288
Geographies of Evasion The Development Industry and Property Rights Interventions in early 21 st Century Cambodia Robin Biddulph Göteborg, 2010 Institutionen för kulturgeografi och ekonomisk geografi Handelshögskolan vid Göteborgs Universitet Vasagatan 1 405 30 Göteborg Department of Human and Economic Geography School of Business, Economics and Law University of Gothenburg Vasagatan 1 S-405 30 Göteborg

100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

  • Upload
    jfmxl

  • View
    84

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

Geographies of Evasion

The Development Industry and Property Rights Interventions

in early 21st Century Cambodia

Robin Biddulph

Göteborg, 2010

Institutionen för kulturgeografi och ekonomisk geografi

Handelshögskolan vid

Göteborgs Universitet

Vasagatan 1

405 30 Göteborg

Department of Human and Economic Geography

School of Business, Economics and Law

University of Gothenburg

Vasagatan 1

S-405 30 Göteborg

Page 2: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

ii

Page 3: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

iii

ABSTRACT

Robin Biddulph: Geographies of Evasion. The Development Industry and Property Rights

Interventions in Early 21st Century Cambodia. 2010. Publications edited by the Departments of

Geography, University of Gothenburg, Series B, no. 117. 288 pages. Department of Human and

Economic Geography, University of Gothenburg, Gothenburg. ISBN 91-86472-63-1.

This study is an enquiry into the relationship between development industry interventions in rural

areas and the lives and livelihoods of the people they are proposed to benefit.

The study has two main departure points. One is the author‟s own experiences of the development

industry in rural Cambodia, where interventions rarely have more than a marginal impact on people‟s

lives and livelihoods. The other is the way in which landmark studies of rural development projects

featured misrepresentation of rural lives and livelihoods as central to their analysis of the failure of

those projects.

Early 21st Century development policy tends to focus on institutional change rather than project

implementation, and property rights are often to the fore. By focusing on property rights interventions

in Cambodia this study enables reflection on whether the patterns of misrepresentation evident three

decades ago in project style interventions persist in contemporary institutionally oriented interventions.

The study is framed as a critical geography of development intervention. In that respect it first attends

to the spatial distribution of interventions in relation to the spatial distribution of key political

economy phenomena they seek to address; it secondly employs contextualised studies of place in order

to subject the generalising claims of theory and policy to critical analysis; thirdly, it employs a

conceptualisation of development interventions as journeys, opening to scrutiny the interests and

discourses that channel and filter them en route to implementation.

The thesis includes three cases. A national case study of Cambodia examines the spatial distribution

and causes of tenure insecurity and maps onto this the spatial distributions of systematic land titling

and community forestry interventions. Two village case studies, one in a rice-field landscape and the

other in a forest landscape, examine villagers‟ livelihoods, the political economies that shape them,

and the effects of systematic land titling and community forestry interventions in the villages.

Misrepresentation was still found to be central to development practice: the livelihoods depicted in

policy rhetoric and project documentation bore little resemblance to the livelihoods in the case study

villages. Interventions were, furthermore, located away from the main problems which they were

stated to address. Community forestry was implemented in places where the forest could no longer

sustain livelihoods because it had been logged; land titling was implemented in places where tenure

was already secure. These findings are explained as a „geography of evasion‟ and discussed as a form

of development industry overreach. It is concluded that there may be little point in the development

industry trying to extend rights to places where national governments are not prepared to enforce those

rights. The implications of this finding for future policymaking and research are discussed.

Keywords: Development geography; property rights interventions; land titling; community

forestry; development industry; Cambodia

ISSN 0346-6663

ISBN 91-86472-63-1

Robin Biddulph

Printed by Geson

Göteborg 2010

Distribution:

Department of Human and Economic Geography

School of Business, Economics and Law

University of Gothenburg

Vasagatan 1

S-405 30 Göteborg

Page 4: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

iv

Acknowledgements

I haven‟t finished yet! I have more thinking and learning to do about the issues raised in this

thesis. Creating a complete text from my incomplete thought processes has tested my abilities, not

least my time management skills. As a consequence the drafts that I have circulated for comment

have not generally been as near completion as I would have wished. Many people have helped

generously with the production of this thesis. The limitations of the final product, however, are

entirely my responsibility. To all who have contributed, please rest assured that I will continue to

listen to criticism and advice and to try to continue learning.

Thank you to all who read and commented on chapter drafts: Jonas Lindberg; Shaun Williams;

Jerry Olsson; Claes Alvstam; Bertil Vilhelmson; Alix Kent; Lotta Frandberg; Fia Espling; Pelle

Amberntsson; Peter Swift; Daniel Adler; an anonymous reader in Phnom Penh. Thanks also to

Anders Larsson for the case study villages map and to Cheryl Cordeira for help with editing the

pictures.

Thank you for their generosity to the Swedish Society for Anthropology and Geography who

funded two of the field trips for this thesis and to Geografiska föreningen i Göteborg and the

Knut and Alice Wallenberg Foundation who funded one field trip each.

The thesis would have been much poorer, and the research would not have been such a joy to

conduct without the contributions of Ton Saroth, Sang Dina, Phon Chanreth, Ouen Sokra. Thank

you to all of you for your assistance and ideas and sense of humour. You are all friendly, open,

respectful people, which is why villagers in Bey and Buon were happy to speak so freely with you

and why you were such an outstanding research team. Thanks also to Te Phally and Hun Chaom

who each participated in one research trip. And a special thanks to Nyik Nai who was a very

special guest researcher on our final trip to Bey.

At the Royal University of Phnom Penh (RUPP), thanks go to Rector Mr Lav Chhiv Eav, and to

Acting Head of the Department of Geography Mr Bun Serey, both for facilitating my work and

for taking an interest in it. Thanks also for the help of Luise Ahrens and Alastair Curry at RUPP

and to all at the Cambodia Development Resource Institute and at the CBNRM Learning Institute

for allowing me to present and for discussing ideas and findings with me.

In the villages we were received with great friendliness and warmth. Thank you to the provincial,

district, commune and village authorities who facilitated our work, to the families in Bey and

Buon who hosted us, and to everyone who gave us their time. I hope to return often in the future

and I hope to witness these villages going through happy times in the years ahead.

Particular thanks and respect to Mr Sar Sovan at the Ministry of Land Management. It was always

an inspiration to arrive at the Ministry and find you giving extra tuition to students from the

university during your lunch breaks, and still finding time to talk to me. I do not think there are

many senior bureaucrats anywhere who behave in that way. Many other women and men involved

in Systematic Land Titling and Community Forestry made time to talk to me and to share

information and ideas. You have my sincere thanks for your assistance and my respect for the

work that you do. I hope that my often critical stance toward the development industry in general,

and the particular conclusions drawn in this thesis do not make you feel that I have repaid your

cooperation badly. I hope for further discussions and look forward to the spotlight being turned

back on my assumptions and approach, as indeed it should be. Thanks in this regard to His

Excellency Ty Sokhun, Mr Lao Sethephal, Franz Volker Mueller, Bodo Richter, Jouni Antonnen,

Page 5: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

v

George Cooper, James Bampton, Khieng Sochivy, Koen Everaert, Try Horng, and to many others

too numerous to mention.

Thanks (and admiration) to Peter Swift, Daniel Adler, So Sovannarith, Amanda Bradley and

Megan MacInnes all of whom engaged me in discussions in Cambodia. Thank you for your ideas

and criticisms and I hope that this thesis will be of service. An older Phnom Penh debt is to Shaun

Williams who was a wonderful colleague and friend ten years ago on the Cambodia Land Study

Project. Every conversation we have reminds me of what a novice I am in matters related to land

and land rights. I hope we meet again soon.

In Gothenburg I have had wonderful support from colleagues at the Department of Human and

Economic Geography. Associate Professor Inge Ivarsson has been the most professional and

engaged supervisor anybody could possibly wish for. You were also brilliant in the villages Inge:

Yahtsee and Frisbee were surely the right technology to transfer! Thank you for all your

encouragement and hospitality. The development geography research group at the Department has

been a great source of support and constructive criticism. Thank you Fia for constantly pushing us

to read and discuss and broaden our horizons, and to Pelle and Jonas for your critical engagement.

Professor Joakim Öjendal generously provided me with a thorough and critical reading of my

draft at a review seminar in February, while Professors Claes Alvstam and Sten Lorentzon have

both at different stages „opposed‟ drafts of this thesis in presentations at the department and

provided valuable advice. Professor Bertil Vilhelmson, provided particularly helpful comments at

times when I found myself in difficulty with the writing.

The department has been a friendly and supportive work environment. Thank you all for the

company. Especially to my neighbour Eva Bang, and my frequent lunch companions Katarina

Gustafsson and Göran Olsson. In addition to friendliness there has been friendship. Many of us

have experienced twists and turns in our lives these past four or so years. There have been times

when I have been very grateful to have had friends at work. Special thanks in that respect to Lotta

and Jonas for your patience and for being there when I needed you.

Beyond the department David Craig at the Univeristy of Auckland was my deputy supervisor and

also managed to make it out to Bey village with me on one occasion. Thanks, David, for all of the

enthusiasm and advice, which helped maintain my energy in the final stages when I started to flag.

Doug Porter, who taught me in Canberra a decade ago and introduced me to David continues to

both inspire and disrupt my thinking. Thanks for that Doug, and also for hosting Peci and I those

couple of idyllic days in Mullumbimby.

The Internet enables us to access people who might otherwise be beyond our reach. I have been

constantly surprised by the willingness of leading academics to field questions from a complete

stranger and to provide information and guidance. In that respect, thanks to Jonathan Rigg, Chris

Dixon, Stuart Rutherford and Tania Murray Li for your generous help and advice.

Thanks for support and friendship from Szilard Nemes and Alix Kent. Also for occasional but

always stimulating discussions with Bent Jörgensen. And to colleagues and former colleagues at

Slättadam, Björkbacken and Focali who have made me feel welcome during my Sweden years.

Being back in Europe has given me the opportunity to be closer to family and friends. I am

grateful for the love and support I have received first and foremost from my Mum and my Dad,

but also from my sisters Janice and Alison and my good friends Dominic Evans and Paul Toal.

Finally, thank you to Saskia, Molly and Beatrice for being such wonderful daughters and for

making me feel happy and proud every time I see you.

Gothenburg, May 2010

Page 6: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

vi

Page 7: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

vii

This thesis is dedicated to Peci Lyons,

with thanks and love.

Page 8: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

viii

Table of Contents in Summary

ABSTRACT ........................................................................................................................................................... iii

Acknowledgements ............................................................................................................................................ iv

Table of Contents in Summary .......................................................................................................................... viii

Table of Contents in Detail .................................................................................................................................. x

List of Figures ..................................................................................................................................................... xv

List of Tables ..................................................................................................................................................... xvi

List of Acronyms .............................................................................................................................................. xvii

1 Introduction ............................................................................................................................................ 1

1.1 Failure, Misrepresentation and Rural Development Intervention.............................................................. 1

1.2 Was it Ever Thus? Misrepresentation and Failure 25 years ago ............................................................... 4

1.3 Introducing the Case: Property Rights Interventions in Cambodia .......................................................... 13

1.4 Thesis Aim and Research Questions ......................................................................................................... 15

1.5 Other Contributions of the Thesis ............................................................................................................ 16

1.6 Structure .................................................................................................................................................. 17

2 A Critical Geography of Development Intervention ............................................................................... 19

2.1 Introduction – Normative Beginnings/Assumptions ................................................................................ 19

2.2 A Critical Geography of Development Intervention ................................................................................. 21

2.3 Fraught Journeys: from Western Origins to Southeast Asian Landscapes ............................................... 26

2.4 Property Rights Theory and Interventions ............................................................................................... 40

2.5 Conclusion ................................................................................................................................................ 55

3 Investigating Intervention at National and Local Scales ........................................................................ 57

3.1 Justification of Overall Approach and Scales ........................................................................................... 57

3.2 Evolution of Research Design and Selection of Cases .............................................................................. 58

3.3 Conduct of the Village Studies ................................................................................................................. 61

3.4 Conduct of National Study ....................................................................................................................... 69

3.5 Ethics and Anonymity ............................................................................................................................... 70

3.6 Limitations ............................................................................................................................................... 71

3.7 Summary .................................................................................................................................................. 72

4. The National Case Study ........................................................................................................................ 73

4.1 Introduction ............................................................................................................................................. 73

4.2 Historical Background .............................................................................................................................. 73

4.3 Immanent Development: A Geography of Tenure Insecurity in Cambodia .............................................. 83

4.4 Intentional Development: A Geography of Property Rights Interventions in Cambodia.......................... 95

Page 9: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

ix

4.5 The Relationship between the Two Geographies ...................................................................................104

4.6 Summary ................................................................................................................................................108

5. Community Forestry in Bey village ...................................................................................................... 111

5.1 Introduction ...........................................................................................................................................111

5.2 Immanent Development: Lives and Livelihoods in Bey ..........................................................................112

5.3 Intentional Development: Community Forestry in Bey ..........................................................................147

5.4 Conclusions and Implications .................................................................................................................162

5.5 Summary ................................................................................................................................................165

6. Systematic Land Titling in Buon Village ............................................................................................... 167

6.1 Introduction ...........................................................................................................................................167

6.2 Immanent Development: Lives and Livelihoods in Buon ........................................................................168

6.3 The Systematic Land Titling Intervention in Buon ..................................................................................186

6.4 Conclusions and Implications .................................................................................................................202

6.5 Summary ................................................................................................................................................205

7. Conclusions and Implications. ............................................................................................................. 209

7.1 Thesis Aim and Research Questions Revisited .......................................................................................209

7.2 Findings: Geographies of Evasion in Property Rights Interventions in Cambodia ..................................210

7.3 Explaining Geographies of Evasion in Property Rights Interventions in Cambodia ...............................213

7.4 Broader Relevance of this Thesis for the Development Industry ............................................................222

7.5 Implications of Geographies of Evasion for Development Industry Policies ..........................................224

7.6 Implications for Research .......................................................................................................................226

Summary ...................................................................................................................................................... 230

References ................................................................................................................................................... 234

Appendices................................................................................................................................................... 249

Appendix 1. List of Interviews Cited .................................................................................................................249

Appendix 2. Village Census Form .....................................................................................................................254

Appendix 3. 25% Livelihood Survey. ................................................................................................................255

Appendix 4. Case Study Households in Bey and Buon: Incomes and Expenditures 2006-7. ............................258

Appendix 5. Question List for Land and Livelihood Survey I (Bey village version) ...........................................259

Appendix 6. Sample Structured Interview Questions: Spring 2008 (Bey version) ............................................262

Appendix 7. Land and livelihood Survey (II) in Bey, October 2008 ...................................................................262

Appendix 8. Survey of Land Transactions in Buon 2009. Summary Data ........................................................263

Appendix 9. LMAP Written Questions and Response, April 2010 ....................................................................267

Meddelanden från Göteborgs Universitets Geografiska Institutioner, Serie B................................................269

Page 10: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

x

Table of Contents in Detail

ABSTRACT ........................................................................................................................................................... iii

Acknowledgements ............................................................................................................................................ iv

Table of Contents in Summary .......................................................................................................................... viii

Table of Contents in Detail .................................................................................................................................. x

List of Figures ..................................................................................................................................................... xv

List of Tables ..................................................................................................................................................... xvi

List of Acronyms .............................................................................................................................................. xvii

1 Introduction ............................................................................................................................................ 1

1.1 Failure, Misrepresentation and Rural Development Intervention.............................................................. 1 1.1.1 Rural Development Outcomes: Author’s Experiences ..................................................................... 1 1.1.2 Impacts of Development Assistance: Academic Literature .............................................................. 3

1.2 Was it Ever Thus? Misrepresentation and Failure 25 years ago ............................................................... 4 1.2.1 The Anti-Politics Machine: the Thaba-Tseka Project ........................................................................ 5 1.2.2 Paved with Good Intentions: The Magarini Project ......................................................................... 8 1.2.3 The Object of Development: America’s Egypt................................................................................ 10 1.2.4 Reflections on the 1990s Studies ................................................................................................... 12

1.3 Introducing the Case: Property Rights Interventions in Cambodia .......................................................... 13

1.4 Thesis Aim and Research Questions ......................................................................................................... 15

1.5 Other Contributions of the Thesis ............................................................................................................ 16

1.6 Structure .................................................................................................................................................. 17

2 A Critical Geography of Development Intervention ............................................................................... 19

2.1 Introduction – Normative Beginnings/Assumptions ................................................................................ 19

2.2 A Critical Geography of Development Intervention ................................................................................. 21 2.2.1 Place-based studies and policy simplifications ............................................................................... 21 2.2.2 Spatial Distribution: Mapping Development Interventions ........................................................... 22 2.2.3 Development Interventions as Travel ............................................................................................ 25 2.2.4 Critical Geography of Development Intervention Recapitulated ................................................... 26

2.3 Fraught Journeys: from Western Origins to Southeast Asian Landscapes ............................................... 26 2.3.1 The Western Development Industry .............................................................................................. 27

2.3.1.1 Policy Trajectories and Industry Trajectories ........................................................................ 27 2.3.1.2 Incentives in the Development Industry ............................................................................... 29

2.3.2 The Nation State – Gatekeeper and Development Partner ........................................................... 31 2.3.2.1 The Development Partner Problematic ................................................................................ 31 2.3.2.2 Neo-patrimonialism .............................................................................................................. 31 2.3.2.3 Shadow state ........................................................................................................................ 33 2.3.2.4 The Developmental State and Asian Values ......................................................................... 35

2.3.3 Uneven Landscapes of Rural Southeast Asia .................................................................................. 35 2.3.3.1 Conceptualising Livelihoods .................................................................................................. 35 2.3.3.2 Agriculture and Agrarian Transitions .................................................................................... 36 2.3.3.3 Decoupling and Deagrarianisation in Southeast Asian Landscapes ...................................... 37 2.3.3.4 Agrarian Change and Resistance........................................................................................... 39

2.3.4 Fraught Journeys Recapitulated ..................................................................................................... 40

2.4 Property Rights Theory and Interventions ............................................................................................... 40 2.4.1 Introduction .................................................................................................................................... 40 2.4.2 Property Rights Definitions ............................................................................................................ 41 2.4.3 Theoretical Justifications for Land Titling ....................................................................................... 42

Page 11: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

xi

2.4.4 Theoretical Critiques of Land Titling ............................................................................................... 44 2.4.4.1 The De Soto Factor................................................................................................................ 44 2.4.4.2 Markets are not benevolent ................................................................................................. 44 2.4.4.3 Tenure is not always reducible to simple formal ownership ................................................ 45 2.4.4.4 Formalisation is biased against women ................................................................................ 46

2.4.5 Empirical Evidence on Land Titling ................................................................................................. 46 2.4.5.1 Impact on Security and Investment ...................................................................................... 46 2.4.5.2 Impact on Access to Credit ................................................................................................... 47 2.4.5.3 Impact on Land Markets ....................................................................................................... 47 2.4.5.4 Impact on revenue raising and other secondary impacts ..................................................... 48 2.4.5.5 Implementation issues .......................................................................................................... 48 2.4.5.6 Spatial distribution of titling ................................................................................................. 49 2.4.5.7 Discursive claims: why land-titling travels well as policy ...................................................... 50

2.4.6 Theories of Common Property Rights ............................................................................................ 50 2.4.7 Critiques of Common Property Rights Approaches ........................................................................ 53

2.5 Conclusion ................................................................................................................................................ 55

3 Investigating Intervention at National and Local Scales ........................................................................ 57

3.1 Justification of Overall Approach and Scales ........................................................................................... 57

3.2 Evolution of Research Design and Selection of Cases .............................................................................. 58

3.3 Conduct of the Village Studies ................................................................................................................. 61 3.3.1 Research Team Composition .......................................................................................................... 61 3.3.2 The Profile of the Research Team in the Villages ........................................................................... 62 3.3.3 Conduct of Interviews .................................................................................................................... 64 3.3.4 Village Census and Developing Analytical Categories .................................................................... 65 3.3.5 Case study households ................................................................................................................... 65 3.3.6 Iterative Research Process ............................................................................................................. 66

3.3.6.1 Inventory of Research activities ............................................................................................ 66 3.3.6.2 Field Visit 1 July and November 2006 ................................................................................... 68 3.3.6.3 Field Visit 2, Spring 2007 ....................................................................................................... 68 3.3.6.4 Field Visit 3 September 2007 ................................................................................................ 68 3.3.6.5 Field Visit 4, January 2008 .................................................................................................... 68 3.3.6.6 Field Visit 5, October 2008 .................................................................................................... 69 3.3.6.7 Field Visit 6, March 2009 ...................................................................................................... 69

3.4 Conduct of National Study ....................................................................................................................... 69 3.4.1 Approach: Adopting and Adapting Bebbington ............................................................................. 69 3.4.2 Database Access for National Case Study ...................................................................................... 70

3.5 Ethics and Anonymity ............................................................................................................................... 70

3.6 Limitations ............................................................................................................................................... 71

3.7 Summary .................................................................................................................................................. 72

4. The National Case Study ........................................................................................................................ 73

4.1 Introduction ............................................................................................................................................. 73

4.2 Historical Background .............................................................................................................................. 73 4.2.1 Rural Inertia in Cambodian History ................................................................................................ 73 4.2.2 Colonial Influences ......................................................................................................................... 74 4.2.3 Post-Independence ........................................................................................................................ 75 4.2.4 UNTAC and Cambodia’s Second Transition to Democracy ............................................................. 77 4.2.5 Cambodia Today ............................................................................................................................. 79 4.2.6 The Myth of Dependency in Contemporary Cambodia .................................................................. 81

4.3 Immanent Development: A Geography of Tenure Insecurity in Cambodia .............................................. 83 4.3.1 The Emergence of Tenure Insecurity as a Political Problem .......................................................... 83 4.3.2 Landlessness was not a Tenure Security Issue ............................................................................... 86

Page 12: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

xii

4.3.3 Regional Distribution of Tenure Insecurity ..................................................................................... 87 4.3.4 Explanation ..................................................................................................................................... 91

4.3.4.1 Rice Farming Landscapes and the Transition to Market. ...................................................... 91 4.3.4.2 State Land and the Transition to Market. ............................................................................. 93 4.3.4.3 The Transition to Peace. ....................................................................................................... 93

4.3.5 Immanent Development and Tenure Insecurity in Summary ........................................................ 94

4.4 Intentional Development: A Geography of Property Rights Interventions in Cambodia.......................... 95 4.4.1 Systematic Land Titling ................................................................................................................... 95

4.4.1.1 Geographical Distribution ..................................................................................................... 97 4.4.1.2 Explaining the Geography of Systematic Land Titling ........................................................... 98

4.4.2 Community Forestry ....................................................................................................................... 99 4.4.2.1 Geographical Distribution ...................................................................................................100 4.4.2.2 Explanation of the Geographical Spread of Community Forestry ......................................102

4.5 The Relationship between the Two Geographies ...................................................................................104 4.5.1 Geographies of Evasion, and the Beginnings of Theory ...............................................................104 4.5.2 Applying a Geographies of Evasion Hypothesis............................................................................106

4.6 Summary ................................................................................................................................................108

5. Community Forestry in Bey village ...................................................................................................... 111

5.1 Introduction ...........................................................................................................................................111

5.2 Immanent Development: Lives and Livelihoods in Bey ..........................................................................112 5.2.1 Modern history of a Village in Forest ...........................................................................................112

