWfo& iohme 2. L ~rkowitz, em!_, Academic Press, New York 1965, pp. 133-175.

    Arbuckle, J.L. AMOS: Analysis of Moment Structures U&s Guide un- published work, James Arbuckle. Depawenr of Quantitative Psy- chology, Temple University, Philadelphia. 1988.

    tia&rach. S.B.. and Lawler, EJ.. The Perception of Power. ~ocii Fonts 55 (September 1976): 123-134.

    Bacharach, S.B., and bawler, EJ., Batguining, Jossey-Bass Publishers, San Francisco. 1981.

    Bagozzi, RP.. and Phillips, L.W., Representing and Testing Organiza- tional Theories: A Holistic Construal. Admin. !ici. Q. 27 (1982): 459-489.

    Benson, J.K., The lnteror@zarional Network as a Political Economy. Admin. Sci. Q. 20 uune 1975): 229-249.

    Bender, P.M., Theory and lmplementution qfEQS: A Stnlctural Equations Program, BMDP Staristical Software, Los Angeles. 1985.

    Berkowitz L, The Concept of Aggressive Drive: Some Additional Con- siderations, in Advances in Eqeritnental So& Psycho&, Volume 2. L Berkowitz, ed., Academic Press, New York 1965, pp. 301-329.

    Benien. F.K., General and .&id Systems, Rutgers University Press, New Brunswick, New Jersey. 1968.

    Bonoma, T.V., Conflict, Cooperation and Trust in Three Power Sysrems. Behavioral Sci. 21 (November 1976): 499-514.

    Boulding. K.. General Systems Theory-The Skeleton of Sciencje. Manugemeot Sci. 2 (April 1956): 197-208.

    Brill, J.E.. Scales to Measure Social Power in a Consumer Conwr, in Advances in ConsumerResearch, Volume 19. J.F. Sherry Jr. and B. Stem- thal, eds. Association for Consumer Research, Provo, UT. 1992, pp. 835-842.

    Caplow, T.. Principles cjOrg~ni&ion, Harcourt, Brace & World, New York. 1964.

    Cartwright. D.. Power: A Neglected Variable in Social Psychology. in Studies ofsocial Power. D. Cartwright, ed., University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor. 1959, pp. 1-14.

    Child, J., Organization Structure and Strategies of Control: A Replication of the Aston Study. Admin. Sci. Q. 17 &ne 1972): 163-177.

    Cross, J.G., The Economics ojBargaining. Basic Books, New York. 1969.

    DahL Rk, The Concept of Power. R&viora~ Sci. 2 my 1957): 201-218.

    Dewar, R, and Webel, J.. Universahstic and Contingency Predictions of Employee Satisbcdon and Conflict. Admin. Sci. Q. 24 (September 1979): 426-448.

    Durton, J.M., and Walton RE., Inrerdeparunenral Confhct and tipera- don: Two &Xrasling Studies. H~mnn Org. 25 (Fall 1966): 207-220.

    El-Ansary. A.. and Stem. L., Power Measurement in the Distribunon Channel. J. Ma&ting Res. 9 (February 1972): 47-52.

    Etgar, M., Channel Domination and Countervailing Power in Discribu- rive Channels j. Marketing Res. 13 (August 1976): 254-262.

    Etgar, M., Channel Environment and Ciia?tl?l >z?-r&p. j. Market- irlg Res. 14 (February 1977): 69-76.

    Etgar. M., Selection nr,qn Effective Channel Conrrol Mix J. Marketmg 42 (July 1978): 53-58.

    Euioni, A . A Comparative Analysis ojCompIex Olgumzaflons. The Free Press. Glencoe. IL, 1961.

    Feldman. DC A Contingency Theory of Sociahzation Admin. SU. Q. 21 (1976): 433-452.

  • 221 J Bum Res 1994:30:21 l-223

    J. E. Brill

    Feldman, D.C., The Multiple Socialization of Organization Members. Acad. Management Rev. 6 (1981): 309-318.

    F&nger. L , An Analysis of Compliant Behavior, in Group Relations at the Crossroads. M. Sherif and M.G. Wilson, eds.. Harper & Brothers, New York. 1953, pp. 232-256.

    Frazier, G.L.. On the Measurement of Interfirm Power in Channels of Distribution. J. Marketing Res. 20 (May 1983): 158-166.

    Frazier, G.L., and Summers, J.O., Perceptions of Interarm Power and Its Uses Within a Franchise Channel of Distributi0n.J. Marketing Res. 23 (May 1986): 169-176.