5.2.1.1 Location ..............................................................................................................................112 5.2.1.2 1950-1970 Pre-War Lives and Livelihoods ..........................................................................112 5.2.1.3 1970-1994 Conflict and Its Aftermath: A local history ........................................................114 5.2.1.4 1994-2006 Peace and Development ...................................................................................116

5.2.2 Livelihoods Shaped by Deforestation ...........................................................................................116 5.2.2.1 Loggers and Rent-seekers Transform the Landscape .........................................................116 5.2.2.2 2004-2008: Demographic Transformation – a trickle becomes a flood .............................118 5.2.2.3 Livelihood Activities During the Research Period ...............................................................121

5.2.2.3.1 Timber-related Livelihood Activities ..............................................................................122 5.2.2.3.2 Farming own land ..........................................................................................................126 5.2.2.3.3 Hiring Out Agricultural Labour .......................................................................................129 5.2.2.3.4 Gathering and Trading Non-Timber Forest Products .....................................................131 5.2.2.3.5 Trading land ...................................................................................................................133

5.2.2.4 Livelihood Activities in a Deforestation Trajectory .............................................................134 5.2.3 Prospects Explained: The Competition for Land ..........................................................................136

5.2.3.1 Introduction ........................................................................................................................136 5.2.3.2 The Vietnamese Company ..................................................................................................136 5.2.3.3 The Casotim Company and the Okhnyaa ............................................................................139 5.2.3.4 The Head-Teacher ... and The South Korean Company? ....................................................140 5.2.3.5 Cham Settlers ......................................................................................................................142 5.2.3.6 The Case of Khang Cheung..................................................................................................143

5.2.4 Reflections: Mediating Actors and Factors in the Competition for Land and Livelihoods ...........144 5.2.4.1 The Role of the Forest Administration ................................................................................144 5.2.4.2 Indigenous and Forest-dependent, but not Ethnically Different ........................................144 5.2.4.3 ‘Community’ and how it mediates change .........................................................................145

5.2.5 Immanent Development and Livelihoods in Bey in Summary......................................................146

5.3 Intentional Development: Community Forestry in Bey ..........................................................................147 5.3.1 Introduction ..................................................................................................................................147 5.3.2 View from the Village: The Story of Community Forestry as Experienced in Bey ........................147 5.3.3 Community Forestry in Bey: Meanings and Interpretation ..........................................................150 5.3.4 Community Forestry Actors from Beyond the Village ..................................................................152

5.3.4.1 The Cambodian NGO Based in the Provincial Town ...........................................................152 5.3.4.2 The Cambodian NGO/donor: Footloose and Flexible .........................................................155

Page 13: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

xiii

5.3.4.3 The International NGO Sub-contracting and Co-financing 2005-9 .....................................157 5.3.4.4 The Donor: Control Orientation Revisited ..........................................................................159 5.3.4.5 Encountering the Concessionaire – Or Not.........................................................................161

5.4 Conclusions and Implications .................................................................................................................162 5.4.1 Bey and Cambodian Community Forestry ....................................................................................162 5.4.2 Bey and Geographies of Evasiveness ...........................................................................................164

5.5 Summary ................................................................................................................................................165

6. Systematic Land Titling in Buon Village ............................................................................................... 167

6.1 Introduction ...........................................................................................................................................167

6.2 Immanent Development: Lives and Livelihoods in Buon ........................................................................168 6.2.1 Setting the Scene ..........................................................................................................................168

6.2.1.1 Modern History of Buon .....................................................................................................168 6.2.1.2 Location ..............................................................................................................................170 6.2.1.3 Site ......................................................................................................................................171 6.2.1.4 Population ...........................................................................................................................172 6.2.1.4 Social Organisation .............................................................................................................172 6.2.1.5 Credit ..................................................................................................................................174 6.2.1.6 Village leadership and safety nets for the poorest .............................................................175

6.2.2 How villagers from Buon make a living ........................................................................................176 6.2.2.1 Overview .............................................................................................................................176 6.2.2.2 Work in Phnom Penh ..........................................................................................................179 6.2.2.3 Small Businesses in the Village ...........................................................................................181 6.2.2.4 Making and Trading String/Rope Tethers ...........................................................................182 6.2.2.5 Rice Farming .......................................................................................................................183

6.2.3 Conclusions: Immanent Development and Livelihoods in Buon ..................................................186

6.3 The Systematic Land Titling Intervention in Buon ..................................................................................186 6.2.4 Introduction ..................................................................................................................................186 6.2.5 Titling in Buon: Inclusion and Exclusion from the Process ...........................................................188 6.2.6 Impact of Titling on Security and Investment ..............................................................................193 6.2.7 Impact of Titling on Access to Credit ............................................................................................195 6.2.8 Impacts on the Land Market ........................................................................................................196 6.2.9 Impacts of Titling on the Social Costs of Land Conflicts ...............................................................199

6.4 Conclusions and Implications .................................................................................................................202 6.4.1 Relation of the Case of Buon to other Research on Titling Impacts in Cambodia ........................202 6.2.10 Buon and Geographies of Evasion ...........................................................................................204

6.5 Summary ................................................................................................................................................205

7. Conclusions and Implications. ............................................................................................................. 209

7.1 Thesis Aim and Research Questions Revisited .......................................................................................209

7.2 Findings: Geographies of Evasion in Property Rights Interventions in Cambodia ..................................210

7.3 Explaining Geographies of Evasion in Property Rights Interventions in Cambodia ...............................213 7.3.1 Development Industry Overreach and Geographies of Evasion ..................................................213 7.3.2 Bigging Up and Dumbing Down: Are Misrepresentation and Simplification Necessary? ............215 7.3.3 Unintended Effects and Space for Creative Agency? ...................................................................217 7.3.4 Implications for Systematic Land Titling .......................................................................................219 7.3.5 Implications for Community Forestry ...........................................................................................221

7.4 Broader Relevance of this Thesis for the Development Industry ............................................................222

7.5 Implications of Geographies of Evasion for Development Industry Policies ..........................................224

7.6 Implications for Research .......................................................................................................................226 7.6.1 A Research Agenda Shaped by Geographies of Evasion ..............................................................226 7.6.2 A Simpler Question (with No Easy Answers) ................................................................................228

Page 14: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

xiv

Summary ...................................................................................................................................................... 230

References ................................................................................................................................................... 234

Appendices................................................................................................................................................... 249

Appendix 1. List of Interviews Cited .................................................................................................................249

Appendix 2. Village Census Form .....................................................................................................................254

Appendix 3. 25% Livelihood Survey. ................................................................................................................255

Appendix 4. Case Study Households in Bey and Buon: Incomes and Expenditures 2006-7. ............................258

Appendix 5. Question List for Land and Livelihood Survey I (Bey village version) ...........................................259

Appendix 6. Sample Structured Interview Questions: Spring 2008 (Bey version) ............................................262

Appendix 7. Land and livelihood Survey (II) in Bey, October 2008 ...................................................................262

Appendix 8. Survey of Land Transactions in Buon 2009. Summary Data ........................................................263

Appendix 9. LMAP Written Questions and Response, April 2010 ....................................................................267

Meddelanden från Göteborgs Universitets Geografiska Institutioner, Serie B................................................269

Page 15: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

xv

List of Figures FIGURE 3-1: RESEARCH TEAM IN PHNOM PENH, 2008. SAROTH, CHANRETH, DINA, ROBIN .................................... 62

FIGURE 4-1: LAND DISPUTES IN CAMBODIA MONITORED BY HUMAN RIGHTS NGO LICADHO 2003-2008. ........ 88

FIGURE 4-2: LAND DISPUTES IN CAMBODIA REPORTED IN THE CAMBODIAN MEDIA 2008 ..................................... 89

FIGURE 4-3: LOCATION OF LAND DISPUTES REPORTED IN THE CAMBODIAN MEDIA 2008 ..................................... 90

FIGURE 4-4: DISTRICTS IN CAMBODIA WITH SYSTEMATIC LAND TITLING AS AT JULY 2009 (SOURCE: LMAP) ..... 98

FIGURE 4-5: COMMUNITY FORESTRY AREAS, CAMBODIA, JUNE 2009 (SOURCE: FORESTRY ADMINISTRATION) .. 101

FIGURE 5-1. MAP OF CAMBODIA SHOWING DISTRICTS WHERE THE CASE STUDY VILLAGES ARE LOCATED ........ 113

FIGURE 5-2: ORIGINS OF HOUSEHOLDS IN BEY IN 2004, 2006, 2008 BY BIRTHPLACE OF ADULTS. ....................... 119

FIGURE 5-3: VILLAGER WITH AN OXCART LOAD OF WOOD IN BEY, JANUARY 2008 (PHOTO: ROBIN BIDDULPH). . 123

FIGURE 5-4: CASSAVA READY FOR PLANTING IN BEY, 2008 (PHOTOGRAPH: ROBIN BIDDULPH). ......................... 127

FIGURE 5-5: HOUSE WORTH 7000 USD IN BEY VILLAGE, NOVEMBER 2008 (PHOTO: ROBIN BIDDULPH) ............. 134

FIGURE 5-6: FORESTRY OFFICIAL HOLDS UP THE SOCIAL LAND CONCESSION SUB-DECREE AT THE

27TH

JULY 2006 MEETING IN BEY VILLAGE. (PHOTOPGRAPH: ROBIN BIDDULPH) ......................................... 138

FIGURE 6-1: LAND TITLE IN BUON, PHOTOGRAPHED 2008. FRONT. (PHOTOGRAPH: ROBIN BIDDULPH) ............... 190

FIGURE 6-2: LAND TITLE IN BUON,. PHOTOGRAPHED 2008. REVERSE. (PHOTOGRAPH: ROBIN BIDDULPH). ......... 191

Page 16: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

xvi

List of Tables TABLE 2-1: HIERARCHY OF RIGHTS IN COMMON PROPERTY REGIMES ................................................................... 51

TABLE 2-2 BUNDLES OF PROPERTY RIGHTS ASSOCIATED WITH DIFFERENT TYPES OF RIGHTS-HOLDER ................ 51

TABLE 2-3: ANALYTICAL FRAMEWORK AND AGRAWAL'S OBSERVATIONS ON THE LITERATURE ........................... 52

TABLE 3-1: SUMMARY OF VILLAGE RESEARCH METHODS USED IN BEY AND BUON CASE STUDIES 2006-2009 ...... 67

TABLE 3-2: DATABASE AND MAP ACCESS FOR NATIONAL CASE STUDY. ............................................................... 70

TABLE 5-1: LOCATION OF ADULT RESIDENTS OF BEY, 1-3 AUGUST 2006 ............................................................ 120

TABLE 5-2: MAIN SOURCE OF INCOME REPORTED BY HOUSEHOLD IN BEY VILLAGE, OCTOBER 2008 ................. 121

TABLE 5-3: CALCULATIONS OF PROFITABILITY FOR A CHAINSAW OWNER-OPERATOR IN BEY 2007 .................... 123

TABLE 5-4: TIMBER INCOMES IN 8 CASE STUDY HOUSEHOLDS, BEY VILLAGE 2006-7 ......................................... 124

TABLE 5-5: HOUSEHOLDS REPORTING TIMBER AS MAIN INCOME SOURCE IN BEY VILLAGE, CAMBODIA, 2008 ... 125

TABLE 5-6: REPORTED AGRICULTURAL LAND HOLDINGS IN BEY VILLAGE, JANUARY 2008. ................................. 126

TABLE 5-7: CASE STUDY HOUSEHOLDS IN BEY VILLAGE LAND HOLDING AND FARMING, 2007 AND 2008. ......... 128

TABLE 5-8: DEFORESTATION LIVELIHOOD TRAJECTORY SUGGESTED BY EXPERIENCE IN BEY 1960S – 2000S ...... 135

TABLE 5-9: BETTER LIVES ORGANISATION‟S COMMUNITY FORESTRY FUNDING 2004-8 ..................................... 154

TABLE 6-1: OUTSTANDING DEBTS IN BUON BY TYPE OF CREDITOR (NOVEMBER 2006) ........................................ 174

TABLE 6-2: REASONS GIVEN FOR INDEBTEDNESS IN BUON (NOVEMBER 2006) ..................................................... 175

TABLE 6-3: MAIN REPORTED SOURCE OF INCOME IN BUON, 2007 ........................................................................ 176

TABLE 6-4: BREAKDOWN OF BUON CASE STUDY HOUSEHOLD (HH) INCOMES APRIL 2006-MARCH 2007 .......... 177

TABLE 6-5: NUMBER OF BUON HOUSEHOLD (HH) MEMBERS WORKING IN PHNOM PENH IN 2007 ...................... 179

TABLE 6-6: LAND HOLDINGS BY HOUSEHOLD IN BUON JANUARY 2008 (N=64) ................................................... 183

TABLE 6-7: REPORTED YIELDS BY HOUSEHOLD IN BUON 2007 GROWING SEASON (N=62) .................................. 183

TABLE 6-8: RICE PRODUCTION IN BUON VILLAGE, CAMBODIA. 2006 AND 2008. .................................................. 184

TABLE 6-9: LMAP PROJECT DEVELOPMENT OBJECTIVE AND OUTCOME/IMPACT INDICATORS ............................ 187

TABLE 6-10: LMAP SYSTEMATIC LAND TITLING COMPONENT: OUTPUTS AND INDICATORS. .............................. 188

TABLE 6-11: TENURE SECURITY BEFORE AND AFTER TITLING IN BUON - AGGREGATE RESPONSES ..................... 193

TABLE 6-12: TENURE SECURITY AFTER TITLING IN BUON SURVEYED IN OCTOBER 2008 ..................................... 194

TABLE 6-13: IMPACTS OF TITLING IN BUON SURVEYED IN OCTOBER 2008, RESPONSE BY TYPE ......................... 195

TABLE 7-1: RESEARCH AGENDA SUGGESTED BY THE GEOGRAHIES OF EVASION THESIS ...................................... 227

Page 17: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

xvii

List of Acronyms

AC Active Communities (pseudonym)

BLDP Buddhist Liberal Democratic Party

BLO Better Lives Organisation (pseudonym)

CBNRM Community Based Natural Resource Management

CDRI Cambodia Development Resource Institute

CF Community Forestry

CHRAC Cambodian Human Rights Action Committee

COHRE Centre on Housing Rights and Evictions

CPP Cambodian People‟s Party

CPR Common Property Rights

FA Forestry Administration

HALO Hazardous Areas Life-support Organisation

HH Household

LA-SSP Land Administration Sub Sector Support Program

LIC Land Information Centre

LICADHO Cambodian League for the Defence of Human Rights

LMAP Land Management and Administration Project

MLMUPC Ministry of Land Management Urban Planning & Constructrion

MOPS Moving Out of Poverty Study

NGO Non-Governmental Organisation

NPA Norwegian People‟s Aid

NTFP Non-Timber Forestry Products

PADEK Partnership for Development in Kampuchea

PRA Participatory Rural Appraisal

PRSP Poverty Reduction Strategy Paper

RECOFTC Regional Community Forestry Training Centre

UNOHCHR United Nations Office for the High Commissioner on Human Rights

UNTAC United Nations‟ Transitional Authority in Cambodia

USAID United State Agency for International Development

Page 18: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

xviii

Page 19: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

1

1 Introduction

1.1 Failure, Misrepresentation and Rural Development Intervention

"That men do not learn very much from the lessons of history is the most important of all the

lessons of history." Aldous Huxley

1.1.1 Rural Development Outcomes: Author’s Experiences

This thesis is a critical geography of development intervention. It examines the spread and the

effects of two property rights interventions, in community forestry and systematic land titling,

in rural Cambodia, and draws conclusions with regard to both the operation of the

development industry in the early 21st century and the potential of geography to theoretically

interrogate it.

During the decade before this PhD project began I participated in research studies and

evaluations of numerous development projects in rural Cambodia (e.g. Biddulph, 1996, 1998,

2000a, 2000b; 2000d, 2001a, 2003b; Charya et al., 2001). Spending up to forty nights a year

in a total of over fifty different rural villages, including stays in all except one of the country‟s

rural provinces, I only ever encountered one project which I believed had significantly

impacted on the lives and livelihoods of the villagers. Even that might be considered to be the

exception that proved the rule, as it was the personal development project of the Prime

Minister and therefore the only intervention that was not financed by the international

development industry1.

I had arrived in Cambodia in 1991 having read the work of rural development practice‟s

leading academic guru, Robert Chambers (Chambers, 1983)2. I had been convinced by his

arguments that an effective development professional needed to be prepared to put the “farmer

first”, or to “put the last first”. This meant learning the local language in order to be able to

listen properly; to spend time with people not just in the dry season when the roads are easy

and there is no malaria threat, but all year round; to speak not only with the better-connected,

wealthier villagers who live in the centre of the village near the chief‟s house, but also those at

the social and geographical margins of the village whose voice is not usually heard. All of this

I did consistently and repeatedly, but with what result?

During my apprenticeship as a development worker in Cambodia I first worked as a volunteer

language teacher at the University of Phnom Penh (1991-3) and then as a humanitarian mine-

1 “The Development Industry” in this thesis is a collective noun describing all individuals and organizations

receiving public or private finance with the purpose of reducing poverty or promoting economic growth in the

former Second or Third worlds. It is not a term of opprobrium, but is rather used within a tradition of authors

such as Gardner and Lewis (2003) and de Haan (2009) who use it while trying to understand the institutional

context for intervention rather than being distracted by the normative aura that the word development can attract

when less specifically defined (Rist, 1997).

2 And subsequently (Chambers, 1997; Chambers & Conway, 1992)

Page 20: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

2

clearance officer with the British non-governmental organisation (NGO) The HALO Trust

(1993-96). At that stage I could see some tangible and, at the local and individual scales,

somewhat significant, impacts from my work. However, once I entered the development

mainstream, where I expected to witness more substantial and widespread change, I instead

found impact increasingly difficult to discern. Fourteen years after my first arrival in the

country, and despite the very best of intentions, the tangible differences that I could see from

my work in the development industry were shelves of reports that I had authored or co-

authored and a dramatic increase in my own earning power. My work had (for the most part)

been well-received: many of my analyses had been accepted and many of the

recommendations I had made had been implemented. Yet, reviewing my working life, there

was not a single rural person or rural place that I could confidently say had benefited

significantly from my intervention.

Neither was this lack of impact confined to my personal contributions. When I looked at the

results of the work of the agencies which had contracted me I again saw precious little impact.

This did not seem to be a result of personal deficiencies on the part of people working in the

development industry. I may have been somewhat exceptional (though not quite unique) in

the amount of time I spent staying in villages, but my colleagues in the industry were no

“Lords of Poverty” (Hancock, 1989). They were, overwhelmingly, committed people who

were open to learn and receptive to criticism. They were often, furthermore, vastly more

experienced, technically qualified and well-read than me. A commitment to combating

poverty and injustice, and to improving performance, was apparent not only at individual

level but also organisationally. Projects and organisations were managed in ways that

incorporated a commitment to reflection, to listening to rural people and their representatives,

and to learning from mistakes and improving. Yet in terms of effectiveness, there seemed

little prospect of any of the organisations, any of the projects making any significant

difference to the livelihoods of the people in the villages3. Partly, of course, this is a question

of focus: my experiences were, for example, usually focused on projects broadly aiming at

rural development, rather than at those working on specific sectors such as health or

education. Some of these interventions improved governance as their priority rather than

immediate economic impact. Nevertheless, whatever I was researching or evaluating, the

biggest challenge to my limited diplomatic skills was almost always reconciling the rather

high expectations of donors and development managers regarding their achievements, with

the limited results that I found in the villages.

In terms of my own personal trajectory, therefore, this thesis represented an opportunity to

take a couple of large steps back from working as a development researcher directly employed

by donors, projects or host government managers, and to take a more reflective look at the

role and impacts of development interventions. With the benefits of both more time in the

field in Cambodia, and more time to survey wider literature on development intervention

elsewhere, I hoped that the research would either suggest worthwhile ways in which to re-

engage with the development industry, or worthwhile alternatives to such an engagement.

This chapter introduces the research as an enquiry into the relationship between rural

development interventions and the lives and livelihoods of the people they are intended to

benefit. Having established my personal motivations for this project, I will demonstrate how

experiences of disappointment and failure have also been strongly characteristic of interaction

3 This is not to suggest that all interventions in rural Cambodia have failed. My own working experience did not

involve much contact with, for example, major programmes in the health or education sectors. There were

likewise some examples of investments that did make a clear and tangible difference, particularly road

improvements, and in some cases well construction.

Page 21: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

3

between academic development studies and development practice. One of the features of

academic disappointment is the sense that lessons do not get learned: development

interventions do not just fail, but they do so in ways that are entirely predictable. In order to

place current debates in a recent historical context I will include in this introduction reviews

of three landmark studies of development interventions in the 1990s. These will provide a

departure point for discussions throughout the thesis, and will enable a sense of whether the

debate between academic development studies and development practice is moving forward

from the analyses and conclusions presented 15 years ago, or simply retracing well-worn

paths. I will then introduce rural Cambodia and explain its particular value for a study of this

sort, and likewise present the cases of property rights interventions in the form of systematic

land titling and community forestry and explain why they are particularly representative of

current trends in development industry policy and practice. The research aim and research

questions at respectively national and local level will then be presented, the potential value of

the thesis explained and the thesis structure described.

1.1.2 Impacts of Development Assistance: Academic Literature

Literature which discusses both the overall of official development assistance (ODA) tends

either to look at the relationship of aid to growth or to attempt to aggregate the results of

evaluations of different interventions (Bigsten, Gunning, & Tarp, 2006; Riddell, 2009). Both

of these literatures struggle with problems of data and method: in particular they struggle to

say anything about cause and effect or to produce meaningful counterfactuals4. Dealing with

„aid‟ as a single undifferentiated „black box‟ concept means that the quantitative literature can

only make the broadest statements in relation to the broad questions – Does aid work? Does

aid help promote growth? Does aid reduce poverty? – that it sets itself (Bigsten et al., 2006,

pp. 8, 29). With better data that disaggregated types of aid in different situations there might

be potential for this literature to make a significant contribution to understandings of

development industry performance. However, the current data and methodological problems

mean that findings tend to be both uncertain and controversial. Burnside and Dollar‟s (2000)

influential finding that aid was only effective in situations were governance was good could

not be repeated with larger data sets or over a longer time period (Easterly, Levine, &

Roodman, 2004). On the other hand, Hansen and Tarp (2000) reviewing three generations of

literature on the macroeconomic impact of aid on growth found that there was a robust and

positive relationship between aid and growth, but that this generated little in terms of policy

applicability as “real-world dilemmas remain unresolved” (Hansen & Tarp, 2000, p. 22).

Sachs , meanwhile, has concluded that „geography‟ rather than institutions determines growth

(J. Sachs, 2003) and that aid does work (J. Sachs, 2005). Again, the science has been

questioned (Rodrik, Subramainan, & Trebbi, 2002), and the policy implications have been

heavily criticised (see Easterly, 2005 for a succinct critique).

The literature that looks at development effectiveness attempts to aggregate evaluations of

different programmes. This attempt is hampered by the widely different methodologies and

standards employed by different agencies and different evaluation teams. When it is most

comparable (e.g. when reduced to a single figure by a cost-benefit analysis) it is least

informative, whilst even the more rigorous and detailed evaluations tend to evaluate outputs

rather than impacts/outcomes (Bigsten et al., 2006, p. 6) and therefore be extremely limited in

what they can say about the difference that is made by development interventions.

4 The counterfactual for aid would be what happened had aid not been provided. The historical and geographical

specificity of each situation means that there is no readily available counterfactual for aid.

Page 22: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

4

Large scale, quantitative assessments of the aid industry as a whole are therefore some

distance short of achieving their goals of developing a convincing overview and explanation

of the effectiveness or otherwise of aid. Academic insights into the effectiveness and the

effects of development intervention therefore remain heavily dependent on contextualised

case study work. It is this body of literature, whose conclusions have been far more sobering,

to which we turn now and to which this thesis seeks to contribute.

Some researchers have carried out contextualised case studies and analyses of particular

successful development interventions (Bebbington & McCourt, 2007; Korten, 1982; Uphoff,

Esman, & Krishna, 1998). However, as those authors would acknowledge, these cases were

exceptions. Amongst scholars who pay attention to specific contexts and study the places and

people intended to benefit from development interventions the overwhelming sense is that

failure is the norm. Canadian geographer Jonathan Crush, introducing his landmark

anthology, The Power of Development, stated that ―As most of us are aware, development

rarely seems to ‗work‘ – or at least with the consequences intended or the outcomes

predicted‖ (Crush, 1995, p. 4). Porter et al.(1991) began their case study of the Australian

intervention in Magarini in eastern Kenya with an anecdote from an Australian government

enquiry into development assistance, as a board of enquiry member questioned a development

worker:

‗When you go home and talk to your wife about what you think you do, what do you say you

are doing?‘ Without hesitation, he replied, ‗We talk about our disillusionment. Seriously, that

is what we talk about. We talk about whether we are throwing our lives away in a futile

exercise.‘ (Porter et al., 1991, p. 1).

And having charted the failure of Magarini (a project that had not only failed but had resulted

in a worsening in the conditions of the supposed beneficiaries) they suggested that this was

symptomatic of an industry-wide tendency:

Try buying a beer for the next hard-bitten professional practitioner you meet, and settle back

to listen to the woes of Magarini echoing from all corners of the Third World (Porter et al.,

1991, p. 201).

Ferguson in his case study of the Thaba-Tseka project in Lesotho reported not only that all

observers of the development industry in Lesotho had found unremitting failure there, but that

this was symptomatic of the situation with interventions throughout the African continent:

―By any criteria, successful projects have been the exception rather than the rule‖ (G.

Williams, 1981, p. 17 cited in Ferguson 1990, p. 9).

In more recent times, Mosse and Lewis (2006, p. 8), introduced their edited ethnography of

aid agencies by drawing attention to the “striking incongruence” between the pragmatism,

moral authority and technical confidence of development documents and the “striking lack of

progress” of interventions in relation to development indicators. Of particular relevance to this

thesis and its study of the case of community forestry was Blaikie‟s critique of Community

Based Natural Resource Management (CBNRM), which he argued was characterised by

“failure” to provide the benefits to local people but “success” as a policy which continued to

be adopted widely (Blaikie, 2006, p. 1952). The apparent paradox of development

interventions persistently failing while the development industry thrives has been a major

theme in studies of development practice.

1.2 Was it Ever Thus? Misrepresentation and Failure 25 years ago

Part of my interest is in the ways and the extent to which the development industry is able to

learn from experience. Crush, again, was pessimistic as he wrote:

Page 23: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

5

Development discourse has a remarkable capacity for forgiving its own mistakes and

reinventing itself as the remedy for the ills it causes (Crush, 1995, p. 16).

The Anti-Politics Machine by James Ferguson (1994) was in many ways the academic

departure point for this thesis: when I first read it in the late 1990s it seemed to me to have

authoritatively identified systematic problems within the development industry, especially

regarding the way in which it misrepresents the context in which it operates. I was interested

to see whether what I saw as the „lessons‟ from that work, which remains a standard reference

point for leading scholars in the field of development intervention (e.g.Corbridge, 2007; Li,

2007), had influenced the industry. Ferguson‟s analysis was not, however, the only available

case study of development intervention in the 1990s: its analysis emphasised processes which

occurred „behind the backs‟ of actors meaning that interests and agency were in some respects

under-analysed. In order to capture key analyses from the time I complement the

consideration of The Anti-Politics Machine with that of two other studies: a book-length case

study which emphasises the agency and interests of development practitioners (Porter et al.,

1991) and a book chapter emphasising international interests and how they are concealed

within (or rather without) development industry discourse (T. Mitchell, 1995).

1.2.1 The Anti-Politics Machine: the Thaba-Tseka Project

Ferguson‟s (1994) study of a World Bank/Canada project in Lesotho, which was described by

contemporary critic Göran Hydén (1995) as ―a mirror in which all development analysts –

past, present and prospective – should view themselves better to understand what they are all

about‖, and is currently one of the most frequently cited case studies of development

intervention5.

James Ferguson, heavily influenced by Foucault‟s (1979) Discipline and Punish, and his

general archaeological/genealogical approach to discourse, framings and critique of action,

examined the implementation of what was fundamentally an agricultural improvement project

with a central focus on ranching, but which also had strong infrastructure development

components and incorporated a phase of supporting decentralisation reforms.

This was a project of Canadian assistance to the government of Lesotho, with a project

memorandum signed in May 1975. The project ran until its premature closure in 1984, though

as early as 1979 it was acknowledged that it had had no impact on agricultural production and

was beginning to be regarded as a failure and a costly mistake (Ferguson, 1994, p. 251).

The departure point for Ferguson‟s study was the contrast between the way in which Lesotho

was represented in academic and “development” discourses. As an example of development

literature about Lesotho, he cited the World Bank‟s 1975 country report which described

Lesotho at independence in 1966 thus:

In spite of the fact that Lesotho is an enclave within highly industrialized South Africa and

belongs with that country, Botswana, and Swaziland to the rand monetary area and the

Southern African Customs Union, it was then virtually untouched by modern economic

development. It was and still is, basically, a traditional subsistence peasant society. But rapid

population growth resulting in extreme pressure on the land, deteriorating soil, and declining

agricultural yields led to a situation in which the country was no longer able to produce

enough food for its people. Many able-bodied men were forced from the land in search of

5 I myself read James Ferguson‟s Anti-Politics Machine after I returned to Cambodia in 1997, so it influenced my

view of development practice during my latter years there. Of the other two texts foregrounded here, America‘s

Egypyt I have read more recently whilst Paved with Good Intentions was the only text that I read during my

Masters research in 1996.

Page 24: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

6

means to support their families, but the only employment opportunities were in neighboring

South Africa. At present, an estimated 60 per cent of the male labor force is away as migrant

workers in South Africa (Ferguson, 1994, p. 25).

This, Ferguson demonstrated, was not only false, but would have been recognised as false by

anyone with even a passing knowledge of Lesotho. The suggestion that Lesotho‟s population

was essentially economically isolated and agricultural and had only recently („At present‟)

resorted to labour migration in response to population pressure and deteriorating soils was

refuted by reference to the 1910 Encyclopaedia Britannica entry for the country which showed

that already at the beginning of the twentieth century, Basutoland (as it was then called) had

been a producer of cash crops for the South African market rather than a “traditional peasant

society”, and that already, at that time of agricultural surplus, it supplied roughly the same

proportion of its population as migrant labourers to the South African economy as it did in

1975. With a cash economy, a domestic market for Western commodities, plough agriculture,

a capital city and a modern central administration and infrastructure (roads, schools, airport,

hospitals, churches), Ferguson showed that:

Lesotho was not ―untouched by modern economic development‖ but radically and completely

transformed by it, and this not in 1966 or 1975 but in 1910 (Ferguson, 1994, p. 27).

The result of this determination to characterize the population of Lesotho as essentially

isolated and agricultural is seen in the nature of the intervention that followed. A project was

designed which would strengthen the livelihoods of the people by linking them to market and

improving first and foremost their livestock farming, and secondarily their crop production.

Labour migration was treated as a temporary aberrance rather than a permanent feature, and

effectively ignored.

The centrepiece of the Thaba-Tseka project was an attempt to improve livestock production.

Increased sales of cattle were interpreted as an indicator of successful agricultural production.

However, the local economy was driven by remitted incomes from migrant labour in South

Africa. Young men worked there from early adulthood until their bodies could take no more,

at which point they returned to their households. Cattle served as a form of savings, insurance

and pension, and incidentally as a demonstrator of economic, and thence social status. They

enabled the smoothing of incomes between the times when a household had one or more

young adults earning well and those times when it did not have such earnings. In this

situation, of course, the last thing that a household wishes to do is sell its cattle6. Selling cattle

indicated that households were enduring economic difficulties, not that they were successful

and productive: so where the project saw success in terms of increased ranching productivity,

it was actually witnessing immiseration (Ferguson, 1994, p. 182).

By the time of its closure in 1984 the Thaba-Tseka project was regarded as a failure in terms

of its own objectives. Infrastructure had been constructed, but agricultural improvement and

livelihood improvement had proved beyond it. For Ferguson, however, whilst intended

objectives had not been achieved, he saw unintended objectives which were at work „behind

the backs‟ of the actors involved. This was effectively an application of the thinking in

Foucault‟s “Discipline and Punish” to development discourse; for „prison‟ and „crime‟ we

might read „development‟ and „poverty‟:

6 As Ferguson makes clear, the characterisation of a „household‟ here is problematic. Decisions about sale of

cattle were also questions about control of incomes from South Africa and often divided households on gender

lines, with men reluctant to sell and women much more open to the idea. Thus the „bovine mystique‟ of a

supposed cultural attachment to cattle, far from being „traditional‟ was actually embedded in contemporary

struggles within the household of redistribution of incomes from migrant labour.

Page 25: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

7

For the observation that the prison fails to eliminate crime, one should perhaps substitute the

hypothesis that prison has succeeded extremely well in producing delinquency, a specific type,

a politically or economically less dangerous – and on occasion, usable, form of illegality; in

producing delinquents, in an apparently marginal, but in fact centrally supervised milieu; in

producing the delinquent as a pathologized subject (Foucault, 1979, p. 277).

And especially:

So successful has the prison been that, after a century and a half of ‗failures‘, the prison still

exists, producing the same results, and there is the greatest reluctance to dispense with it

(Foucault, 1979, p. 277).

In other words, Ferguson‟s argument was that even as development projects “failed” in their

own terms, they did succeed in achieving certain results. In particular, he argued that the

consequence of attempts to develop was that issues that were deeply political became

depoliticised, and at the same time, that the reach of the bureaucratic state increased.

Following Foucault, Ferguson interpreted this as the work of a „subjectless‟ discourse; one

that had its own regularities and purposes which occurred independent of the interests and

intentions of any particular actor. Like Foucault, he concluded that the extension of

bureaucratic state power (Ferguson, 1994, p. 255), despite serving certain interests was not

being deliberately driven or steered by them.

Whilst such an analysis seems to imply that development and its consequences are somehow

structurally determined independently of the interests of those who benefit from them,

Ferguson‟s presentation of the discourse highlighted the way in which the discourse was

shaped by the needs of the development industry. His argument was that the industry

represented Lesotho in a certain way because it needed to portray it as susceptible to

intervention. He pointed to four particular requirements: that Lesotho needed to be presented

as aboriginal/isolated, as agricultural, as a national economy and as governable (Ferguson,

1994, pp. 71-72).

He argued that the misrepresentation of the context of Lesotho was a direct consequence of

the requirements of development discourse:

For an analysis to meet the needs of ‗development‘ institutions it must do what academic

discourse inevitably fails to do; it must make Lesotho out to be an enormously promising

candidate for the only sort of intervention a ‗development‘ agency is capable of launching: the

apolitical, technical ‗development‘ intervention (1994, p. 67).

There is therefore a duality to Ferguson‟s analysis. On the one hand he suggested that there

was an impersonal, subjectless force at work, but on the other hand he suggested that the

discourse was shaped by the distorting needs of the development industry and its employees.

This paradox directs our attention towards the other two contemporary case studies. Porter et

al. (1991) were strong where Ferguson was weak, namely on analysing the actual motives and

behaviours of the development practitioners, whilst Mitchell (1995) examined a case (the

United States in Egypt) where geopolitical economic and security interests of the development

partner were engaged, which was hardly the case for Canada in Lesotho.

Ferguson suggested that the Lesotho case provided a particularly vivid example of how

distorting development discourse could be on the grounds that it was exceptional in the degree

to which it differed from the characterisation that the industry „needed‟. It was not isolated or

agricultural, and its economic life was determined from beyond its borders. However, he

suggested that the schism between academic discourse and development discourse would be

present in all less developed countries. As we will see, the other two studies tended to support

that argument.

Page 26: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

8

1.2.2 Paved with Good Intentions: The Magarini Project

Development in Practice: Paved with Good Intentions by Doug Porter, Bryant Allen and

Gaye Thompson was, as one contemporary review (Gasper, 1994, p. 908) put it, ―a still too

rare genre, a detailed case-study of planning and implementation that is informed by hands-

on experience and yet constantly refers to wider theory, comparing theory and case.‖7 The

book was a case study of an Australian project at Magarini in Coast province, Kenya. The

project intended to settle about 4,000 households onto 12-hectare plots (Kanyinga, 2000, p.

72), and to provide them with: land titles; groundwater; agricultural extension, marketing and

credit services; soil conservation technical assistance and infrastructure; transport

infrastructure. However, this was another case where the agricultural improvement visions of

the designers did not come close to being realised in practice: water supplies were not

identified, land was not cleared at anticipated rates, issue of agricultural plots and land titles

was a fraction of that anticipated. Implementation began in 1978, but by 1982 the Australian

donor was reporting that the project would not succeed. Ultimately, an NGO community

development project in the area was deployed as (amongst other things) a means by which the

donor could discreetly withdraw with dignity.

The misrepresentation of the context of the Magarini Settlement Project was essentially an

erasure of context. A “people without a past” were to be settled onto an area of “empty land”

(Porter et al., 1991, pp. 43-45)8. On this geographical and historical equivalent of a blank

sheet of paper was sketched a characterisation of the beneficiary Giriama people as

―landless‖, ―squatters‖, ―poor and illiterate‖ and a ―national environmental risk‖. They

were furthermore held to constitute a ―squatter problem‖ in a strip of land near the coast

where their presence was contributing to tenure insecurity which was said to be constraining

incentives to farm and also ability to use land as collateral. The project would therefore move

them from the coastal strip to the “empty land”, and having thus placed them, would develop

them. With more local historical awareness the project designers would have understood that

the Giriama already considered themselves, with some justification, the owners of the “empty

land”, and furthermore that many of them had chosen to locate away from it because of its

inability to support them. In return for being allocated plots on this land that they already

considered theirs the Giriama were required to pay a fee equivalent to two years of income.

The authors suggested that rather than bringing order to chaos, the project was doing the

reverse:

Through the mechanism of compensation they were relieved of their rights of occupation and

for all intents and purposes, became squatters. The project fostered the antithesis of its

primary aims of settlement, and contributed in no small measure to people‘s overall

uncertainty about their future (Porter et al., 1991, p. 176).

Without conducting any substantial study of the strengths and limitations of existing

agricultural practice, and ignorant of the failures of agricultural interventions during colonial

times, the project introduced a completely new system of sedentary farming. The book‟s

narrative makes it clear how unlikely any of the components was to succeed. However, only

by all of them succeeding to produce a hugely improved agricultural system would the

Giriama households have stood a chance of repaying their debts:

7 The genre remains rare, (see also Li, 2007; Mosse, 2005 discussed in Chapter 3).

8 There is painful irony in an Australian project seeking to rebuild relationships with the non-white world,

beginning with a characterisation of an area as terra nullius.

Page 27: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

9

(T)he activities promoted by the project were not sustainable in economic or environmental

terms. The high-cost water supply system, for example, was beyond the financial and technical

resources available to either the Kenyan government or the community to operate and

maintain. Moreover, simply to maintain agricultural productivity, the broader strategy of

sedentary farming demanded a guarantee of water that was not available, labour that was in

short supply, and agricultural inputs that were beyond most farmers‘ financial means (Porter

et al., 1991, p. 4).

The authors explained how the Giriami project represented a meeting of diverse actors with

often conflicting interests. At government level, Australian interest was in demonstrating its

prowess and also its good will in order ultimately to improve (trading) relations with non-

white countries. The Kenyan government representatives were chiefly interested in a

settlement project which would include opportunities for politicians to reward their local

clients, who were overwhelmingly Kikuyu9. The local Giriami people were interested in

preserving their links with the land and also their cultural identity (Porter et al., 1991, p. 142).

Regarding the project they were interested in the 400 casual jobs which the project provided,

but these were gradually allocated away from them and to Kikuyu people instead (Porter et

al., 1991, pp. 178-179). The authors were scathing about the way in which the project

documents managed to suggest, in the face of the facts, that all actors had shared interests and

objectives:

Available information about Magarini does not suggest a single credible or coherent picture

of the problems that would yield common objectives. A seething mass of contending

perceptions, divergent personal and institutional strategies, and polarized interests, yes. But a

common medium- to long-term statement of objectives of targets that could make sense outside

the confines of a project document, no (Porter et al., 1991, pp. 197-198).

Partly in response to the fact that the Giriama were “being shafted by the government” (Porter

et al., 1991, p. 136) an NGO project was introduced by the Australians in order to ―strengthen

their hand‖. However, notwithstanding the attempts of the NGO to find room for manoeuvre

between the various actors, the authors‟ conclusion was that when it came to a matter of

facilitating and supporting the Giriama in a struggle where their interests were directly

challenging those of the government, the NGO did not succeed and indeed could not have

succeeded (Porter et al., 1991, p. 184).

At every stage, before and during implementation, there were conflicts of interest between the

government “partners” and the Giriama “beneficiaries”. And at every stage, the development

industry actors, with more or less awareness of what they were doing, concealed these

differences in order to be allowed to operate. Furthermore, to the extent that they were

prepared to support the local poor in conflicts with the nationally powerful, those attempts

were futile.

Why, in the view of Porter et al. did the development industry misrepresent its context? What

was the source of the “reluctance of development practitioners to appreciate the significance

of history”? The principle explanation provided by the book was “control orientation” within

development practice. By control orientation they meant the attempt to envisage a project

intervention as a system, where inputs can be turned into outputs by controlling and

understanding all of the variables in the process. This type of planning, they argued, was

appropriate in certain branches of engineering: it enabled men to be put on the moon.

9 In the course of the project allegations were made in the national parliament that senior politicians had

forwarded to project staff a list of 53 people, not local Giriama, who were to be allocated good land on the

settlement area.(Kanyinga, 2000, p. 72).

Page 28: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

10

However, the social contexts into which development projects were inserted are simply too

complex and variable to control:

Our conclusions are that in this period development practice has become increasingly control-

oriented in a futile effort to reduce the level of uncertainty which accompanies any rural

development intervention. Futile because increased control-orientation leads inevitably to a

denial of reality and greater not less uncertainty (Porter et al., 1991, p. 212).

Other themes familiar from Ferguson‟s account of Lesotho weave through the book, not least

the blindness of the development industry to non-agricultural livelihoods – illustrated by a

project staff member ironically introducing the researchers to „my best farmer‟ a project

„settler‟ who was also a barman in the local town (Porter et al., 1991, p. 69). Likewise the

completely unrealistic assumptions required to make the idea of agricultural development on

this land plausible, which the authors found ―beyond our comprehension‖ (1991, p. 110).

A final postscript from the Magarini project relates to its spatial travels10

. The authors note

that the failure in Kenya would have been rendered much less surprising if one had tracked

back to Australian experiences of dryland farming improvement interventions in its own

territory, which had also been characterised by failure (1991, p. 84). They also highlighted

was the gatekeeper role played by the Kenyan government. Other proposals had preceded the

settlement project idea. An earlier Australian mission had suggested a small-scale pilot to trial

„catchment communities‟ whereby people farming a catchment would be given assistance to

build and maintain soil and water conservation structures that they themselves participated in

the design of.

Before Kenyan government comments on this report had been received in Canberra, the

Nairobi AHC informed AIDAB that this approach would not be acceptable to the Kenyan

government, because it would jeopardise the way in which many Kenyan public servants and

politicians held pieces of land around the country but did not farm them, or farm them

properly. The local community, under these recommendations would be able to insist that this

land was properly farmed and protected. The AHC predicted the report would be rejected ...

These predictions proved correct (Porter et al., 1991, pp. 34-35).

In that particular case, a blanket approach which would have enabled local farmers to develop

entitlements that challenged elite interests across the country was barred from entry to Kenyan

territory. On the other hand, a settlement project which legitimised removal of Giriami from

coastal land and enabled encroachment on Giriami land by settlers from the dominant Kikuyu

clan was ushered in. This diversion, of development intervention away from places where it

might challenge elite interests will be one theme of this dissertation, likewise the dilution of

attempts to create entitlements.

1.2.3 The Object of Development: America’s Egypt

The Object of Development: America‘s Egypt by Timothy Mitchell (1995) is an essay focused

on how international development agencies described Egypt. He quotes from a USAID report

typifying “almost any study of Egypt produced by an American or international development

agency” as follows:

Egypt depends upon the fruits of the narrow ribbon of cultivated land adjacent to the Nile and

that river‘s rich fan-shaped delta. For more than 5,000 years agriculture has sustained Egypt.

During the first half of this century, however….The growth of agriculture failed to keep up

10

In contrast to Ferguson and Mitchell, the authors of the other two studies reviewed here, two of the Magarini

authors, Porter and Bryant, were geographers.

Page 29: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

11

with the needs of a population which doubled, then nearly tripled. It is a matter of simple

arithmetic (Johnson et al. 1983, p1 cited in Mitchell 1995, p. 130).

Mitchell emphasised the “visual simplicity of the image, spread out like a map before the

reader‘s eye, combines with the arithmetical certainty of population figures, surface areas

and growth rates to lay down the logic of the analysis to follow”. However, the “simple

arithmetic” that the stylised geography suggested was in fact wrong. Mitchell demonstrated

that while Egypt‟s agricultural population was very dense in relation to other countries (about

the same as Bangladesh and about double Indonesia), its agriculture was far more productive.

Not only that, but agricultural production had, in fact, been increasing more rapidly than

population growth.

By looking into the discrepancy between relatively high food production and relatively low

nutrition levels, Mitchell was further able to show that the key issue was not population

increase, but unequal distribution of income within the population. A wealthy segment of the

population – upper and middle urban classes and foreign residents and tourists – ate large

amounts of meat and animal products compared with the rural population. The consequence

of this demand was the reorientation of domestic cash crop agriculture towards the more

lucrative market of animal fodder. This in turn led to a severe deficit in cereals for human

consumption with Egypt rapidly becoming the world‟s third largest importer (after Japan and

China) of grain. That demand was partly met by subsidised American wheat provided by the

United States Agency for International Development „to help the poor‟, overlooking the fact

that the deficit here was not caused by low productivity, but by the preference of the wealthy

for meat.

Mitchell applied the same logic to the question of land holdings. He argued that if Egypt had

adopted the same land reform measures as South Korea and Taiwan in the 1950s, every

household in the country would have had the means to produce enough to feed itself. Political

issues highlighted by Mitchell – inequalities of income and asset distribution – were absent

from the development discourse. He saw representation as key in this:

Thanks to the powerful image of millions of Egyptian peasants squeezed into a narrow river

valley, it seems natural to assume that land holdings are already smaller than is practicable

and that other sorts of solutions are required (T. Mitchell, 1995, pp. 138-139).