    Freedman, J.L.. Wallington, S.A., and Bless. E., Compliance Without Pressure. J. Pen. Sot. Psychol. 7 (October 1967): 117-124.

    French, J.RP., and Raven, B., The Basis of Social Power, In Studies of Social Power. D. Cartwright, ed., University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor. 1959. pp. 150-167.

    Framing, W.J., and Carver, C.S., Divergent In5uence of Private and Public Self Consciousness in a Compliance Paradigm. J. Res. Pers. 15 uune 1981): 159-171.

    Gaski. J.F., The Theory ofPowe! and Con!il!ct in _.._.... _- _. f%u,~*I~!c 1.f DisrI ;bu_

    tion. J. Marketing 48 (Summer 1984): 9-29.

    Gaski, J.F., Interrelationships Among a Charmel Entitys Power Sources: Impact of the Exercise of Reward and Coercion on Expert, Refer- ent, and Legitimate Power Sources. J. Marketing Res. 23 (February 1986): 62-77.

    Gray, T., and Roberts-Gray, C., Structuring Bureaucratic Rules to En- hance Compliance. Psychol. Rep. 45 (October 1979): 579-589.

    Hage, J., and Aiien, M.. Program Change and Organizational Proper- ties: A Comparative Analysis. Am. J. SJcioi. 72 (1967): 503-519.

    Hannan, M.T., and Tuma, N.B., Methods for Temporal Analysis. Ann. Rev. Social. 5 (1979): 303-328.

    Howell, RD., Covariance Structural Modeling ar.d Measurement Issues A Note on Interrelations Among a Charmnei Entitys Power Sources. J. Marketing Rcs. 24 (February 1987); 119-126.

    Hunt, S.D., and Nevin, J.R. Power in a Channel of Distribution: Sources and Consequences. J. Marketing Res. 11 (May 1974) 186-193.

    Isenberg, D-J., The tactics of strategic opportunism. Harv. BUS. Rev. 65 (March-April 1987): 92-97.

    John, G., An Empirical Investigation of Some Antecedents of Oppor- tunism in Marketing Channel. J. Marketing Res. 21 (August 1984): 278-289.

    Johnson, G., The Dilemma of Channel Management. J. ofPhysical Dis- tribution and Materials Management 11, #7 (1981): 3-19.

    JBreskog, K.G.. and %rbom, D., LISREL: Analysis of Linear Structural Relationships by Methods ofMti?num Likelihood, Users Guide Version VI, Fourth Edition, Scientific Software Inc., Mooresville, 1N. 1984.

    Jbreskog, K.G., and %rbom, D., LISREL VII: Ihets Reference Guide, Sci- entific Software Inc , Mooresville, IN. 1989.

    Julian, J., Compliance Patterns and Communication Blocks in Comolex Organization. Am. Social. Rev. 31 (June 1966): 382-389.

    Kiesler, CA.. and Kiesler, S.B., Conformity. Addison-Wesley Publish- ing Company, Reading, MA. 1969.

    Kipnis, D., Schmidt. SM.. and Wilkinson, I.. lntraorganizational In- fluence Tactics: Explorations in Getting Ones Way J. Appl. Psy- chol. 65, #4 (1980): 440-452.

    bwley, D.N., and Maxwell. A.E.. Factor Analysis as a Statislical Melhod, Second Edition, Butterworths, London. :971

    Lawton, Ml.. The Dimensions of Morale, in Research Planning and Ac- tion _fw the Elderly: The Power and PotenM of Sociai Science. D P

    Kent, R. Kastenbaum, and S. Sherwood, eds., Behavioral Publica- tions, New York. 1972, pp. 144-165.

    Lawton, M.P., Morale: What Are We Measuring?, in Measuring Morale: A Guide To Ejective Assessment. C.N. Nydegger, ed., Gerontological Society, Washington, D.C. 1977, pp. 6-14.

    Lusch, RF., Sources of Power: Their Impact of Interchannel Conflict. J. Marketing Res. 13 (November 1976): 382-390.

    Lusch, R.F., Franchisee Satisfaction: Causes and Corisequences. Int. J. Physical Distribution 7 (February 1977): 128-140.

    Lusch, RF., and Brown, J.R., A Modified Model of Power in the Market- ing Channel. J. Marketing Res. 19 (August 1982): 321-323.