In this context, the question of whether fifty million people in the Nile Delta constituted

„overpopulation‟ or not became far more contentious11

. And this was Mitchell‟s point:

development discourse operates in such a way as to frame all problems as having “natural”

rather than political or social causes. This framing thus suggests that interventions should be

technical or managerial, rather than political attempts to challenge existing power relations

and interests.

It is the discussion of interests that principally distinguishes Mitchell‟s study from Ferguson‟s.

Mitchell argued that a “proper analysis” of American aid to Egypt would set it in the context

of international relationships, and here he looked specifically at the broader range of

relationships between the US and Egypt, and at US interests within those relationships. This

meant, not least, acknowledging the importance of the military in the Egyptian economy and

the fact that half of US assistance to Egypt was military aid, most of which Egypt then spent

purchasing US military equipment (T. Mitchell, 1995, p. 155). This military assistance was

not recorded in development documents. For Mitchell, these development industry

representations did not constitute “proper analysis”. A “proper analysis” of Egypt as an object

11

Mitchell recalls Susan George‟s warning that when you hear the word overpopulation “you should reach, if not

for your revolver, at least for your calculator”.

Page 30: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

12

of development would have included an analysis of the economy and power of the Egyptian

military, its relations to US military and to the systems of US state subsidies for its military

industries. Likewise, an analysis of the Egyptian agricultural system would have included

setting the shift to meat production and the consequent food shortages and national

indebtedness in the context of the crisis in US farming and the deployment of subsidized food

exports as a remedy to that problem (T. Mitchell, 1995, p. 156). He concluded by relocating

the stylised geographical image of „overcrowded‟ Egypt within his own argument:

Development discourse wishes to present itself as a detached centre of rationality and

intelligence. The relationship between West and non-West will be constructed in these terms.

The West possesses the expertise, technology and management skills that the non-West is

lacking. This lack is what has caused the problems of the non-West. Questions of power and

inequality, whether on the global level of international grain markets, state subsidies and the

arms trade, or the more local level of landholding, food supplies and income distribution, will

nowhere be discussed. To remain silent on such questions, in which its own existence is

involved, development discourse needs an object that appears to stand outside itself. What

more natural object could there be, for such a purpose, than the image of a narrow river

valley, hemmed in by the desert, crowded with rapidly multiplying millions of inhabitants?

1.2.4 Reflections on the 1990s Studies

The common ground between these three studies is the systematic misrepresentation by the

development industry of the rural context in which it sought to operate. In each case the rural

was (mis)represented as:

Essentially agricultural (usually a form of subsistence agriculture disconnected from

wider cash economies);

Isolated, traditional, primitive;

Removed from local, national and international politics and conflicts of interest.

One clear, implicit question for the current research, then, is whether early twenty-first

century rural development interventions have continued these trends, or whether the industry

has learned to represent rural contexts without repeating the caricatures of the 1990s?

Idealised (mis)representations of the rural have a long tradition in literature and philosophy.

There is a sense of this untouched, unsullied world in the 1990s misrepresentations, although

the explanations provided by the respective authors are distinctly less romantic. Porter et al. in

their study keep the characters and motivations of the development practitioners in focus.

Here one has the sense that there is a degree of cynicism at play: that experienced fixers and

brokers, who knew what was required in order to sell a development project and keep the

funds flowing, deployed the misrepresentations at key strategic moments so that highly

conflicted, near-impossible situations were described as amenable to intervention. To this end,

the underplaying of manifest physical difficulties, ignoring the relations between Gikuya and

Giriami and the production of cost-benefit analyses with extremely optimistic internal rates of

return, were all key in enabling the Australians to embark on a project whose only realistic

prospect was failure.

Whilst Porter et al. framed their explanations in terms of the interests of the actors concerned:

Kenyan conflicts that were not amenable to outside intervention, and Australian interests in

making the project happen regardless, Ferguson and Mitchell, by contrast, laid more stress on

discursive explanations. Both of them stressed the way in which politics was systematically

screened out of representations of the rural context. Mitchell laid more weight on geopolitical

interests. While not actually making the case that American interests deliberately shaped the

discourse, he drew attention to the way in which it served those interests for military relations,

Page 31: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

13

class differences, international trade and agricultural subsidies to be absent from development

discussions. For Ferguson the self-interested „needs‟ of the development industry to represent

reality as de-politicised such that its interventions (framed as non-political) can be of

relevance is part of a larger unconscious unfolding of a process which extends the reach of the

bureaucratic State. He is quite explicit in suggesting that the processes at work are not directly

driven by the self-interest of actors whose interests are engaged, but rather that these

processes work themselves out “behind the backs” of the actors.

We thus have a repertoire of explanations for misrepresentation – relating development

practitioner techniques and interests, to geopolitical interests, to anti-politics and

bureaucratisation. If the misrepresentation of the rural endures in twenty-first century practice

these competing explanations can be revisited and sources of resistance to learning or change

may be sought.

The three cases do not provide any direct links regarding the relationship between the failure

of intervention and the misrepresentation of context. While the misrepresentation appears to

be central to the failure of the two interventions in question, there is no easy counterfactual

which suggests that if reality could be truthfully represented interventions would then

succeed12

. On the contrary, a reading of the case studies suggests that better representations of

the situations in Thaba-Tseka and Magarini would have resulted in the projects not being

started rather than in them being completed successfully in anything resembling the form they

actually took. While truth may be the holy grail of the academic world, there may of course be

good strategic reasons in the world of development intervention to deploy partial truths and

untruths in order to achieve objectives. To conclude, these rural development interventions

failed strikingly, and they also misrepresented context strikingly. However, while the

misrepresentation of context contributed to the setting of unrealistic objectives, it did not

provide a conclusive explanation of failure.

1.3 Introducing the Case: Property Rights Interventions in Cambodia

This thesis is broadly concerned with the relationship between development interventions and

the lives and livelihoods of the people who are intended to benefit from them. It takes as its

departure points on the one hand my personal experiences of development interventions

failing to make a substantial difference in rural Cambodia, and on the other hand the trio of

academic studies of development practice and discourse in the 1990s which, taken together,

constituted a powerful argument for the importance of the relationship between development

failure and systematic mis-representation of context. In the light of these departure points, the

broader research interest can be expressed as an inquiry into whether rural development

interventions in the early twenty-first century fail, and if so, whether they fail in the same

ways and for the same reasons as interventions in the 1970s and 1980s. With regard to the

context which contemporary projects describe, do they (contra Thaba-Tseka, Magarini and

America‟s Egypt) recognise that rural people‟s livelihoods are: diverse and multiply-

integrated into wider economies and ecologies; partly conditioned by a dynamic history which

includes centuries of engagement with wider (global) economies; characterised by mobility

12

The recommendations provided by the authors suggest that no such easy counterfactual is available. Mitchell‟s

implicit call for „proper analysis‟ is not a recommendation for practitioners. Porter et al. recommend a less

control oriented practice that is more flexible and attuned to local circumstances, but warn that even with best

practice that problems embedded in conflicts of interest will not be readily amenable to outside intervention.

Ferguson recommended that practitioners engage politically, but his practitioners were academics rather than

development industry practitioners and he anticipated any difference made being made outside the realms of the

industry.

Page 32: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

14

and uncertainty; embedded in (more or less explicit) political struggles where their interests

are often in conflict with those of the State?

Bringing the question up to date also involves acknowledging that rural development

interventions in the early twenty-first century are set in a quite different policy context.

Whether or not development practice has developed, it has certainly changed. The earlier

studies I have referenced were focused on development interventions that exemplified

approaches in the 1970s and 1980s – mostly large area-based integrated rural development

projects. During the two decades between the closure of Thaba-Tseka and Magarini and the

commencement of work on this thesis in 2005 the pendulum of development policy had

swung dramatically both ways (see Chapter 2). Approaches intending to address basic needs

through State supported interventions were eschewed in favour of rolling back the State in a

process of structural adjustment intended to let markets do the work of development

unfettered by State interference. This turn to market, however, was superseded by an

institutional turn, which held that the State did have a key role in ensuring that the institutions

required for markets to do their work were in place (Fukuyama, 2004).

The mainstream in development policy during the 1990s was dominated by the so-called

Washington Consensus, within which legal property rights stood as the tenth of the ten points,

formulated as follows: “The legal system should provide secure property rights without

excessive costs, and make these available to the informal sector”, and were regarded by

Williamson (1993, p. 1333) as uncontroversial compared with some of the other points in the

„consensus‟. The harsher structural adjustment policies of downsized government,

deregulation, privatisation and liberation of trade attracted widespread criticism and failed to

demonstrate economic success (Jomo, 2005), and were succeeded in the mainstream by a

poverty reduction emphasis which arguably amounted to superficial rather than substantive

change (Craig & Porter, 2006; Porter & Craig, 2004). The project of „getting the institutions

right‟ survived the Washington consensus, and property rights continued to be key. According

to Chang (2006, p. 5) ―In the orthodox literature on institutions and development, property

rights are accorded the most important role‖. In this respect, then, to focus on property rights

interventions is to focus on a central and characteristic feature of the dominant thinking in

development policy in the last decade of the twentieth century and the first decade of the

twenty-first.

The focus on systematic land titling and community forestry in this thesis enables

consideration of examples of the two major types of property right intervention: supporting,

on the one hand, individualised property rights as land-titling emphasises the individual as an

economic actor and supports their integration into the formal economy as small capitalists,

prepared to borrow against and/or trade their assets. On the other hand are common property

rights, as community forestry, emphasises „community‟ as a source of local regulation and

moral values in the spaces evacuated by the rolled back state13

. Systematic land titling in

Cambodia is a government programme that has received financial and technical support from

the World Bank, the governments of Finland and Germany, and latterly the government of

Canada. It is anticipated that registering all land property in Cambodia will involve issuing

title to twelve million parcels of land. The project began in 2004 and by 2009 over a million

titles had been issued. Community forestry by contrast, has constituted a diverse collection of

projects and initiatives initially supported by international donors and NGOs in Cambodia. By

the time the government began to recognise the concept of community forestry in the 2002

Forestry Law, and then to pass a Community Forestry sub-decree in 2003, there were already

13

The process by which I arrived at property rights interventions in general and systematic land titling and

community forestry in particular will be described and explained in Chapter 3.

Page 33: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

15

over 200 community forestry projects in existence. By the completion of field work for this

project in early 2009, 18 of those projects had received recognition from the government and

had been authorised to proceed with a management plan.

The choice of Cambodia as a case study country rests first and foremost on my comparative

advantage in conducting research there, having lived there for ten years, and carried out two

or three research and evaluation consultancies per year there during the years from 2001,

when I left, and 2005 when I began the employment for this research. Cambodia presents a

particularly interesting case for students of development intervention. Prior to the fall of the

Berlin wall, most interventions in Cambodia had been motivated by geopolitical security

interests. This included the political isolation of the country during the 1980s, during which

time the United Nations continued to recognise the Khmer Rouge - responsible for the (auto-)

genocide of the 1975-9 period – as the rightful representatives of the Cambodian government.

The collapse of communism set in motion a process whereby elections were held and the

international actors who had been supporting an insurgency against the Cambodian

government could now redefine their role of one supporting development and democracy in

the country. This process was routinely described as a „peace process‟, although the

withdrawal of the Khmer Rouge from the elections meant that the United Nations‟

intervention during 1992-4 did not produce peace, but that rather guerrilla warfare continued

until the ruling elite in the Cambodian government finally completed deals with all of the

remaining Khmer Rouge leadership such that they defected and allied themselves to the

government.

The years of international isolation, meanwhile, meant that Cambodia had avoided the worse

consequences of debt and the ravages of structural adjustment which many of the world‟s

other poorest countries had undergone in their encounters with the development industry. This

meant that in some respects when Cambodia emerged as a host for development intervention

in the early 1990s the development industry arrived with a relatively clean slate. In another

respect, however, the development industry slate was far from clean. The first international

intervention was the United Nations‟ Transitional Authority in Cambodia (UNTAC).

Expensive, time-bound and with objectives that involved nothing less than taking temporary

control of the country, it proved itself capable only of completing tasks which did not involve

confronting elite power. The general population was educated in the principles and practice of

electoral democracy, the refugees were returned from the Thai border. However, UNTAC was

powerless first to either discipline the Khmer Rouge when they withdrew from the elections,

and second to ensure that the winners of the election could form a government. The beginning

of full-scale development assistance in Cambodia was therefore marked by this huge parable

which showed that whilst the high-spending international actors made much noise in the

public space, they could safely be waited out or ignored whilst the real political decisions and

negotiations occurred elsewhere (see Chapter 4 below).

1.4 Thesis Aim and Research Questions

As explained above, the broad area of interest for this study is the relationship between

development interventions and the livelihoods of poor people. Among the understandings that

inform the enquiry are a documented tendency for the development industry to systematically

misrepresent rural areas, and scepticism regarding the capacity of the industry to effectively

learn from experience. This interest and these understandings are applied to the case of

property rights interventions in Cambodia, yielding the following aim:

To describe and explain the relationship between property rights interventions and the

livelihoods of the rural poor in Cambodia.

Page 34: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

16

The property rights interventions selected were community forestry and systematic land titling

(see Chapter 3). Broadly, the approach to studying intervention has been to begin with rural

livelihoods, to set those livelihoods in the context of political economy, and finally to

investigate the impacts of implementation on livelihoods in the context of the political

economy. This three-step process was applied at both village and national scales. The

advantage of village level research was that it enabled a detailed, contextualised analysis of

real people‟s livelihoods. The advantage of national level research was that it enabled broader

trends to emerge, not least in terms of the geographical distribution of phenomena. The

relative advantages of the different scales for the research meant that the process led to

slightly different research questions for the respective scales:

Local Cases:

1. How do people in the village earn a living?

2. What factors constrain and enable villagers’ livelihoods, and what is the importance

of tenure security/insecurity in those livelihoods?

3. To what extent do tenure security interventions make a difference to rural tenure

security/insecurity and rural livelihoods? Why/why not?

National Case:

1. Where in rural Cambodia is tenure insecurity a problem? Why?

2. Where in Cambodia have tenure rights interventions been implemented? Why?

3. What is the relationship between the geography of tenure insecurity and the

geography of tenure security intervention?

A pair of analytical questions then connect these findings back to respectively the thesis aim

and the broader research interest:

1. What do these local and national cases contribute to understandings of the

relationship between rural livelihoods and property rights interventions in

Cambodia in the 2000s?

2. What does the case of property rights interventions in Cambodia in the 2000s

contribute to understandings of development industry interventions in rural areas of

the global South?

1.5 Other Contributions of the Thesis

This introduction has explained the ambition of the thesis to contribute to the general

literature on development studies and development practice, as well as the specific literature

on property rights interventions. Complementary to these contributions the thesis will also

contribute to literatures on Southeast Asian rural development, development geography and

livelihoods.

Within Southeast Asia studies Cambodia often remains as a geographical gap. Anthologies

frequently include chapters on all countries except Cambodia, and authors such as Rigg (e.g.

1997, 2001) who rely predominantly on detailed local case studies to build up a picture of

trends within the region, generally do so without the benefit of studies from Cambodia. The

only sustained studies of livelihoods in rural Cambodia have been based on fieldwork carried

out in the early 1960s (Ebihara, 1968)14

. Recent detailed case study work has either focused

on cultural issues (Zucker, 2007) or has been written up in ways that obscure rather than

14

New and forthcoming work by Katherine Brickell (e.g. 2008) may also contribute to understandings of

livelihoods in rural Cambodia, see http://www.gg.rhul.ac.uk/Brickell/publications.html

Page 35: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

17

highlight the specifics of place. This particularly applies to the study Moving out of Poverty?

(Fitzgerald & Sovannarith, 2007) conducted at the Cambodian policy research institute CDRI

as part of a multi-country World Bank research project under the leadership of Deepa

Narayan15

. The two village studies presented here will therefore contribute to filling that gap.

This thesis by applying an explicitly spatial analysis to development industry interventions

also makes a contribution to development geography as a sub-discipline. Currently,

development geographers are often prominent in development studies or, increasingly, in

political ecology. On the other hand, it is rare to find that something explicitly identified or

identifiable as development geography is being practiced. Building on work by Bebbington

(2001, 2003, 2004) this thesis will show that an opportunity is being missed. A critical

geography of development intervention geography can be a corrective to analyses which, by

avoiding crucial questions about where activities do and do not happen, facilitate depoliticised

framings of obviously political questions.

Finally, „livelihoods‟ have been a prominent object of enquiry within development studies

over the past couple of decades. This has often been as part of an attempt to ensure that the

situations of the poor are adequately apprehended in development analyses, and partly an

attempt to ensure that poor people‟s agency is acknowledged and they are not simply

portrayed as helpless victims of structural processes. In order to indicate that a balance

between structure and agency is at work livelihoods literature has used metaphors such as

pathways or trajectories to imply a process of limited agency. While instructive as metaphors,

the literature has not made progress in identifying what a particular pathway or trajectory

might look like and how different situations might structure (constrain and enable) agency. In

the process of researching chapter 5 of this thesis a trajectory of livelihoods shaped by

deforestation became apparent. Given that many interventions that respond to deforestation

tend to operate as though deforestation had never occurred, this could be a useful contribution.

1.6 Structure

Chapter 2 is organised into three sections each with a distinct purpose. Firstly a research

framework – termed a critical geography of development intervention – is defined featuring

concerns of place, space and travel. The spatial element of this framework is central as it

provides a theoretical perspective within which this thesis intends to make its principle

theoretical contribution. Secondly, in order to introduce theoretical positions that will inform

arguments in the thesis, the next section traces – very selectively – a development journey

from origins in the western development industry, via the host government development

partner/gatekeeper, to the livelihoods of the people who are intended to benefit from

intervention: in this case with Southeast Asia to the fore. Thirdly, and finally, the chapter

presents the theories which inform the property rights interventions – both common property

and individualised, private property – and discusses both their ideological underpinnings and

what is known about the conditions required for them to translate into effective policy

interventions.

15

Globally, MOPS uses nationally representative panel data sets supplemented by qualitative methods in order to

try and provide a picture of change, specifically, the „movement‟ of households either upwards or downwards

over the poverty line. Such a panel data set was not found to be readily available in Cambodia. However, CDRI

had conducted detailed empirical research in nine different villages intended to represent the so-called agro-

ecological zones of Cambodia. An attempt was therefore made to conduct a hybrid study which combined the

benefits of longtitudinal place-based study with the benefits of panel data. While there is some valuable material

in these studies, they tend generally to have failed to achieve either convincing representative statistics or

contextualised, grounded accounts of cause and effect to explain findings.

Page 36: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

18

Chapter 3 will explain and justify the methods chosen for the study. This includes the choice

to focus on national and village scales, and also the sequencing of the research whereby each

case study first concentrates on apprehending the context for interventions – livelihoods in

their political economy context (immanent development) - and after that on interventions

themselves (intentional development). The iterative process for selecting the case study

villages and interventions is described and the particular methods used in conducting the

national and village studies are also described and explained.

Chapter 4 is a national level case study of property rights interventions in Cambodia, which

is fundamentally spatial. It presents a geography of tenure insecurity explaining where tenure

insecurity is found in Cambodia, and what factors have caused it. It overlays this with a

geography of systematic land titling and community forestry in Cambodia which describes

and explains the location of these purported solutions to tenure security issues in relation to

the location of the problem. The chapters that follow are then accounts of how intervention

has unfolded in two detailed, place-based case studies.

Chapter 5 is a case study of a village I call Bey. It charts the factors which have determined

the livelihood trajectories of villagers, and explains them in terms of the ongoing deforestation

in the region. It then describes the way that community forestry travelled to Bey, and what

impact it had on the lives and livelihoods of villagers there. Chapter 6 is likewise a study of

village livelihoods, this time in a village I call Buon, a far more tranquil village both because

there was not the contestation and uncertainty that was experienced in Bey during the study

period, and also because so much of Buon‟s economic activity was located away from the

village. The development intervention in Buon was the national programme of systematic

land titling. Again, its journey to the village and its impacts on local lives and livelihoods are

described and explained, and compared with the representations put forward in project

literature.

Chapter 7 summarises the findings of the thesis and discusses their implications for property

rights interventions in Cambodia, and more broadly for development industry interventions in

general. The main finding of the thesis is the way in which the development interventions in

these cases tend to be located away from the problems they are scheduled to address. Land

tenure is located away from tenure insecurity, whilst community forestry is located in places

where the forest has already been degraded. These geographies of evasion are theorised as

being a consequence of overreach by the development industry and resistance by the host

nation government. The thesis concludes with some general points on the policy implications

of the study, as well as deriving a research framework based on the geographies of evasion

hypothesis, and some more specific ideas on future research projects within that framework.

Page 37: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

19

2 A Critical Geography of Development Intervention

2.1 Introduction – Normative Beginnings/Assumptions

Gillian Hart (2001, 2010) has used a dichotomised view of the development concept, which

she contracts to D/development.

―Big D‖ Development I define as the multiply scaled projects of intervention in the ―Third

World‖ that emerged in the context of decolonization struggles and the Cold War. ―Little d‖

development refers to the development of capitalism as geographically uneven but spatially

interconnected processes of creation and destruction, dialectically interconnected with

discourses and practices of Development (Hart, 2010, p. 119).

There are, as we shall shortly see, other dichotomised views of development as a concept

which have some similarities to this one, as well as some significant differences. From the

point of view of this thesis, what appears to be missing in the D/development description is

something of the moral impulse for justice that is for many the first engagement with, and the

ultimate reference point for discussions of Development, or (in the more concrete term which

I have preferred in this thesis) the development industry.

The first chapter of this thesis framed a concern with development industry failure in terms of

case studies which have anatomised and attempted to explain failure. This was complemented

with my own personal encounters with rural development initiatives in Cambodia which have,

at the level of the household and the village, been almost without exception, of peripheral

significance to the lives and livelihoods of villagers. In the introduction to this chapter, which

concerns, in various ways, the theoretical departure points for the thesis, I will go a little

further back in my personal history in order again to supplement the points I am making in

relation to the literature.

As a youth in the late 1970s and early 1980s I became aware, mainly via television news, of

people dying of hunger and hunger-related diseases. As I tried to make sense of the world and

of what moral rules there were or should be, these avoidable deaths became a key reference

point. One possibility, I felt, was that remoteness made understanding difficult. We were all

morally complicit in those deaths, but that perhaps the imaginative feat required to understand

them was too great. In which case the project that was required in order to prevent people

dying in this way, and therefore to restore some sort of decent moral order to the world, was

one of communication. If people in Britain could more fully understand, could imagine, what

it meant to starve, or to watch your children starve, these deaths would be stopped. We, the

decent people of England would not allow them. At other times I felt the opposite was the

case: even if the people in the next town or village were starving, we would find a way of

rationalising it as being unavoidable or their fault and would not lend a hand.

While I tried to learn more and to think about what could and should be done, and to decide

how I should live my life, there was also the short term imperative. What could I do now?

How could I demonstrate to someone who had watched their children or parents starve, whilst

I lived a life of comfort, that I had at least done something; had displayed some shred of

Page 38: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

20

humanity in the face of horror and injustice. And that was where I encountered „development‟

for the first time.

The people who offered a means to help were organisations like Oxfam, which were called

development agencies. The part of government that took a portion of the taxes that my parents

paid in order to respond to these injustices was the Overseas Development Administration.

Development was, in the beginning, in my first encounter with it, a response to poverty and

injustice. It was, to my mind, the organisational response to the impulse from people like me

dotted around the cities, towns and countryside of Britain to do something about people dying

unnecessarily.

Serving this demand, a part of what Tania Murray Li (2007) refers to as “the will to improve”,

is still to my mind the ultimate rationalisation and the legitimate mandate for the development

industry. On the other hand, as Hart‟s conceptualisation makes clear, D/development is much

more and much different to the impulse for altruism or justice, much more and different to a

simple will to improve. How the development industry should fulfil its mandate is of course a

highly contested question. However, the normative underpinning for this thesis is that the

development industry should deliver improvement, or at least contribute convincingly to the

possibility of improvement.

My expectations of what development might do were perhaps not wholly unrealistic. A

teenager wanting to support Oxfam soon heard (or read in the newspapers) that the people

who work in the Oxfam shops took the best clothes for themselves, or that half of the money

that was supposed to go to the poor went towards salaries and administration. My response

was that if the only way that I could send ten pence to someone in miserable circumstances

was to pay a pound to a development agency, then that was good value for money.

The normative concern of this thesis is with the conservation or rehabilitation of the will to

improve within D/development. Within this, the assumption is that if there is to be a

development industry, then it should provide a credible organisational mechanism for people

prepared to spend a pound of money to give ten pence worth of support to people in desperate

circumstances.

There is, of course, nothing remarkable about these positions. After the “nothing can be done”

turn of the 1990s, and an abundance of calls for development to be abandoned as a concept

and a project (Escobar, 1995; W. Sachs, 1992), much academic literature seems to be

returning to a “something should be done” position. A general repositioning and convergence

„beyond impasse‟ has been reviewed by Simon (2007) and argued through by Corbridge

(2007) who noted that the development industry was not going anywhere, and that whilst a

perfect world may not be realised, improvement was worth striving for. While normative

questions of what the development industry should do, motivate this study, much of its

concern will relate to what the industry can (and cannot) do. Murray Li, who is possibly

askance the current convergence, argues thus:

Transnational agencies are not in a position to trigger revolutions or change regimes. If they

tried to do these things, they would be expelled. They would also alienate the social

movements and political parties who see such struggles as their affair. This is a crucial

paradox: the goal of transnational development agencies is poverty reduction, yet major

processes of poverty production escape their grasp (Li, 2010, pp. 233-234).

This chapter is organised into three sections, each of which fulfils distinct purposes in the

scheme of the thesis. Section 2.2 presents a framework, which I term „critical geography of

development intervention‟ which is partly an extension of proposals that have been made by

Bebbington for a theoretical framework for development geographers. Section 2.3 takes a

Page 39: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

21

conceptualisation of development as a journey from 2.2 and uses this to introduce

perspectives from existing theoretical and empirical literature that inform the arguments made

in the course of the thesis. Section 2.4 focuses on property rights interventions by describing

the theoretical foundations for the policy interventions introduced in this study, discussing the

critical literature in relation to those theoretical foundations, and establishing from a policy

point of view what is known about the conditions and prospects for successful interventions

based on such theories.

2.2 A Critical Geography of Development Intervention

This thesis is concerned with the relationship between development industry interventions and

the livelihoods of the people whom they are intended to serve. As I have just explained, this is

not a neutral, detached concern, but is rather grounded in the proposition that the development

industry should serve as a bridge between the altruistic impulses of people who have more

than enough to support their material needs, and other people in other places who do not.

My approach to apprehending this relationship I will call “critical geography of development

intervention”. Critical here is to indicate scepticism in relation to development. So whilst I

start from the position that the development industry should be an organisational response to

altruistic impulses for justice, I do not take it for granted that the development industry is such

a response. Rather, I assume that the sorts of failure documented in the 1990s case studies in

Chapter 1 should alert us to the ways in which the development industry might not be what it

should be.

Three components comprise this critical geography of development intervention. First,

contextualised understandings of place provide an analytical lens through which to view the

general claims of development theory and policy. Second, studies of the spatial distribution of

development interventions provide understandings about the locations and circumstances in

which the development industry might or might not engage with poverty. Third, the idea of

development interventions as journeys is used to unpack the contingencies and choices that

shape those spatial distributions.

2.2.1 Place-based studies and policy simplifications

The reason I value The Anti-Politics Machine discussed in Chapter One is not primarily its

theoretical discussions or its contribution to “Anti-development” or “Post-development” (cf.

Simon, 2007, p. 205), but rather for the powerful empirical case that it presents. The project in

Lesotho managed to represent and engage the population as though they were essentially rural

livestock farmers. Migrant labour dominated the local economy, and was arguably the

dominant fact in what constituted Lesotho as a country, yet the project pushed this to the side

of its vision. As a result, the project managed to utterly misapprehend local realities: increased

selling livestock was not indicative of improved production, but was rather indicative of

economic crisis as the savings and status accumulated in the animals were liquidated to meet

short-term needs. And the enigma at the heart of the case was that the people working on the

project were highly-educated, intelligent and principled. Yet somehow the dynamics of

development practice had led them to design and implement a project so misconceived that it

could only fail.

Part of what Ferguson‟s case convincingly showed was the way that the development industry

in that case was so committed to a particular way of interpreting situations that rather than

engage with reality, it engaged with a simplified and distorted version of reality. The idea of

policy as simplification and distortion will be a theme encountered in relation to the work of

various leading development thinkers in this chapter (e.g. Li, 2002; Mosse, 2005; Ostrom,

Page 40: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

22

1990). Piers Blaikie (2006), writing on community based natural resource management

(CBNRM) as it is practiced globally, reflected on epistemological tensions when studying

development policies and practice. On the one hand there is a sense that development theory

and development policy can and should be taken at face value:

Better theory will then appeal to rational policy makers, who change or adapt the existing

policy in directions suggested by the theory (Blaikie, 2006, p. 1947).

On the other hand, that policy should not be taken seriously in its own terms, but rather that it

is rhetoric deployed in a context of competing ideas and interests and therefore should be

subject to “a more discursive and political approach” (Blaikie, 2006, p. 1947).

Analyses of discourse and of competing interests will indeed be of service when attempting to

analyse why an intervention misrepresents its context. However, in order to understand

whether and how situations might be misrepresented, contextualised understandings of place

are key.

A good empirical case study of development practice, such as those encountered in Chapter 1

(Ferguson, 1994; Porter et al., 1991), might demonstrate how a development intervention

(mis)represents its context, and how that contributes to intended and unintended effects. A

good theory of development practice, meanwhile, will provide an explanation of why the

policy is failing to engage the situation it claims to address. Many of the methods for

understanding failure will include the “more discursive and political approach” (Blaikie,

2006, p. 1947), but the ultimate intention is to contribute theory that can be of service to

“rational policy makers who change or adapt the existing policy in directions suggested by

the theory” (Blaikie, 2006, p. 1947).

The strengths and limitations of case studies as research methods, and how I have conducted

contextualised studies of place in this thesis is described in Chapter 3. Using contextualised

understandings of local reality in order to critique the generalised abstractions of theory and

policy, whilst not untypical of work by geographers, is certainly not unique to geography

either. Studying the spatial distribution of interventions, on the other hand, is very much at the

heart of the discipline; in this thesis it will be the analysis of the distribution of interventions

that will enable discussions to go beyond the specific local cases and to make a theoretical

contribution to discussions of development industry practice and effects.

2.2.2 Spatial Distribution: Mapping Development Interventions

Reviewing work by development geographers at the outset of this project, I found it difficult

to identify a sub-discipline of development geography. Some authors do not recognise the

term at all. There is, for example, no entry for „development geography‟ in the 907 pages of

the Dictionary of Human Geography (R J Johnston, Gregory, Pratt, & Watts, 2000), nor is

there even any mention of „development geography‟ in the standard textbook „Geographies of

Development‟ (Potter, Binns, Elliott, & Smith, 1999).

Amongst the authors who would recognise a distinct sub-discipline called „development

geography‟ various definitions fit into two categories. The first defines a sub-discipline which

focuses on the uneven spread of capitalism across physical space, as for example Johnston

(1997, pp. 231-237) reviewed within Anglo-American geography. The second defines a field

which studies the people and places of „the developing world‟ (e.g. Hodder, 2000, p. 5) and

therefore as a successor to or descendent of „tropical geography‟ (Power & Sidaway, 2004).

When geographers have addressed the subject of development, and especially development

Page 41: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

23

intervention, their contributions have barely been distinguishable from those of non-

geographers.16

The article by Simon cited above is a case in point. He mentions in passing the association of

the discipline of geography with “nineteenth- and twentieth-century imperial exploitation”

(Simon, 2007, p. 208) and goes on to suggest that if geography has been able to rehabilitate

itself, then development studies should too (Simon, 2007, p. 215). Geography does not seem

to be the lens through which he sees development; rather it seems to exist as a separate field

with which comparisons may be drawn. Other development geographers clearly tackled issues

that were directly relevant to my themes (Corbridge, 2007; Hart, 2001; Kumar & Corbridge,

2002 for example), but it was difficult to discern geography in these contributions.

Bebbington made some similar observations in an article (Bebbington, 2003) where he argued

that development geographers had – more or less deliberately – become invisible in

development studies, but that the core concerns of geography “in its simple concern for

variation across space, and linkages among places” should be more central in the analytical

concerns of development studies (Bebbington, 2003, p. 298). That article was one of a series

of three where Bebbington proposed a theoretical framework for “a geography of

development” (Bebbington, 2000) or a “geography of development intervention”(Bebbington,

2004). He suggested that development geography‟s particular role might involve

dichotomising development and „mapping‟ the two separate parts onto each other:

Cowen and Shenton (1996) have argued that one of the ―confusions, common throughout

the development literature, is between development as an immanent and unintentional

process, as in, for example, the ‗development of capitalism‘ and development as an

intentional activity‖. The suggestion here is that mapping the latter onto the former, and

tracing the mutually constitutive interactions between the two, is critical to a geography of

development (Bebbington, 2000, p. 515).

This suggestion – mapping intentional development onto immanent and analysing the

interactions between the two17

, forms the framework for the spatial component of my critical

geography of development intervention. However, the „confusions‟ about immanent and

intentional require some attention.

Bebbington oscillates between the concept of intentional/immanent development (Cowen &

Shenton, 1996) and Hart‟s (2001) D/development. Hart sees the value of a third dichotomy,

namely that of Karl Polanyi. For Polanyi, though, capitalist development was far from

immanent or unintentional. Rather, the project to dis-embed the market from social relations

and to commodify land, labour and money (i.e. market liberalism) was very much a planned

intervention, whilst the reaction by society to re-embed the market in its social context, was

the more spontaneous element of the double movement which he described as being integral

to capitalist development (Block, 2001, p. 10; Polanyi, 2001, p. 141).

Bebbington‟s compromise was to retain the notion of immanent and intentional development,

but modify Cowen and Shenton‟s concepts by acknowledging that „immanent‟ development

too could be intentional in character18

. I too use the terms immanent and intentional

16

See for example the contributions in Schuurman (1993) This includes contributions from both geographers

and sociologists but little in the content would lead a reader to characterise any particular writer as one or the

other. 17

Unlike Bebbington, I do not assume that the two are „mutually constitutive‟. 18

While Cowen and Shenton‟s conception of historical development as immanent is difficult, it is otherwise

similar to the idea of the uneven contractions and expansions of capitalism that Hart and Bebbington use, with

the stress upon capitalist progress as inherently destructive and disordering, as it generates unemployment, social

Page 42: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

24

development in this thesis, but define them slightly differently, and in terms that keep the

struggles and dynamics implicit in Hart‟s and Polanyi‟s concepts in play.

In this thesis intentional and immanent development are defined in terms of the actor which is

carrying out the intervention. Thus, for the intervening agency, its own intervention is an

instance of intentional development. The context into which the intervention is inserted is one

of immanent development in the sense that the context is one with its own pre-existing

dynamics. What that „immanent‟ development consists of is the set of ongoing struggles that

constitute a political economy or a political ecology. This can be conceptualised as a struggle

between Hart‟s Development and development, or, as in Polanyi, between the disembedding

and re-embedding tendencies within capitalism19

.

Cast in a Polanyian frame it is clear of course that the development industry can be found on

both sides of the internal contradictions of capitalism. In some cases the development industry

actors work to liberate capital, whilst in others they seek its re-embedding in society.

Bebbington‟s proposition for a geography of development intervention provides a theoretical

perspective (Bernard, 2002, p. 75): the idea that mapping an intervention in a territory, and

mapping key features of the political economy that the intervention seeks to address onto the

same territory will yield insights into how the intervention and the political economy are

constituted. It does not in itself provide a body of existing theory. Bebbington himself has

used his framework on just one occasion, when looking at the operations of Dutch NGOs in

Peru and Bolivia. Bebbington argued that studies of the geography of intervention should take

into account the geography of aid chains and transnational networks associated with those aid

chains. In this he included factors such as the historical engagements of funders, and donor-

funded activities, especially centralised training courses. The NGOs he studied were oriented

towards reducing poverty. However, when he mapped their activities onto poverty in the two

countries, he found that the NGOs were not active in the poorest regions. This Bebbington

ascribed to the „structuring‟ of their geographies by earlier engagements. To some extent he

found that these older structural factors were being replaced as an indirect result of Dutch

being targeted on poverty grounds towards Africa and South Asia rather than Latin America.

This had led to NGOs increasingly seeking financing by getting contracts from multilaterally

or bilaterally financed government programmes, which had their own thematic and

geographical path dependencies (Bebbington, 2004, p. 737). While these findings both

explain a particular case and might be used to predict and explain other cases they are

certainly nothing that Bebbington claims as worthy of being theory in geographies of

development intervention. The intention in this thesis was that by working inductively within

the theoretical framework of geographies of development intervention it might be possible to

generate some hypotheses or theories that constituted an early contribution towards a body of

theory of geographies of development intervention, which would also respond to the research

interest that motivated the thesis, namely the nature of the relationship between development

interventions and the livelihoods of the people that they are intended to assist.

misery and conflicts, which require some form of ordering, namely „intentional development‟. Intentional

development embodies a range of philosophies and programmes to counter the disordering effects of progress.

Crucially, philosophies of development become doctrines of development for Cowen and Shenton when they are

adopted by states. Cowen and Shenton are dismissive of the claims of contemporary „alternative development‟

theories as doctrines precisely because they are not connected to a state apparatus that might realistically enforce

them.

19 Another similar dichotomy also partly inspired by Polanyi, is Craig and Porter‟s liberal versus territorial

modes of governance (2006, p. 23).

Page 43: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

25

2.2.3 Development Interventions as Travel

The final component of my critical geography of development intervention framework is the

conceptualisation of development interventions as travel. The main analytical purpose here is

to unpack the histories of interventions. A journey is, of necessity, through time and space. By

demanding some attention to the question of where an intervention comes from one starts to

attend to the sets of relationships and events that constituted it. In our introduction, for

example, the Magarini project (Porter et al., 1991) was traced back to its Australian origins in

various ways which illuminated the question about why there was an Australian project in

Kenya (because Australia wanted to counter the negative impacts its „white Australia‟

reputation was having on its trade relations in the Pacific), why the project was located where

it was (because suggestions from Australian consultants for a programme which would

generate entitlements for communities nationwide and threaten interests of the clients of the

ruling elite were rejected by the Kenyan government), and why the project failed (similar

projects in similar conditions in Australia had met the same fate).

Two quite different texts in my reading have particularly influenced my understanding of the

implications of development as travel: Korten‟s (1982), discussions of successful projects in

Asia, and Craig‟s (1997) account of the travels of anti-biotic pills to Vietnam.

In the 1970s David Korten had been involved in USAID supported development programmes

in Asia. In 1982 he wrote an article which tried to distil lessons from five successful

programmes. These were not all complete or permanent successes, and they had quite

different scopes of operation (family planning in Thailand, dairy cooperatives in India,

irrigation management in Philippines, community development movements in Bangladesh and

Sri Lanka). What Korten distilled from these cases, however, was a three-phase evolutionary

process. Each phase represented about 5-7 years of learning, leading him to call this a

“learning process approach”. The first phase was “learning to be effective”. During this phase

an intervention was trialled, errors were corrected, resistance was overcome and eventually

interventions became established as effective in their initial locations. The second phase was

“learning to be efficient”, where having become effective, the programme then found ways to

achieve that operate at reduced costs. This included some compromises in terms of

effectiveness. The third phase was “learning to expand”, whereby the programme found ways

to operate at a larger scale, which included some compromises in terms of effectiveness and

efficiency.

Often cited in the late 1980s and early 1990s the Learning Process Approach has not made a

lasting imprint on development thinking. Neither has it been empirically tested and developed

such as to become a more convincing theory for explaining successful dissemination of

improvement projects. The phrase „learning process‟ is encountered often enough, but usually

as code for a form of trial-and-error learning by doing rather than a structured diffusion of a

newly-introduced policy or practice.

What it does offer, however, is a counter to the proposition that organisations and

programmes that make a difference can be introduced according to a detailed pre-determined

plan. It also suggests a form of evolution that originates in one place within the area of

intervention. So an idea for a project may have been tested or developed in Nepalese

mountains, Peruvian slums, or North American universities. However, if it is to work in a new

territory, it might need to be re-establish itself in situ. The managerial implication is first of

all, that interventions should work somewhere in a territory before attempts are made to make

them work everywhere. Secondly, that considerable time and flexibility might be required in

order to enable a successful intervention to spread successfully.

Page 44: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

26

While Korten provided some insights into the organisational difficulties of producing

effective, efficient interventions at a large scale, Craig‟s (1997) focus was on the difficulties

inherent in transplanting things and concepts one from context to another. It is well-known

that the promotion of antibiotic use is challenging because the pills only work if they are taken

in the correct doses for the correct period of time. Craig looked at the travels of antibiotics to

Vietnam in terms of travelling rationalities. In other words, the introduction of antibiotics

required that both the pill and the rationale concerning its use needed to travel. What Craig

found, of course, was that the pills travelled rather more easily than the ideas. Often when the

pills arrived somewhere, in a pharmacy or a family home, they were not accompanied by the

rationales that had informed their design. Instead, other ideas about what medicine was and

how it should be used which were already circulating locally attached themselves to the pills

and determined how they were used. This serves as an example and as a metaphor for what

can happen when new ideas are introduced. The place to which they are introduced will never

be „empty‟ and simply waiting to receive new ideas. Rather there will already be ideas and

explanations circulating and competing. Some parts of an intervention may travel as easily

and as successfully as small white pills, but other parts may not travel well at all and be

crowded out by local ideas and local agendas.

In this thesis, there will not be a case study of the journey of a particular idea or person.

Rather the concept of interventions as journeys will be used to inform analysis, for example

showing how an edict from the Prime Minister is transformed en route to the village, or

looking at the role of the national government as gatekeeper.

2.2.4 Critical Geography of Development Intervention Recapitulated

To conclude, the conceptual framework for this thesis is one which adopts a critical, or

sceptical approach to generalising claims of theory and policy that inform intervention. It

seeks evidence of the mechanisms that underpin these general claims by means of an analysis

of processes in particular places. This is seen as vital given the level of misrepresentation

exemplified in the policy narratives of the 1990s case studies which provided the departure

point in the introduction to this thesis. A second component is an attention to the spatial

distribution of interventions. This is conceptualised as mapping the intervention (intentional

development) onto key features of the political economy/ecology (immanent development)

which it seeks to intervene in. Complementary to the notion of spatial distribution is the

notion of development as travel. Thus, rather than seeing an intervention in space as

accomplished fact, it is seen as the result of a series of journeys which are influenced by

interests and discourses in play at their origins, by the various gatekeepers who might obstruct

or facilitate the journey, as well as by the conditions in the final destination. It is this third

conception, of development as journey, which is used to structure the following section which

presents key elements of the literature on development interventions and their contexts which

will inform the analysis of property rights interventions in Cambodia.

2.3 Fraught Journeys: from Western Origins to Southeast Asian Landscapes

If development geography is the nascent theoretical field to which this thesis has ambitions to

contribute theory, other theories and empirical work contribute to understanding the context

for the study. The general research interest motivating this thesis is in Western development

interventions and their relations to the rural people who are intended to benefit from them.

These interventions involve journeys (metaphoric and actual) from western countries to

landscapes in the global South. In this section I will highlight three stages on this journey and

look at particular theoretical perspectives that can inform our understanding of them. These

Page 45: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

27

are highly selective samplings from much wider reading, made with particular reference to

their relevance to the case studies and arguments that follow.

I will first consider the origins of the journey in the western development industry, where

attention will be given to the ever-expanding nature of the development policy agenda, and

also to the incentives which structure the development industry. I will then consider a key

moment on the journey, namely the engagement with the host country government

characterised as both gatekeeper and development partner. Here I will briefly discuss host

country governments‟ relationships to formal and informal economies via theories of neo-

patrimonialism, shadow states and the „Asian Values‟ developmentalist state. Thirdly, and

finally, I will look at the idea of livelihoods, and more particularly at attempts to understand

rural livelihoods in Southeast Asia both in terms of more traditional agriculture-centred

agrarian transition debates and alternative de-agrarianisation perspectives which suggest that

agriculture and agricultural land may no longer be the central issues in rural change.

2.3.1 The Western Development Industry

2.3.1.1 Policy Trajectories and Industry Trajectories

Development policy is not drafted in isolation from other policies20

. A global geography of

development intervention (see 2.2.2 above) would show that a spatial distribution of

assistance where Afghanistan, Iraq and Pakistan went from receiving 2% of all aid in 2000 to

26% of all aid in 2005, while less than half of all aid provided by the main donors is

channelled to the 63 poorest countries in the world where the majority of poor people live

(Riddell, 2009, pp. 66-67). The politics of security and trade agendas clearly have

implications for how development is perceived and engaged21

. Nevertheless, the point I wish

to emphasize here relates to the policies articulated within the development industry and its

tendency to overreach. By overreach here I mean a tendency to set itself tasks which are

beyond it capacity to deliver. What Porter et al. (1991) noted as „control orientation‟ in

Magarini in the introduction to this thesis has remained characteristic of development industry

responses to difficulty and failure at all scales over recent decades. Each failure has led to a

widening of the agenda and an attempt to control more factors. Sectoral project interventions

did not address poverty fully, so multi-sectoral integrated rural development projects were

attempted. It no longer became sufficient to support projects, so programmes were supported

instead. Even where objectives were somewhat narrow, as Mosse has noted, policy has

attempted to control more and more factors:

...aid policy has become more managerial. Its ends – the quantified reduction of poverty or ill

health – have narrowed, but its means have diversified to the management of more and more:

financial and political systems and civil society (Mosse, 2005, p. 237).

20

Craig and Porter put Truman‟s famous “Point 4”, usually taken as heralding the beginning of modern

development assistance in the context of the security agenda which shaped the Truman Doctrine (Craig & Porter,

2006, pp. 46-49). 21

In Cambodia there is currently international criticism of the Cambodian judges at the joint Cambodian-

International court to prosecute senior leaders of the Khmer Rouge for genocide. These judges are held to be

susceptible to political influence. There was, meanwhile, no call for such a trial from the international

community for the first decade after the end of the Khmer Rouge rule. That was because the UN, mainly for

reasons of US-China relations, chose to continue to recognize the Khmer Rouge in exile as the legitimate (sole,

then joint) government of Cambodia. In this context, one might expect some scepticism from Cambodians with

regard to the idea that the international human rights agenda is universal, rather than one that while universal in

name is only deployed as and when other political contingencies suit.