    Markus, G.B., Analyzing Panel Data, Sage University Paper series on Quantitative Applications in the Social Sciences, No. 07-018, Sage Publications. Newbury Park, CA. 1979.

    Marrett, C.B., On the Specification of Interorganizational Dimmsiorls. Social. Sot. Res. 56 (1971): 83-99.

    Miller, J.G., Toward a General Theory for the Behavioral Sciences. Am. Psychol. 10 (1955): 513-531.

    Miller, J.G., Living Systems, McGraw-Hill Book Company, New York. 1978.

    Pahng, S., A Theoretical Approach to the Study of Channel Negotia- tion Process, in AMA Proceedings. P. Bloom.: et al., eds., American Mar- keting Association, Chicago. 1989. pp. 73-78.

    Pondy, L.R., Organizational Conflict: Concepts and Models. Admin. Sci. Q. 12 (September 1967): 296-320.

    Pruchno, R.A., Kleban, M.H., Michaels. J.E., and Dempsey. N.P., Men- tai and Physical Health of Caregiving Spouses: Development of a Casual Model. Journal o/Gerontology: PSYCHOLOGICAL SCIENCES 45 (September 1990): P192-199.

    Pruitt, D.G., Negotiation Behavior, Academic Press, New York. 1981.

    Raven, B.H., The Comparative Analysis of Power and Influence. in Per- spective on Social Power. J.T. Tedeschi, ed., Aldine Publishing Com- pany, Chicago. 1974. pp. 172-198.

    Raven, B.H., and Kruglanski, A.W.. Conflict and Power, in The Struc- ture oJCot#ct. P. Swingle, ed., Academic Press, New York. 1970, pp. 69-109.

    Robins, J.A., Organizational Economics: Notes on the Use Transac- tion-cost Theory in the Study of Organizations. Admin. Sci. Q. 32 (March 1987): 68-86.

    Rosenberg, L.J. and Stern L.W., Conflict Measurement in the Distribu- tion Channel. J. Marketing Res. 8 (November 1971): 437-442.

    Rosenberg, MJ., and Hovland, Cl., Cognitive, Affective, and Behavioral Components of Attitudes, in Attitude Orgunizution and Change. C.l. Hovland and M. J. Rosenberg, eds., Yale University Press, New Ha- ven, CT. 1960, pp. I-14.

    Schein, E.H.. Organization Socialization and the Profession of Manage- ment. Hindus. Management Rev. 9 (1968): 1-16.

    Simpson, R.L.. and Gulley, W.H., Goals, Environmental Pressures. and Organizational Characteristics. Am. Social. Rev, 2: (June 1962): 344-351.

    Skinner, B.F., Behavior ojorganisms: An Experimental Analysis, Apple- ton, New York. 1966.

    Smith. F J , Work Attitudes as Predictors of Attendance on a Specific Day J Appt. Psychol. 62 (February 1977): 16-19

    Van Maancn. J , Breaking In: A Conslderarlon of Organizational So- clahzauon. m Hundboolz o/Work, Or~m~;u~wt. mtl Sac-icfy R DubIn. cd.. Rand-McNally. Chicago 1075

  • Beyond Managerial Opportunism

    von BertaJanffy, L., The Theory of Open Systems in Physics and Biol- ogy. Science 1!1 (January 13. 1950): 23-29.

    von Bertalanffy, L, G, zrul Systems Theory. George Braziller, New York, 1968.

    W&er, 0-C. Jr., The Effects of Learningon Bargaining Behavior, in 1971 Combined Procee,!ings. F.C. Allvine, ed.. American Marketing As- sociation, Chicago. 1972, pp. 194-199.

    Wilkinson, I.F., Researching the Distribution Channels for Consumer and Industrial Goods: The Power Dimension. J, Market Res. Sot. 16 (1974): 12-32.

    J Busn Res 223 1994:30:21 l-223

    Wilkinson, I.F., Power, Conflict and Satisfaction in Distribution Chan- nels-An Empirical Study.J. Physical Distitir and Matoials Man- agement 11, #7 (1981): 20-30.

    Williamson. O.E., Murke~adHierurchies:Andy5is and AntCrust Imp& cations. The Free Press, New York_ 1975.

    Williamson, O.E., The Economics of Organization: The Transaction Cost Approach. Am. j. Soctil. 87 (1981): 548-577.

    Zajonc, RB., Conformity, in lnternatiotuzl Enqcbpe&a of the Social Sciences, Volume 3. D.L Sills, ed., The Macmillan Company & The Free Press. New York. 1968. pp. 253-260.