Page 46: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

28

Addressing needs was no longer sufficient, so the agenda broadened and development policy

attempted to address people‟s rights and entitlements. As delivery of services did not suffice,

the agenda broadened to include democracy and governance. The advent of Poverty

Reduction Strategy Papers saw the development industry attempting to discipline the whole of

the government‟s policy and budgeting process, with every decision and every plan to be

related to „poverty reduction‟ (Biddulph, 2001b). Merilee Grindle (2004) comparing the scope

of successive World Development Reports from 1997 to 2002 demonstrated how, even in

relation to the emerging governance agenda, the list of items to address (factors to control)

expanded rapidly.

The criticism of control orientation that was central to Porter et al.‟s conclusions at Magarini

was based on the fact that, for a variety of reasons documented in their case, events in and

around the project area were clearly beyond the capacity of the Australians to control. The

attempt to control these factors was “futile because increased control-orientation leads

inevitably to a denial of reality and greater not less uncertainty” (Porter et al., 1991, p. 212)

Tania Murray Li also saw futility in relation to a development industry agenda, particularly

where it was expanded to issues which challenged elite interests (Li, 2007, p. 4), a point

which she has expanded more generally to attempts by international development agencies to

attempt to support substantive political change in host countries (Li, 2010, pp. 233-234 cited

in the introduction to this chapter). While expanded international agendas may have limited

capacity to achieve substantial change, they have developed a track record for achieving

facades of change.

Poverty reduction strategy papers (PRSP) have been written in countries around the world,

supposedly nationally-owned, but often repeating verbatim the guidelines from the World

Bank‟s four-volume Aide Memoire (Biddulph, 2001b; Porter & Craig, 2003). As a result,

documents that pretend to be centre-pieces of national government policy are in fact little

more than side-effects of the insistent need for donors to have the sense that all elements of

budgeting, planning and execution of national development policy are under (their) control.

One can only imagine the scorn that this would provoke from Cowen and Shenton (1996)

given their conclusion that doctrines of development could only be taken seriously to the

extent that they were serious state projects. I return shortly (2.3.2.2 below) to a consideration

of how to apprehend and conceptualise government agendas that are developed behind the

ventriloquised facade of internationally authored „national‟ „policy‟.

One consequence of these expanding agendas has been strands of academic analysis which no

longer take development industry policies seriously (cf. Blaikie 2006, p.1947 cited above).

Pieterse‟s (2009, p. 33) tone is one of sceptical disdain:

The development industry is, in no small measure, a rhetorical industry, an ideological

performance in which discourse production, paradigm maintenance and tweaking the

perception of receding horizons are the actual achievement.

Mosse, on the other hand, while making similar points about development practice

reproducing rather than implementing policy, and referring to policy machinery that

“fabricates its separation from political economy” also finds reasons for optimism in this

apparent failure:

An implication of the privileging of policy over practice and the limited scope for control in

development is the autonomy that subordinates in development‘s chain of organisation

(whether field staff, agency mangers or others) can create for themselves and their fields of

action. In de Certeau‘s terms they consent to development models while making of them

something different, escaping the power of the dominant order without leaving it, using their

Page 47: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

29

tactics to contend with the strategies of consultants and donor advisers (1984: xviii). In short,

policy is co-opted from below (Mosse, 2005, p. 239).

The idea that even if the goals inscribed in development policies and project documents are

not realised, that the interventions might nevertheless create space for resourceful agents to

make something worthwhile out of them is an important one, and one which we will return to

reflect on in the light of the cases in this study.

While the western development industry has generated ever broader, more all-encompassing

policy agendas for itself, its position has become questioned, not because of internal

reflections on the problems of overreach, but rather because of the growing awareness that

there are other more important sources of both assistance and investment than the western

development industry. Pieterse (2009, p. 40), has argued that “the development industry is not

as important as it thinks” by noting that, for example, remittances from migrants who have

left countries in the global South and send money back constitute a larger overall financial

transfer than development assistance. This is in the context of an essay where he tries to

discern directions for development in the 21st Century. Here of course the key contextual

factor is the crisis in US capitalism where the policies of deregulation that have been

promoted by the development industry are seen to be the very policies that have propelled the

United States into crisis and debt (Hart, 2010). Whether in the search for sources of

investment, or in the search for policies that might support stability and growth, there is a shift

in progress which Pieterse summarised as “looking east”. The current historical juncture

might, of course be one where the development industry becomes even more thoroughly (and

perhaps more explicitly) re-embedded in donors‟ self-interested security and trade agendas, as

evidenced by Hilary Clinton‟s framings of „smart power‟ with „defense, diplomacy and

development‟ in harness (Hart, 2010, p. 18). However, it might also be one where the

possibility to open development industry eyes to its own limitations, and to coax, goad or

satirise it out of overreach are more promising than they have been for some time.

2.3.1.2 Incentives in the Development Industry

More or less explicit (and more or less central to the analyses of failure and misrepresentation)

in the Thaba-Tseka and Magarini case studies in the introduction was the sense that

development industry actors were responding to powerful incentives. The framers of Thaba-

Tseka needed to represent rural Lesotho as isolated, rural and as in control of its own

economic destiny in order to make it amenable to the sort of projects that the Canadians and

the World Bank could provide (Ferguson, 1994). The various missions in Kenya needed to

suggest that water could be found, and that the internal rate of return for the project would be

positive, in order to keep the intervention alive (Porter et al., 1991).

A brief look at work from institutional economics provides insights into the reasons why the

interests of the poor might not always come first even in an industry whose work is explicitly

framed in terms of poverty reduction. This work tends to take the organisational objectives of

development organisations at face value (i.e. does not concern itself with the possible effects

of parallel security and trade agendas, or of the effects of shifting economic trends), but

instead to look at the incentive structures within organisations.

Institutional economics is attentive to issues of information and transaction costs. In the

context of the development industry this orients attention towards the distance between the

people who are supposed to benefit from development interventions and the people who pay

for them:

This geographical and political separation between beneficiaries and taxpayers blocks the

normal performance feedback process: beneficiaries may be able to observe performance but

Page 48: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

30

cannot modulate payments (rewards to the agents) in function of performance (Martens,

2002a, p. 14).

The link postulated to repair this „broken feedback loop‟ is project evaluation. However,

evaluation is subject to incentives, and, Martens argues, the conflicting agendas of taxpayers

and suppliers of development which create the climate for the evaluation, which will

invariably be handled by the aid agency, with the consequence that “evaluation will be

manipulated in function of these interests” (Martens, 2002a, p. 27).

Generally, the studies by Martens et al. (2002) tended to find strong incentives for agencies to

concentrate effort on financial reporting and input reporting, rather than the less tangible and

more risky reporting of results or outcomes22

. Interestingly, one of the policy conclusions that

Martens (2002b, p. 187) drew was that sub-contracting to interest groups whose interests

coincided with the beneficiaries and with the project orientation would be a way of avoiding

some of the problems of broken feedback and perverse incentives. He particularly named

NGOs in this regard, though as we will see, the incentive structures facing NGOs and those

facing small private commercial companies might not differ greatly.

Ostrom et al., similarly, conducted „incentive studies‟ which looked at the factors affecting the

behaviour of both staff and consultants employed by the Swedish International Development

Cooperation Agency, Sida. They found that the relatively rapid rotation of staff, on average

four years per posting, and the lack of relationship between performance of past projects and

future career prospects, meant that staff had few incentives to learn about the sustainability of

projects. With respect to contracting companies, they found that these companies were

strongly motivated by a desire for long-term relationships with Sida. This led them to try and

maximise their efforts towards tasks which they felt would please Sida, which often included

concentrating control in their own hands, rather than taking the more risky option of ceding

more control to intended beneficiaries. (Ostrom, Gibson, Shivakumar, & Andersson, 2002, pp.

xxi-xxvi).

In short, a brief encounter with institutional economics analyses of the development industry

suggests that the structure of incentives in the industry encourages the reporting of success

more than it does the achievement of it. Furthermore, the strong incentive to report success

tends to focus attention on indicators that are both countable and under agency control.

Money out of the door, inputs purchased and direct outputs may be expected to at the

forefront of agency considerations.

To summarise the first of these three steps in the journey, namely its western origins, the

development industry, with demand and supply located in the west, and embedded in western

political interests, is susceptible to policy overreach. Its successes may be imagined as being

in spite of rather than because of the structure of incentives within the industry: attention is

focused on short term, easily measurable indicators with strong incentives to decouple these

from the contingency and complexity of substantive outcomes. Tempering this bleak picture

of an industry in ever-increasing overreach, but with every encouragement to represent

success through the deployment of indicators under its own control are the possibilities that

22

One of my observations from work as a development consultant would be that experienced development

managers and consultants are extremely aware of the importance of defining indicators that will satisfy donor

cravings for success. The ubiquitous logical frameworks that projects are required to generate have a higher end,

where the goals are described in terms of the general conditions that are to be influenced, whilst the lower end of

the framework describes the inputs and outputs which the development agency pretty much controls itself. The

skill, then, is to shift elements of the intervention as high up the hierarchy as possible: dress outputs up as

outcomes; dress inputs up as outputs etc. By this means, simply to implement a project guarantees that it can be

reported as successful.

Page 49: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

31

firstly, the time may be ripe for a more realistic look at the capabilities of the industry, and

secondly, that however much the designs and policies of the industry may „fail‟, they may

also generate space for initiatives which make unintended but beneficial use of the

possibilities created by development industry interventions.

2.3.2 The Nation State – Gatekeeper and Development Partner

2.3.2.1 The Development Partner Problematic

The national government of the country hosting interventions has a key role to play for any

development industry activity. Assistance to or via government must be framed up as a

cooperation project and the government must sign up for it. Non-governmental organisations

meanwhile must also register with government and are subject to national regulation. Li

argues that even the more enlightened development industry actors in Indonesia:

...pay astonishingly little to attention to the character of ruling regimes, which they continue

to treat as development partners desiring only the best for their citizens. In Indonesia,

despite the evidence of widespread state-sponsored violence and the trampling of rights,

donors continue to assume that the state apparatus operates, or can be made to operate, in a

coherent and accountable manner in the public interest (Li, 2007, p. 275).

In this respect it seems almost inevitable that there would be a gap between the documentation

of development policy and the understanding of development practitioners. It would hardly

seem feasible to have a government sign up to a project which included phrases such as

“widespread state-sponsored violence and the trampling of rights”23

. Project practitioners are

therefore faced with a range of possibilities:

1. Be aware that some state practices and agendas are systematically excluded from

project documentation for diplomatic reasons, and factor these back in to everyday

and strategic work.

2. Accept uncritically the view of the state as a development partner fully committed to

the project as described in the project document.

3. Delineate between the world of the project (probably as „technical‟) and the world of

politics (whether party politics or the politics of other struggles for resources and

power)

In accordance with the critical perspective adopted in this thesis, I select theories which help

us to understand how and why there may be more to the role and functions of a host country

government than what is implied in the „development partner‟ framings of development

industry documents. Shadow state theory relates to competition over resources and potentially

links to resource curse theory. Neopatrimonialism relates to how networks of power are

managed in terms of recruitment and management of support and possible accountabilities.

These are both concepts that have been developed in African contexts (Erdmann & Engel,

2007; Reno, 2000), but have been applied to Cambodia (Kimchoeun et al., 2007; Le Billon,

2000). These will be complemented by a third, more positive concept, namely that of the

Developmental State.

2.3.2.2 Neo-patrimonialism

The concept of neo-patrimonialism addresses the way in which the motivations and structures

that define the activities of members of government reflect other fields of interest than those

defined by their formal role or the constitution, policies and laws that are associated with

23

Though as we shall see, some quite critical formulations are certainly possible.

Page 50: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

32

formal government. Erdman and Engel (Erdmann & Engel, 2006, 2007) reviewed literature on

neo-patrimonialism and attempted to crystallise a definition of the concept. They concluded as

follows:

Neopatrimonialism is a mix of two types of political domination. It involves a conjunction of

patrimonial and legal-rational bureaucratic domination. The exercise of power in

neopatrimonial regimes is erratic and unpredictable, as opposed to the calculable exercise of

power embedded in universal rules (...). Public norms under neopatrimonialism are formal

and rational, but their social practice is often personal and informal. Finally,

neopatrimonialism corresponds with authoritarian politics, whereas legal-rational domination

relates to democracy (Erdmann & Engel, 2007, p. 114).

Whilst many earlier writers had suggested that western or modern or legal-rational forms of

government had been facades concealing a politics that was essentially personalised and

patrimonial, Erdmann and Engel felt that this was to effectively cast neo-patrimonialism as a

form of patrimonialism. They argued that the literature and the conceptual framework for neo-

patrimonialism needed to pay more attention to the implications of the legal-rational element

of the neo-patrimonial framework. A particular distinction they suggested between

patrimonialism and neo-patrimonialism was that under patrimonialism the big person and the

little person deal directly with each other in the exchange of services for protection. Under

neo-patrimonialism, on the other hand, they suggested that a plethora of brokers mediated

exchanges at the intersections of the two interlinked systems of domination (Erdmann &

Engel, 2007, p. 107) In Cambodia one item on the research agenda, explicitly theorized in

neo-patrimonial terms, has been to investigate the nature and extent of any accountability to

clients within the informal patron-client networks which, for instance, subsidise infrastructure

construction throughout the country as part of political campaigning (Craig & Kimchoeun,

2009).

Blaikie‟s (2006, pp. 1950-1951) discussion of the role of the intersection of the State with

CBNRM (sub-titled “blowing on cold embers?”) uses Malawi during and since the rule of

Hastings Banda as a prime example of a neo-patrimonial state. Referring to pre-existing flows

as patrimony, in contrast with aid money which he calls neo-patrimony he describes the way

in which the neo-patrimonial state manages to keep up sufficient appearances to keep donor

funds flowing, but without disturbing existing informal revenues:

...the waving through of some local NGO projects and some rhetorical gestures in the form of

policy papers may be enough to ensure the continuing flow of the neo-patrimony of aid

without really compromising the flow from the capillaries which draw patrimony from the

local up to the national level. While there were several training and skills development

workshops facilitated by the Department of Forests, foot-dragging over approving regulations

and management plans has meant that many communities have lost interest.

Within the modern development industry, exemplified with Truman‟s Point 4 speech,

capacity building is a card that is almost always played. Whatever problem is to be tackled,

whatever strategy is to be employed to address it, it is almost inevitable that training will be

required. Blaikie‟s example demonstrates how capacity building (“training and skills

development”) can be part of a national government strategy in a neo-patrimonial frame.

Government accepts training programmes, which give the impression of progress and keep

the money flowing, but use them as a means to postpone or substitute for substantive action

along the policy lines envisaged.

The point here, of course, is that metaphors of corruption and decay tend to suggest state

actors who lack competence or capacity. What the neo-patrimonial discourse stresses, on the

other hand, is that the „strong men‟ and „presidential‟ figures at the head of neo-patrimonial

Page 51: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

33

systems may need to be highly active and competent, but that their competences are in

managing the two systems, rather than bringing the ideal form of one of them into reality:

Patrons in neo-patrimonial relationships are also required to have special ability to manage

the system. Neo-patrimonial power effectively combines mastery of the formal system with

mastery of the informal as neo-patrons straddle two or more power bases, combining

resources from cultural (traditional), family, economic political and administrative worlds

(Kimchoeun et al., 2007, p. 44).

When the neo-patrimonial theorists begin to discuss control over resources and the

management of violence they begin to share common ground with another theory of state

functioning which comes out of Africa, and which has been applied to Cambodia.

2.3.2.3 Shadow state

Shadow state24

theory is primarily concerned with the relationship between political elites and

informal economies. It implies two broad claims. One is that the erosion of the formal state

and the flourishing of informal markets should not be seen as a form of decay, but rather as an

active project conducted by formal leaders who maintain their political power through the

control of informal markets. Second is that this strategy is facilitated by the involvement of

foreign investors in informal markets. Reno (1995) introduced the idea of the „shadow state‟

in his study of governance in Sierra Leone, which also drew on examples from Zaire and

Liberia. He subsequently made a more generalised, summarised presentation of his shadow

state theory (Reno, 2000). He demonstrated that this was not simply a contemporary

phenomenon, but that colonial rulers had made a conscious choice to support the informal

economy rather than an emerging formal economy. In current times he discusses how the

shadow state is resilient to difficulties, how it has coped with attempts to introduce liberal

policies both in the 1930s and the 1990s by intensifying rather than weakening the link

between political power and informal markets:

Thus ‗entrepreneurs‘ in state offices and informal markets do not respond with political

support for policies that undercut their own political power through control of markets (Reno,

1995, p. 55).

and concludes that the most likely successor to any shadow state with its networks of informal

business links and private armies, is another Shadow state set up by somebody within the

existing arrangements (Reno, 1995, p. 188).

Whilst Reno emphasises that a shadow state is “a matter of degree, rather than an all-or-

nothing proposition” (Reno, 2000, p. 442) the key dimensions of the theory point to an

extremely predatory relationship between the political elite and the people, as rulers are

imagined fomenting chaos in order that people will seek their personal protection in a

situation resembling government-as-protection-racket which undermines any ideas of

reciprocity between ruler and ruled (Reno, 2000, pp. 442-443 & 446). The chaos features the

deployment of gangs of violent youths employed as private armies paid to protect elite

business interests and to intimidate opponents. Such a system is inherently instable, but

stability partly comes through the ability of the elite to use its international legitimacy to

attract international investment (often for activities that would not be allowed in states with a

functioning rule of law).

24

When Reno (1995) coined the term he capitalized it as Shadow State. Other authors are divided. I have opted

not to capitalize (likewise for the discussion of the developmental state below).

Page 52: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

34

The absence of a formal state that can enforce property rights or provide political stability will

deter most investors in manufacturing and service sectors. However, enclave natural resource

operations may provide lucrative opportunity:

Diamond, cobalt and gold mining, timber operations and money laundering do not require

extensive protection of assets. Where necessary, firms can manage their local economic

environments, either by renting local military units, or hiring private security guards from

outside the country (Reno, 2000, p. 456).

Cambodia clearly is not an extreme case of a shadow state. The fact that it has hosted a

substantial manufacturing sector during the past decade is one example of this, as are the

presence of largely functioning (if less than perfect) health and education systems.

Nevertheless, as we shall see, Le Billon (2000) has clearly identified elements of the shadow

state in Cambodia‟s governance, especially in relations to how illegal (or „informal‟ or

„clandestine‟ in Reno‟s terms) logging incomes underpinned State power during the 1990s.

The focus of shadow state economics on resource enclaves links to the literature on resource

curses, which suggest that, paradoxically, countries with high value natural resources fare

worse economically than countries without such resources. A two-step argument is suggested:

first that the reorientation of the elite to capturing rent from the resource works to an erosion

of accountability to the wider population and a deterioration of national accountability and

institutions. Secondly, and possibly more contentiously, that the natural resource money is

then frequently used to subsidise other parts of the economy such that they do not become

competitive (Auty, 2001; Ross, 1999, 2001).

Finally, shadow state theory, and its focus on the political economy of resource enclaves links

to theories of Uneven Development (Harvey, 2006; Smith, 2008) which suggest that as capital

moves to and fro in the global landscape that it creates sites of accumulation which are also

sites of dispossession. A particular argument about uneven development was provided by

Ferguson (2005). Reviewing experience in Africa, he made the case that globalisation, far

from smoothing out space and creating homogeneity, is actually characterised by the way in

which capital does not flow evenly across and through spaces but instead “„hops‟ over

„unusable Africa‟, alighting only in mineral-rich enclaves that are starkly disconnected from

their national societies” (Ferguson, 2005, p. 380). This establishes the vision of a form of

„development‟ which is characterised by violent and unfair competition for high value

resources dominated by footloose actors able to avoid systems of either global or national

political accountability. Ferguson‟s vision has a particular resonance when he outlines the

example of the offshore oil in Angola as „the clearest case of extractive enclaving‟ (2005, p.

378), given that prognoses about Cambodia‟s economic future are currently dominated by the

prospects of income from recent discoveries of offshore oil. However, for the purposes of this

thesis, as we will see, it is the timber wealth in Cambodia‟s forests which have turned them

into the more insecure areas on the map as they have attracted the interest of cut-and-run

capitalists and the security apparatuses that they employ (see Chapter 4).

Literature on neo-patrimonialism and shadow states highlights the way in which the informal

agendas of political leaders may bear little relation to the public transcripts to which they

subscribe when conducting their formal business. In extreme form, their interests consist of

undermining the very objectives inscribed in official policy. The literature furthermore

highlights the way in which the informal agenda may be highly focused onto resource rich

areas, and that in cooperation with international capital, national elite interests may become

quite divergent from those of wider populations. These are important correctives to the sort of

uncritical engagements which Li, cited at the beginning of this section, thought she saw in

Indonesia.

Page 53: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

35

2.3.2.4 The Developmental State and Asian Values

Neopatrimonialism and shadow state theory, especially the latter, are frequently associated

with corruption and with failing states. These are not theories which are commonly associated

with narratives of success and improvement. Another, much broader, literature looks at

another form of state which also departs from mainstream development industry prescription,

not least in its refusal to prioritise human rights, is that of the developmental state (Chung-In

& Rashemi, 1994; Önis, 1991), and especially the „Asian Values‟ developmental state which

has centred around the arguments made by former Singapore president, Lee Kuan Yew (Barr,

2000; Dalton & Ong, 2005). The debates in this literature centre on the relationship between

politics, the bureaucracy and the economy, with successful economies of East Asia and

Southeast Asia providing the main empirical base for discussion. Debates typically centre

around the relationship between authoritarian, leader-centred politics (which Cambodia has),

well-functioning, dedicated professional bureaucracies (which Cambodia does not have) and

successful economies (which, as we will see in Chapter 4, Cambodia has up to a point). In

contrast to shadow state theory, the enigma at the centre of developmental state theoretical

discussions relates to why the state does not become predatory:

Why should the state, given its autonomy, strength and capacity, choose a ―benign‖ or

developmental‖ rather than ―predatory‖ course of action? States such as Zaire leverage their

strength to rob their society. Why are South Korea and Taiwan not motivated to do the same?

Why do they confound neo-utilitarian expectations? (Chung-In & Rashemi, 1994, p. 371)

What we take from these contrasting theories for this thesis is the fact that elite political

projects may be developmental or they may be predatory. Or they may, indeed, be a complex

and shifting combination of the two. Furthermore, because they may be planned and executed

in ways that are partly or wholly clandestine it may be difficult to judge what dynamics and

motivations are driving behind-the-scenes state agendas.

In Chapter 4 we will see in more detail how the shadow and the developmental aspects of the

Cambodian state co-exist. It is beyond the scope of this thesis to turn the spotlight on elite

politics in Cambodia and to try and identify signs of whether it is essentially developmental or

shadow, or to what extent there is flux. As an indication that both are powerfully present I will

use the term shadow/developmental state in order to refer to the informal elite politics and its

interaction with the informal economy which dominate much of Cambodian governance and

which find little place in official policies and legislation.

2.3.3 Uneven Landscapes of Rural Southeast Asia

This whistle-stop tour of selected theories that inform the journeys that development

interventions take has begun in the western development industry, has 1) begun with

incentives and compulusions in core/donor countries, 2) reflected on the nature of the host

nation government – a key gatekeeper on the journey – and now 3) finishes in the local

setting, in the lives and livelihoods of the people who are scheduled to benefit. The focus here

will be on debates about what defines and shapes livelihoods in rural Southeast Asia. First,

though, a brief note on how livelihoods are conceptualised here.

2.3.3.1 Conceptualising Livelihoods

One strand of development practice literature has sought to ensure that the perspectives of the

poor are given priority. Robert Chambers was at the fore in this, especially with his book

Page 54: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

36

Rural Development: Putting the Last First (Chambers, 1983)25

. This perspective generated

two major strands of practitioner literature, one devoted to Participatory Rural Appraisal

(PRA), and another to Sustainable Livelihoods.

The sustainable livelihood approach was intended to enable analyses of individual or

household situations which supported understanding of people‟s situation and their agency. In

its rural iterations this led to a sustainable livelihood framework which located the

individual/household in a „vulnerability context‟ endowed each individual/household with

various „capitals‟, and postulating them as having livelihood choices which could be

simplified to variations on intensification, diversification and migration. The approach

embedded in this literature has much in common with the critical aim of this thesis of

avoiding the systematic and persistent misrepresentations exemplified in the 1990s studies:

The aim is to do away with pre-conceptions about what exactly rural people are seeking and

how they are most likely to achieve their goals, and to develop an accurate and dynamic

picture of them in their environment (Carney, 1999).

The sustainable livelihood framework has some significant limitations. One is that it provides

such a broad agenda that as a researcher it does not help one to prioritise any particular

variables, but rather tries to sum up every conceivable factor at every conceivable scale which

might influence how a household gets by (Scoones, 1998, p. 13). Another is that the framing

up of household endowments as „capitals‟ seems to both assign people the wrong class

position and to make static what are in practice highly dynamic and relational endowments

(Murray, 2001, p. 7).

For the purpose of this thesis, my concept of livelihoods relies centrally on incomes

(including non-monetary incomes). More specifically it focuses on the make-up of

households‟/individuals‟ everyday incomes; the coping strategies that households/individuals

have if there is an economic shock to their everyday income/expenditure balance; the

aspirations they have for the future incomes for themselves and for their children. This

concern with crises and with intergenerational issues what authors refer to when they discuss

sustainable livelihoods (Chambers & Conway, 1992, pp. 15-18). Understanding about the

political economy/political ecology/immanent development context is then accessed via

questions about the factors which constrain or enable livelihoods (ie current and future

incomes).

With this conceptualisation in mind we turn to some discussions which seek to identify trends

and determining factors in rural livelihoods in Southeast Asia.

2.3.3.2 Agriculture and Agrarian Transitions

Mainstream theories of national development suggest that national development tends to

follow a phased process with agricultural development preceding industrial development (e.g.

ADB, 2000, pp. 13-19; Timmer, 2006). Surplus labour from the countryside is postulated as a

necessary factor to enable capitalism to be driven from urban concentrations. Rostow‟s stages

of growth and Lewis‟s „dual sector‟ model, were the classic statements of this argument and it

continues to have purchase today: a recent Swedish study of Cambodia‟s economic situation

was framed in explicitly Rostovian terms (Sjöberg & Sjöholm, 2007). This version of the

agrarian transition, and its development policy implications remain firmly within the

mainstream; Bezemer and Headey (2008), for example, argue that industrial transformation

has always been preceded by agricultural transformation, and further argue that agricultural

25

This was one of two development books which I carried with me to Cambodia in 1991. The other was

Hancock‟s (1989) Lords of Poverty.

Page 55: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

37

transformation is necessarily dependent on state intervention, arguing that “no agricultural

transformation has ever occurred without extensive and effective state support programs”

(Bezemer & Headey, 2008, p. 1346).

In this tradition, much scholarly attention is given to the conditions that are required to

stimulate the sort of agricultural development/agrarian transition that is required to stimulate

national development. Within this, debates about the role of farm size and land policy have

been central. James Putzel (2000) has argued that one of the main lessons to be learned from

20th

century history in Asia was that redistributive land reform works, and that “in situations

of capital scarcity and labour surplus there is an inverse relationship between the size of farm

and the productivity of land and labour in agriculture” (Putzel, 2000, p. 3). Specifically he

argued that successful development in South Korea and Taiwan, and then in China and

Vietnam had been squarely founded on land reform policies that both stimulated economic

growth and enabled political stability.

Hayami (2001) explained regional variation in the agricultural development in post-war

Southeast Asian economies in terms of the modes of production that had dominated in key

historical moments when hitherto unused natural resources on „empty land‟ suddenly acquire

a market value when exposed to international trade thereby enabling these unused resources to

be the basis for economic growth (Hayami, 2001, p. 178). Essentially he argued that Thai

agriculture had outperformed Indonesia and the Philippines because it had an almost entirely

smallholder economy. Indonesian agriculture, furthermore, had outperformed the Philippines

because it had more smallholders and fewer plantations.

In Hayami‟s view all crops typically considered „plantation crops‟ were actually farmed as

smallholder crops somewhere, and that the vertical integration and coordination required for

competitiveness could be supplied far more efficiently through systems of contract farming.

Plantation agriculture, he argued, has occurred not because it was economically optimal, but

because it was a means by which colonialists could pre-empt large areas of unused, or

apparently unused, land.

Crucially for the arguments in this thesis, it was unfolding historical events rather than the

pulling of policy levers at national level that had shaped these uneven developments. Attempts

at land reform in the Philippines had worsened agricultural productivity because of what

Hayami terms „the dilemma of land reform‟. Attempts at reform were restricted to the

subsistence sector, but because the threat of reform also hangs over the cash crop sector,

plantation owners have limited their investments in agriculture. Similarly, in the smallholder

sector, beneficiaries of the land reform were reluctant to hire out their land (as they might for

example in Indonesia) for fear that tenants might also acquire rights over that land under the

terms of the reform.

In this frame of thinking (narrowly exemplified by these two contributions from Putzel and

Hayami) then, agriculture is central to national development, farm size is central to the

demographic structure and economic incentives required to drive agricultural development,

and state policies (intentional development) may be key in determining appropriate farm size.

However, these cannot simply override considerations of political economy and „small d‟

development.

2.3.3.3 Decoupling and Deagrarianisation in Southeast Asian Landscapes

Analyses of rural development which blur the distinctions between rural and urban and

disrupt the more linear agrarian transition framings have been present in Southeast Asia

scholarship for some time (e.g. Rigg, 2001). It has been argued that important trends have

Page 56: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

38

included a de-linking of rural development from agricultural development, and a consequent

de-linking of land holding from wealth, have rendered standard rural development policy

staples such as land reform and agricultural improvement less relevant and effective (Rigg,

2006)26

. A recently published study in northeast Thailand (Rigg & Salamanca, 2009) spanned

twenty-five years in two villages, and citing other research in villages in Northeastern

Thailand found strongly in favour of the de-agrarianisation thesis. This not only challenged

the linear, agriculture-driven development models, but also models that argue that Thailand

has been a case of dependent industrialisation and peripheral marginalisation. Rigg and

Salamanca (Rigg & Salamanca, 2009, pp. 265-266) used the example of an apparently

increasingly vulnerable and impoverished 58-year old widow, in poor health, who had sold

much of her land to pay hospital bills with one of her two sons having died, one having

moved to another village and her only daughter having married and moved to Bangkok. In the

village she was also classified as close to poor in wealth ranking exercises. However, her

livelihood was in fact relatively secure. She took care of her daughters‟ two children and

received about 100 USD per month remitted from her daughter (a garment factory worker)

and son-in-law (a taxi driver). The point here was not that there had been a decisive or

permanent improvement in the rural economy, but rather that “risk and vulnerability have

been re-shaped in significant ways” and that “the parameters of these changes are clear ... the

shift from farm to non-farm, from local to extra-local, from community to state and from

social to economic” (Rigg & Salamanca, 2009, p. 265). Meanwhile, the misrepresentation

identified with the 1990s studies in the introduction to this thesis appeared to be alive and well

in the late 2000s:

It is striking how far scholars, development practitioners and government officials still

rehearse the script of Northeast Thai villages being poor, farming dependent and isolated

(Rigg & Salamanca, 2009, p. 266).

Recent work in the de-agrarianisation tradition, encompassing studies from Asia and Africa,

has focused on studies of „frontiers‟. In this context, a frontier is “a particularly dynamic space

where the forces of economic, demographic and social change are brought to bear”

(Agergaard, Fold, & Gough, 2010, p. 1), and these frontiers are “regions where linkages to

global markets are dominated by one particular product (coffee, pineapples, gold etc) or a

number of similar products (handicrafts, fresh fruit)” although the concept also encompasses

the more diverse “manufacturing frontier” in Thailand (Fold, Gough, & Agergaard, 2010, p.

198).

Reviewing case studies of rural manufacturing and handicraft frontiers, Gough and Rigg

(2010, p. 156) found the non-farm sector developing dynamics which were increasingly

shaped by non-local markets and raw material sourcing rather than local resources.

Agriculture did not usually benefit from increased investment and even tended to become

more extensive as human resources and financial investment were attracted into handicrafts

and manufacturing, which even became a magnet for low-skilled migrant labour (Rigg,

Veeravongs, Rohitarachoon, & Veeravongs, 2010, p. 137). At least in the case of the Thai

manufacturing frontier (Rigg et al., 2010, pp. 146-147), it seemed that the success of the

manufacturing sector meant that the local economy was able to be successfully re-constructed

without requiring the degree of out-migration and remittance livelihoods that have been

characteristic of much of the shift towards de-agrarianised rural development. A region that

had formerly been Thailand‟s „rice bowl‟ had become not a labour reserve, but rather a site of

26

Whilst Rigg in that article was reaching out from Southeast Asia experience to look for empirical evidence of

comparable trends in South Asia and Africa, scholars such as Ellis (1998) and Bryceson (2006) were developing

similar perspectives on the basis of studies of livelihoods in rural Africa.

Page 57: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

39

„industrialisation and metropolitanisation‟ with a population whose livelihoods were delinked

from the land and coupled to remote sites in the wider economy (Rigg et al., 2010, p. 148).

Meanwhile, in the agricultural frontiers, even in areas where agricultural was most

successful, more people tended to be employed in services and trade (Fold & Tacoli, 2010, p.

96). Fold and Tacoli, summarising the case studies in agricultural frontiers described a

continuum from mono-location and mono-activity to multi-activity and multi-location.

In contrast to the literature on agricultural development and agrarian transitions which Putzel

and Hayami exemplified, the recent work on rural-urban dynamics is not readily translated

into a narrative of national development. Fold, Gough and Agergaard (2010, p. 201) explain

that national rural-urban dynamics cannot be read off from their studies of frontiers. Their

frontier regions are primarily sub-national phenomena, oriented around complex dynamics

between local production and global markets. For them, the study of frontiers tends more to

structuring a “simple bipartite division of rural-urban dynamics in the context of national

development, namely into hinterland areas and areas which are resource rich” (Fold et al.,

2010, p. 200). Once again, then, as with the references to Uneven Development (Harvey,

2006; Smith, 2008) and Ferguson‟s (2005) Seeing Like an Oil Company, rural space becomes

conceptualised as a patchwork featuring resource rich sites of accumulation and less endowed

hinterland areas. The analytical lesson from a case study point of view is that conclusions

about what a case represents should be drawn with reference not to a generalised „national‟

„rural‟ space, but rather in relation to the mix of interdependencies and independencies in the

array of variously endowed and positioned frontiers and hinterlands.27

2.3.3.4 Agrarian Change and Resistance

Resistance has been a central theme in the politics of rural Southeast Asia, whether related to

the (successful) opposition to collectivised agriculture (Kerkvliet, 1995), or in opposition to

the rolling out of the Green Revolution (Scott, 1985). This is not least because of the limited

successes of Southeast Asia‟s rural poor when they have acted politically in acts of overt

resistance or rebellion (Scott, 1977).

The findings of studies of rural-urban dynamics in the frontiers and hinterlands of Southeast

Asia might almost suggest that there is little reason for resistance, given the overall

trajectories of change:

Factors such as the further development of frontier regions, technological innovations,

agricultural intensification and off-farm migration have – at a broad scale – reduced the

precariousness of rural life (Turner & Caouette, 2009, p. 13)

Such a position would be supported by Walker‟s analysis of the impacts of contract farming

in Northern Thailand, where he found that – notwithstanding various complaints by farmers –

that contract farming offered a reduction of risk and therefore of agricultural indebtedness and

had resulted in an engagement which he characterised as experimental rather than resistant

(Walker, 2009, pp. 76-78).

It might also be noted that the „hidden transcripts‟ of the rural poor do not always find place in

either „public transcripts‟ or acts of resistance. It is still possible for people and their ideas to

be marginalised. In my years in rural Cambodia discussions with farmers about potentials for

27

In the authors‟ words “attention should be paid to the selection of different regions with distinctive positions in

the national development process (including, for example labour reserve regions, resource-poor regions, and

geographically isolated regions) before conducting analysis on livelihood diversification, mobility and settlement

transformation….” (Fold et al., 2010, p. 201).

Page 58: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

40

agricultural development frequently ended in suggestions that included the creation of state

marketing boards to guarantee prices for their produce, and the introduction of import bans to

prevent cheap produce from Thailand and Vietnam coming into the domestic Cambodian

market. Such views, however, find little voice in the various participatory processes to define

either donor assistance strategies or national policies.

A rural scene with relatively few broad-based political movements (Borras, 2009, p. 19) and

with complaining voices both mollified by the effects of relative prosperity and muted by the

lack of effective outlets may be a feature of a time that is coming to a close. Turner and

Caouette saw concerns about massive poverty and unemployment in rural Southeast Asia in

the 1970s as having been “deferred” rather than avoided. Certainly theories of Uneven

Development would encourage one to see the benefits of the past couple of decades as

contingent and precarious, with the possibility of economic crisis generating destructive

impacts throughout the now highly-integrated and interdependent rural landscapes of

Southeast Asia:

In some locales, the proliferation of wage labour along with the agrarian transition has

resulted in increased dispossession and marginalization, especially of smaller landowners and

agricultural workers. In other sites, there has been increased economic growth, with people

able to form new and increasingly sustainable livelihoods. Such divergent outcomes have even

occurred between village neighbours due to the progressively more individualized

consequences of the agrarian transition (Turner & Caouette, 2009) .

2.3.4 Fraught Journeys Recapitulated

This three-stop selective tour of the travel of development intervention from western origins

to Southeast Asian landscapes highlights some of the contradictions and contingencies

involved in interventions by the western development industry. It suggests that there are

strong reasons for having a critical approach in the sense of being sceptical of any intervention

that is framed as a well-intentioned, technical, win-win solution to problems jointly identified

and jointly addressed by host country governments acting in harmonious concert with

development industry actors. It also suggests that what we might term a „rural caricature‟,

present in the 1990s case studies in Chapter 1, remains a feature of development in the late

2000s. Having reflected critically on the long and uncertain journeys that development

interventions in general represent, attention will now focus on the theories that underpin the

particular sorts of intervention – property rights interventions in the form of land titling and

community forestry – that are the focus of the cases in this thesis.

2.4 Property Rights Theory and Interventions

2.4.1 Introduction

Commerce and manufactures can seldom flourish long in any state which does not enjoy a

regular administration of justice, in which the people do not feel themselves secure in the

possession of their property, in which the faith of contracts is not supported by law, and in

which the authority of the state is not supposed to be regularly employed in enforcing the

payment of debts from all those who are able to pay (Adam Smith, "The Wealth of Nations"

cited in Rodrik et al., 2002).

Property rights have long had a prominent place in arguments over the pre-requisites for

growth and development. In recent debates about factors which best explain development

Rodrik has been a champion of institutions as opposed to „geography‟ or trade integration

(Rodrik et al., 2002). However, he has been critical of the way in which:

Page 59: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

41

―institutions rule‖ has sometimes been interpreted as a form of property rights reductionism—

one that views the formal institutions of property rights protection as the end-all of

development policy (Rodrik, 2004, p. 1).

This section will examine the theoretical underpinnings of the interventions studied in this

thesis – individual private property rights theory for systematic land titling and common

property rights theory for community forestry. It will also review literature on these styles of

intervention, both the “rational policy” literature which enquires into the relations between

intention and outcome and what has been learned about the conditions required for successful

policy outcomes, and also literature that has “a more discursive and political approach” and

that “better captures what actually happens in the policy process” (Blaikie, 2006, p. 1047).

First, however, brief attention is paid to defining property rights.

2.4.2 Property Rights Definitions

Bromley (2006, pp. 479-480) defines property rights by separating the concept of property

and that of rights28

. Property is “not an object, but is, instead, a stream of benefits (values)

into the future”, with the concept of ownership being related to the control of a benefit stream

arising from the “setting and circumstance” that is the property relation. A right, meanwhile,

is understood as dependent on “an enforced duty”. The duty is for those who do not have

rights to not interfere with the interests of those who do have rights. The enforcement of rights

then requires enforcement by an authority or an authority system which is willing and able to

impose sanctions on those who do not fulfil their duties. Bromley stresses that this need not be

a state or government as understood in the industrialised economies, but might instead by a

“traditional leader”.

The distinction between different sorts of authority to enforce rights and duties in relation to

property is highlighted by Schlager and Ostrom (1992, p. 254) when they draw a distinction

between de jure and de facto rights. De jure rights are “given lawful recognition by formal,

legal instrumentalities”, whereas de facto rights arise when “resource users cooperate to

define and enforce rights among themselves”. Schlager and Ostrom make two points in

relation to these. First, that they are not an either/or pairing: de jure and de facto rights may

“overlap, complement, or even conflict with one another”, and second, that for a user there is

no qualitative difference between the two sets of rights unless the de facto rights are

challenged in an administrative setting.

The distinction between de jure and de facto rights might invite the idea that there is a latent

potential for any given de facto right to be made de jure through the simple measure of

formalising it. The term legal pluralism has, however, been termed by authors who suggest

that there is a need to be attentive to “multiple legal orders such as state, customary, religious,

project and local laws, all of which provide bases for claiming property rights” and that:

Instead of looking for clearly defined rules within a single, coherent legal system, it is more

useful to recognize the ambiguity of rules, and the multiplicity of legal systems. This ambiguity

and pluralism gives scope for human agency, through forum shopping and adapting rules in

the concretization of rights. Such agency is critical for dealing with uncertainties that arise

from environmental fluctuations, livelihood changes, social and political upheavals, and other

sources (Meinzen-Dick & Pradhan, 2002, p. 27).

28

My friend and former colleague Shaun Williams has pointed out to me that property is a form of right, and that

the term „property rights‟ is thus an oxymoron. This is surely correct, but given the prominence of the term

„property rights‟ in the mainstream, including much of the literature I have cited, and in the absence of an elegant

alternative, I have let it stand.

Page 60: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

42

This, we may be sure, is not what Adam Smith (cited above) had in mind when he wrote of

the importance of the state securing property rights in order to facilitate economic

development. On the other hand, if property rights are about a quest for security and control,

the legal plurality and forum shopping concepts possibly serve to illustrate the fact that

„making secure‟ is not always within the reach of policy makers:

In general, legal pluralism calls for greater humility in policies and programs. It is not just a

matter of getting the ―right‖ law or the ―right‖ institution to allocate or manage resources.

Instead, rights to resources will be determined through messy, dynamic processes (Meinzen-

Dick & Pradhan, 2002, pp. 28-29).

Having adopted Bromley‟s definition of property rights, we might also note his argument

(Daniel W Bromley, 2006, pp. 481-482) that there are two common assertions which connect

property rights and development in policy discussions:

1. Economic development is impeded by the lack of property rights

2. Natural resource degradation in the developing world persists because of insecure

property rights.

He warns that neither of these assertions is adequately supported by empirical evidence. They

do of course represent the core claims of the respective interventions that are examined in this

thesis. Systematic land titling aims to stimulate economic development by providing

individualised, exclusive property rights via land registration and the issuance of title.

Community forestry aims to prevent natural resource degradation by providing communities

with rights over forest: the remainder of this section continues to investigate this apparent

paradox. Why would an assertion that is unsupported by evidence nevertheless be persistently

asserted in policy circles?

2.4.3 Theoretical Justifications for Land Titling

If farmers are secure in the ownership of their land, they will dare to invest in it, which they

would not dare to do if they were worried it would be taken from them. If people have title to

land, they can then use that title as collateral to obtain loans which would not previously have

been available to them, and then to invest either in improving the land or in other productive

activity. If all property is titled, then buyers and sellers will be confident to transact land,

thereby enabling a functioning land market which will allocate land to the most efficient

farmers. This set of three justifications constitute the core of the theoretical argument that has

long underpinned the promotion of land titling programmes (see Daley & Hobley, 2005, pp.

204-205; Deininger, 2003; Feder & Feeney, 1993; Feder & Nishio, 1998, pp. 26-28; Heltberg,

2002, pp. 204-205). A further motivation, less commonly at the fore of international

proponents of titling, but one which has been argued to be a historically dominant motive for

national adoption of titling programmes, is that land registration provides the government

with the basis for revenue-raising by means of a land tax. (Feeny 1988 cited in Heltberg,

2002). A final benefit which may be added relates to social costs of land conflicts: it may be

anticipated that a programme to title all land, whilst generating increased conflict during the

period of implementation, will potentially lead to clarity and resolution and therefore save on

the social and economic costs of conflicts and appropriations that persisted prior to titling. It

has been suggested that this might particularly benefit the most poor and vulnerable

(Törhönen, 2001).

Regarding the three principle justifications for titling, each of these has been stressed to

different degrees and for different reasons in different contexts. For many the impulse to title

is first and foremost about facilitating land markets (Barnes, 2003, p. 367; K. A. Gould,

Carter, & Shrestha, 2006). The assumption here is that the market is a far better and more

Page 61: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

43

efficient distributor of land than the state, ensuring not only that the most efficient farmers

(those who are assumed to make most profits from farming and then to invest those profits in

expanding their holdings) receive most land, but also that the most efficient farm size will be

achieved (farms that are smaller or larger than the optimum will lose out in competition with

optimally sized farms and will either be combined or sub-divided until they are optimally

competitive). Because the efficiency of land markets is often assumed, the focus when

evaluating titling has often been limited to whether the market is active or not (and not on the

results of its allocations) with increased transaction volume and increased land prices are held

to be sufficient indicators of the benefits of titling (Feder & Nishio, 1998, p. 40), although this

assumption has not gone unchallenged (D. Mitchell, Clarke, & Baxter, 2008, p. 472) .

The argument that systematic land titling improves security and therefore leads to investment

and increased productivity is coupled to the idea of a strengthened, stabilised rural sector. In

Cambodia, for example, it has been suggested that enabling security of tenure and increased

investment would provide the impetus for smallholder farming to become the third engine of

national economic growth after garments and tourism (World Bank, 2006, 2007b). While not

necessarily in conflict with the aim of facilitating the land market, there is some tension

between the images evoked: the one of land changing hands and with the prospect of a surplus

population seeking their comparative advantage elsewhere having sold up in the dynamics of

the agrarian transition; the other an essentially conservative vision of farming households

remaining in place but becoming securer, more productive and more prosperous.

Even convinced advocates of land titling programmes have not suggested that they are

appropriate in all situations:

If it is not clear whether the key factors for the economic viability of land registration systems

are present, it may not be an opportune time for the government to invest in land registration.

The society would benefit more from other types of investment ,which address more binding

constraints to its economic development (Feder & Nishio, 1998, p. 38)

Or (in the context of a sceptical review of De Soto‟s work):

Titling must be followed by a series of politically challenging steps. Improving the efficiency

of judicial systems, re-writing bankruptcy codes, restructuring financial market regulations

and similar reforms will involve much more difficult choices for policy makers. These are

swept under the rug in the text of The Mystery of Capital (Woodruff, 2001, pp. 1222-1223).

For each of the main three postulated benefits, a set of complementary functioning institutions

is required: tenure security requires that a legitimate authority (courts or their equivalent) will

enforce and sanction the property rights inscribed in the title; collateralisation requires that

there is a well-functioning financial market so that the new demand for credit can be supplied;

a functioning land market requires that the land administration authorities are efficient,

affordable and accessible to buyers and sellers (Feder & Nishio, 1998, p. 37). It is the lack of

complementary institutional arrangements that prompts scholars to doubt whether the

theoretical benefits of titling can in fact be realised in, for example, transition economies (Ho

& Spoor, 2006, p. 586)

The functioning of these institutions post-titling must be compared with the situation prior to

titling. It is possible that even without the land registration apparatus, and possibly without the

involvement of formal authorities and credit institutions, that tenure might be secured, credit

obtained and market transactions guaranteed by means of informal authorities. Such a

situation would, paradoxically, solve most of the potential implementation problems that

relate to titling interventions, but would at the same time rob them of their potential to add

value.

Page 62: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

44

2.4.4 Theoretical Critiques of Land Titling

2.4.4.1 The De Soto Factor

During the past decade, largely as a result of the prominence achieved by Hernando de Soto‟s

(2000) The Mystery of Capital, it is the second theoretical potential of titling, to enable

increased access to credit, that has received most attention. Highly popular in political and

policy circles whilst at the same time often criticised heavily in academic circles (Gilbert,

2002, p. 2; T. Mitchell, 2004, p. 5; Payne, Durand-Lasserve, & Radoki, 2009, p. 445;

Woodruff, 2001, p. 1215), de Soto (2000) argued that the reason some economies had

successfully developed, or, in his terms, that capitalism had only succeeded in the west, was

that individual property rights were formally secured in the west and not elsewhere. Formal

title, he argued, had enabled loans to be leveraged against assets which otherwise were „dead

capital‟. In poor countries, and especially in the informal urban settlements in Latin America

which is where he began his research career, his findings were that poor people did not lack

assets, but that these assets were held in „defective forms‟. If their informal residences could

be securely titled then they would be able to raise financial capital and further exploit the

business skills which he found them already to possess in abundance in the informal

economy. Counterarguments to this thesis have abounded.

To the extent that arguments for land titling are increasingly taking their theoretical departure

point from the work of de Soto29

, there has been criticism of the historical validity of the case

that he makes. Mitchell (2004, p. 25) has suggested that the focus on documentation is

misplaced. He points out that there has been a traditional mistrust of documents in the west

(there being, for example, no title document in either British or US systems), and that what

counts is not paper representations but extent of control. To select from the tip of the iceberg

of criticisms of de Soto‟s reasoning, methods and findings, Mitchell (2004, p. 11) has pointed

out that most homeowners in the West do not collateralise their domestic properties in order

to obtain business loans, but rather go into debt in order to purchase the property in the first

place; most of the 40%-70% of the population in the West are „homeowners‟ do not

completely own their homes because they are mortgaged and not yet paid for. Gilbert,

meanwhile, cites his own research and reviews other studies suggesting that titling has not

made a difference to the ability of people in urban settlements to obtain formal credit, and

furthermore that most poor people would rather not seek credit because “repaying a loan is a

burden that may endanger the household‟s whole financial viability” (Gilbert, 2002, p. 17).

The heavy weight of academic critique notwithstanding, de Soto‟s work has furthered the

promotion of titling as a development strategy and of collateralisation as a justification for

that strategy, not just in urban Latin America but in urban and rural settings around the globe

(Alden Wily, 2008, p. 43).

2.4.4.2 Markets are not benevolent

Collateralising land and transforming it into a tradable commodity are both double-edged

swords. If land is used as collateral for a business loan and the business fails, the land is lost.

If land can now be more easily sold as a commodity, then poor people will be more vulnerable

to losing it at low prices when their circumstances become difficult (Cousins, 2009, p. 897).

29

This is surprisingly widespread as even serious scholars such as Deininger whose engagements with the topic

are longer, more scientifically grounded and nuanced, use reference to de Soto to justify the claim of a

theoretical benefit from land titling in the form of improved access to credit (Deininger, Ali, & Alemu, 2009, p.

5).

Page 63: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

45

Mitchell, not entirely at ease with the conceptualisation of the informal sector and the assets

lying „outside‟ capitalism, also sees any change wrought by titling as exposing poor people to

unequal competition within the formal market arena:

The movement of assets from what is called the outside to the inside does offer a means to

create wealth. But not in the way De Soto describes. The process of property titling and the

use of property as collateral offer up opportunities for speculation, for the concentrating of

wealth, and for the accumulation of rents (T. Mitchell, 2004, p. 27).

Christophers (2010) meanwhile, drawing inspiration from David Harvey (Harvey, 1973,

1982), takes issue with the idea that it is possible to separate property as financial capital

(realisable by collateralising an asset) from its physical manifestation. This is in direct

contradiction to de Soto‟s encouragement to “conceptualise property less as its physical

manifestation and more in terms of its legal function, and hence as a form of representation”

(Christophers, 2010, p. 103). What this theoretical argument comes down to, is that at all

scales, household, national and global, the analytical separation (what Christophers terms the

„mystification‟ of „voodoo economics‟) of financial capital from its material manifestation

will inevitably, somewhere, constitute not a win-win but a zero-sum scenario, and there will

be losers:

Any apparent ‗economic growth‘ located in the property rental market must ultimately be

grounded in, and sustained by, growth in the real economy of productive activity. If such

growth is not occurring, and surplus value is not being generated, the notional growth

delivered by the landlord class must eventually come crashing back to earth (Christophers,

2010, p. 106).

Bromley, (2009) has argued that the priority for poor people is employment: as such he

viewed the advocacy for formal titles as “cultural imperialism” and “an example of the

persistent quest for ideational hegemony” (2009, p. 6).

2.4.4.3 Tenure is not always reducible to simple formal ownership

As we will see in the common property literature, even where tenure is not essentially

communal “often several layers of interest in property are recognised as legitimate”

(Benjaminsen, Holden, Lund, & Sjaastad, 2009, p. 34). Two issues coincide here and both

provide theoretical grounds for challenging registration of ownership as a policy intervention.

The first is the impossibility of reducing to a single category of exclusive ownership complex

bundles of rights to property where different people have different rights over land at different

times of the year.

The second relates to the idea that tenure systems evolve over time as a result of a number of

(highly contested) variables including demographic change, relative factor prices, the cost of

providing and enforcing private title, agricultural commercialisation and trade, available

technology, (Heltberg, 2002, p. 199). Partly, as Heltberg discusses, these debates over the way

in which tenure systems evolve has focused around discussions of the validity of Boserup‟s

(1965) proposition (both neo-Malthusian and anti-Malthusian) that increased population

would drive technical development and agricultural intensification.

Recent work in Africa describes an alternative historical trajectory. Chauveau and Colin

(2007, p. 66) make a definitional distinction between traditional „tutorat‟ forms of exchange

“in which land transfers are embedded within a broader socio-political relationship and entail

a continuing duty of gratitude and of allegiance toward the customary land holders” and sales

“which are monetarised deals that do not entail a continuing relationship once the transaction

is completed”. They portray a long-term transition from a situation of labour scarcity to a

situation of land scarcity has seen a transition in forms of property rights. This has largely

Page 64: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

46

(though with variation within and between countries and a great deal of hybridisation between

older and newer property regimes) been a transition towards more private, individualised

exclusive forms of tenure. The point here, then, is that a titling programme is potentially

capable of formalising a property rights regime that has achieved a point on its trajectory (or

evolution in some discourses) where broader socio-political relationships have brought into

being private, individualised tenure. The proposition that the simple fact of implementing a

titling programme might shift tenure arrangements to that point is altogether more unlikely.

Cousins makes a similar argument with regard to a general approach that prioritises bestowing

formal legal rights, when these will not have leverage with substantial reality and argues that

only “civic activity (i.e. politics)” can achieve these (Cousins, 2009, p. 906).

2.4.4.4 Formalisation is biased against women

The potential gender bias of land titling interventions is as much an empirical issue as a

theoretical one. To the extent that land titling is a process of formalising existing tenure

arrangements, it may be unfair to women in that formal arrangements may tend to be highly

biased towards men in comparison to customary or „informal‟ pre-titling arrangements. This

has been found, for example, in the way a „head of household‟ has been designated as title

holder in Latin American projects:

In the past, land titling projects granted titles in the name of the head of household, who was

usually an adult male. This often undermined the tenure security that women had through the

customary system that operated prior to titling (Barnes, 2003, p. 373).

On the other hand, when attempts were made to address this, for example through joint titling

of conjugal property, this was often met by resistance from within existing dynamics, which

also had their gender biases. Based on experience in Colombia and Nicaragua, strong rural

women‟s organisations were found to be the most promising way to address the issue of

protecting women‟s land and resource rights through titling (Barnes, 2003, p. 373). Case

study evidence from Senegal and South Africa, meanwhile suggested that women‟s tenure

security had been enhanced by being specified on ownership records (Payne, Durand-

Lasserve, & Radoki, 2009, p. 447).

2.4.5 Empirical Evidence on Land Titling

It is beyond the ambition of this thesis to provide a definitive and conclusive summary of

findings relating to the claims made for and against land titling programmes. Broadly it might

be said that they are both varied and contested. This section examines findings, primarily from

recent reviews of the literature, in relation firstly to the main theoretical claims made for

titling namely Impact on Security and Investment, Impact on Access to Credit, Impact on

Land Markets, then on a range of significant secondary issues, Impact on Revenue Raising

and Other Impacts and Implementation Issues. Finally, but of high importance given the

arguments of this thesis, I examine observations in relation to the Spatial Distribution of

Titling.

2.4.5.1 Impact on Security and Investment

Deininger‟s (2003) research report for the World Bank on land policies for growth and

poverty reduction found that while tenure security was strongly correlated with economic

growth, that the relationship between formal land titling and tenure security could not be

assumed (Deininger, 2003, p. 39). His understanding from the literature was that informal

options might in many circumstances provide many of the tenure security benefits that are

expected from land titling, but that formal titling became the preferable option in situations

Page 65: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

47

where there was sufficient land administration capacity, and where land prices were

sufficiently high (Deininger, 2003, p. 56). While stressing the importance of context in

determining which land policies were appropriate, and noting mixed results in Africa,

Deininger also gave Thailand as the case which most clearly demonstrated positive economic

impacts (Deininger, 2003, p. 5). While the Thai project has been widely praised, Williams

has suggested that it may be a case where successful implementation and output delivery has

blinded judges to the lack of evidence on which to base claims of positive outcomes (S.

Williams, 2003).

Looking for evidence of the relationship between security and titling, Payne et al. (2009, p.

447) found that titling programmes have often been implemented where there is already de

facto security. In places where there was insecurity they found the evidence of improvement

“surprisingly thin and mixed”.

Some risks associated with titling related to unequal information and involve speculation and

acquisition of land at low prices in anticipation of price rises post titling. However, even when

all actors are well informed, the anticipation of programmes has led in some cases to an

intensification of conflicts, social unrest and insecurity (Benjaminsen et al., 2009, p. 31).

2.4.5.2 Impact on Access to Credit

Deininger et al. (2009, p. 5) have recently – and in passing - summarised the literature on the

impact of titling on credit. They found the literature somewhat equivocal: some studies

showing some positive effects, but others showing either no effect at all, or that only larger

land owners had benefited. This ambivalence has long roots, and possibly reflects the lack of

studies that specifically engage with the relation of titling to credit and adequately

contextualise and explain findings. One of the more frequently cited studies by Feder and

Onchan (1987) is referred to as both demonstrating that titling does improve access to credit

(Deininger et al., 2009, p. 5) and that it does not do so (Daniel W. Bromley, 2009, p. 23).

Payne et al. (2009, p. 455) are if anything less optimistic, finding that the literature suggests

that titling has not (at least in the short term) generated any significant increase in access to

formal credit. Their case study work in Senegal and South Africa, furthermore suggests that

most loans taken out are for house improvement rather than as business loans, and that

business development loans have not been secured against houses.

2.4.5.3 Impact on Land Markets

Part of the key to the relationship between land titling and a functional land market is not the

initial titling process itself, but the registration of subsequent transactions. In Latin America

earlier experience had been that registering land and issuing title were insufficient to address

land market issues, but that problems within the land departments responsible subsequent

registration “overly bureaucratic, costly, inaccessible, centralized, corrupt and not transparent

to the users” also needed to be addressed (Barnes, 2003, p. 369). This, whilst being a problem

identified since the 1980s remained an area where the World Bank and USAID remained

“short of lessons” (Barnes, 2003, p. 373).

Payne et al. (2009, p. 453) in their review found that whilst the literature supported the claim

that titling enhances the value of land, and that this is often in the order of a 25% rise, that this

was not necessarily of benefit to the poor because:

...the lack of a formal title is a price that the urban poor pay to gain access to a residential

plot that they could otherwise not afford. Of course, increases in land values are beneficial to

owners planning to sell land, but they are less attractive to those seeking to acquire it as

Page 66: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

48

average incomes do not increase at a similar rate to average urban land values (Payne et al.,

2009, p. 453)

Increased land values have also had adverse knock-on effects in terms of reduced access by

the poor to rental markets (Payne et al., 2009, p. 447).

2.4.5.4 Impact on revenue raising and other secondary impacts

Whilst not always to the forefront of literature promoting the benefits of land titling, the

preparation and maintenance of a land register can provide part of the basic infrastructure for

the collection of land taxes. One of the intentions of the World Bank supported Thailand Land

Titling Project was certainly that it should include a land valuation component which would

enable government to use the land register as the basis for revenue raising. This was an

intention that despite the best efforts and encouragements of project staff was never realised

(Rattanabirabongse, Eddington, Burns, & Nettle, 1998, p. 13).

One might speculate that two different agendas were in play here. The Bank might be

imagined to have a self-interest in being able to demonstrate that loan repayments flowing out

of a country are covered by the tangible revenues to the treasury generated by the project

thereby eliminating any doubts as to whether the loan was (at the national scale) cost effective

for the borrower. The Thai government, on the other hand, might be reluctant to risk its

political capital by introducing unpopular new taxes. If development projects are

conceptualised as somewhat long and uncertain journeys, the land valuation and revenue

raising component of the Thai Land Titling Project may be seen as an example of a project

component which was turned away at the threshold by the national gatekeeper. In this respect,

the suggestion by the authors that the key lesson was a “need” to “document the necessary

commitment of all parties to the implementation of the project design” (Rattanabirabongse et

al., 1998, p. 15) is strongly reminiscent of the unrealistic control orientation and obliviousness

to local political realities that Porter et al. (1991) found characterising international

development practice in eastern Kenya twenty years previously.

In a recent study, Deininger and colleagues reviewing the literature suggested that clear

positive impacts of titling had been more associated with increased investment and increased

land values in rural schemes, as well as reducing fertility, increasing investment in children

and affecting governance, corruption and the performance of local institutions (Deininger et

al., 2009, pp. 3-4).

2.4.5.5 Implementation issues

Some of the literature reflects on issues relating to effective (or otherwise) implementation of

land registration and titling. In Guyana, for example, titles were issued in blocks of 100 plots.

If one title was delayed by a conflict then the whole block had to wait (Hendrix & Rockcliffe,

1998). Were lessons from glitches such as this learned during the preparation and

implementation of land titling in Cambodia? Chapters 4 and 6 will answer that question.

Meanwhile, the implementation literature also yields some unintended lessons about the

relationship between operational imperatives and substantive results. Within the World Bank,

the Thailand Land Titling Project, mentioned above, is regarded as an outstanding success;

Rattanabirabongse and some of his colleagues and advisors on that project have written on the

reasons for that success (Rattanabirabongse et al., 1998, p. 3). Some of their solutions,

however, had implications for the substantive goals of the project.

One implementation issue in the early phases of the Thailand project was that completion rate

was affected by the fact that survey teams were not able to register parcels near forests. This

was solved in later phases by the Royal Forest Department being brought in to define forest

Page 67: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

49

boundaries before titling commenced, in order that the overall scope of titling was clear.

Within adjudication areas a second problem was that completion rates were affected by the

fact that not all people eligible for title actually completed the process of paying for and

taking receipt of their titles once land had been registered. The solution to this problem was

that the definition of „complete‟ titling was amended such that titling was considered

complete when all plots had been registered, and where a plan was in place for dealing with

any remaining non-issued titles. In terms of project efficiencies these „lessons‟ clearly had

value (Rattanabirabongse et al., 1998, p. 18). However, for people with a claim to land

deemed by the Forest Department to be inside forest, and for people who did not receive titles

at the time as their neighbours, these solutions may have confirmed their exclusion from the

benefits of titling, or at least made their struggles to obtain benefits much less visible.

In a similar problem to the Thai forest example related to communal lands in Ethiopia; a risk

that was prevented by identifying communal lands in a “public and participatory process”

before titling (Deininger et al., 2009, p. 6). As always, it is difficult to discern much about the

outcomes of conflicts between competing interests when they are glossed with participation

(cf. Biddulph, 1996), however, this may indicate a development of a more contested if not less

power-laden dynamic than simply inviting in the relevant state authority to, at one go, make

and achieve its territorial claim.

2.4.5.6 Spatial distribution of titling

Cambodia‟s titling process resembles earlier processes also supported by the World Bank in

Thailand and Indonesia. Williams has suggested that the main lessons that Indonesia learned

from Thailand were “ways to avoid complex tenurial situations, as well as complex land types

such as forests, so as to be able to concentrate on reaching high production targets in non-

contested areas” (S. Williams, 2003, p. 8). In other words, the titling programme (intended to

achieve security of tenure) was being implemented in areas where tenure security was not a

problem (“non-contested areas”).

Liz Alden Wily (2008), meanwhile made a similar point from the other side of the fence when

she argued that instead registration of the rural commons should take priority:

The reason is simple; that it is these properties, not the family farm or house, that have been

and remain today at most risk from involuntary loss – and which represent losses with most

real and potential jeopardy to the rights of the majority rural poor (Alden Wily, 2008, p. 48)

The introduction of communal property and community based management leads us into

another area of theory-inspired policies and a literature replete with advocates and critiques

and discussions of what is necessary or desirable in order to make policies effective. Before

making that step, it is worth making one geographical point. Alden Wily was writing about

Africa, and on the basis of vast experience on the African continent. She referred to two sorts

of common land: one where communities exercised “de jure or de facto customary tenure”

and another which referred to “the millions of hectares of land designated state or public land

but customarily understood as community property” (Alden Wily, 2008, p. 43).

From quite different perspectives, then, what both Williams and Alden Wily are pointing to is

the possibility that in its spatial distribution, systematic land titling may tend to be

implemented away from the places where the problem it is supposed to address is most

present.

Page 68: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

50

2.4.5.7 Discursive claims: why land-titling travels well as policy

Mitchell‟s (2004) analysis of de Soto‟s success was that he had succeeded in generating a

“much more positive account of the resources and potential of the majority of the people of

the global south”. Cousins (2007), likewise notes the benevolent assumptions that “a

competitive market economy by its very nature generates „win-win‟ solutions”. The

suggestion that by means of a relatively simple administrative intervention that latent forces

may be brought into harness may provide much of the explanation as to why de Soto in

particular and titling in general have been so „successful‟ as policy „simplifications‟ or

„development myths‟. As we will see, similar arguments circulate in relation to common

property rights as policy.

2.4.6 Theories of Common Property Rights

The departure point for the literature on common property and the associated literature on

community based natural resource management (CBNRM) is Hardin‟s short (1968) article on

„The Tragedy of the Commons‟ (Alden Wily, 2008, p. 43; Dietz, Ostrom, & Stern, 2003;

Ostrom, 1999). The well-known and often-rehearsed element of Hardin‟s argument was that

rationally behaving herders would put too many animals on common grazing land leading to

its overgrazing and degradation, even though they knew that this was the outcome: a form of

prisoner‟s dilemma on a larger scale with more actors. As a result, commons were not a

sustainable form of land management for anything but very sparsely populated areas. Either

state intervention (Hardin‟s preference) or privatisation was required if the tragedy was to be

avoided.

From the point of view of common property and CBNRM theorists, the faulty assumption that

Hardin made was that the herders would not communicate with each other and there would be

no spontaneous social organisation in response to the threat of overgrazing. Hardin was not in

fact describing a situation of common property, but rather an open access regime. Common

property rights theory takes issue with the assumption that commons regimes are de facto

open-access regimes:

The prediction that resource users are led inevitably to destroy CPRs is based on a model that

assumes all individuals are selfish, norm-free and maximisers of short-run results. ...

However, predictions based on this model are not supported in field research or in laboratory

experiments in which individuals face a public good or CPR problem and are able to

communicate, sanction one another, or make new rules (Ostrom, 1999, p. 279).

Common property theory takes into account the possibility that populations may take on some

of the characteristics of a community, and that this may enable local institutions to develop

which enable a more rational balancing of community and individual interests than that

assumed in the tragedy scenario:

Simply enabling subjects to engage in face-to-face communication between decision rounds

enables them to approach socially optimal harvesting levels rather than severely

overharvesting the commons (Ostrom, 2007, p. 15183).

As we have seen, one of the criticisms of programmes of systematic land titling is that they

deliver an individualised, exclusive ownership. Schlager and Ostrom (1992) encouraged a

more disaggregated understanding of property rights in the context of common property

regimes

The conception of rights in common property rights (CPR) theory is typically more complex

than that used in the theoretical literature on the benefits of land registration and

Page 69: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

51

formalisation. Rather than one simple category of exclusive ownership, a hierarchy of rights is

imagined (see Table 2-1) and these are conceptualised as „bundles of rights‟ (see Table 2-2).

Table 2-1: Hierarchy of Rights in Common Property Regimes

Right Defined as the right to...

Access ...enter a defined physical property

Withdrawal ...obtain the „products‟ of a resource (e.g. catch fish, appropriate water etc)

Management ...regulate internal use patterns and transform the resource by making improvements

Exclusion ...determine who will have an access right, and how that right may be transferred

Alienation ...the right to sell or lease either or both the above collective-choice rights

Source: Adapted from Schlager and Ostrom, 1992, p. 250-1

Table 2-2 Bundles of Property Rights Associated with Different Types of Rights-Holder

Hierarchy of Rights Owner Proprietor Claimant Authorised

user

Access and withdrawal X X X X

Management X X X

Exclusion X X

Alienation X

Source: Schlager and Ostrom, 1992, p. 252

An empirical literature, revolving around the work of Ostrom, draws on real world cases and

laboratory experiments in order to identify key variables and criteria for functioning common

property regimes and commons management. A central theme in this literature is an insistence

on the complexity of common property scenarios and, therefore, of the complexity of any

institutional arrangements for common property management and of any intervention that

intends to support such institutions. Ostrom has, throughout her career, rallied against

simplifications (arguing that much policy discussion is so simplified that it constitutes

metaphor) and panaceas. Furthermore, that the failure to acknowledge the complexity of

“institutional details” has been particularly disastrous where communally owned forests in

Third World countries have been nationalised (Ostrom, 1990, pp. 22-23).

If the common property literature is framed as an enquiry into the circumstances in which

some form of common property regime may be preferable to state ownership or private,

individualised ownership (Ostrom, 1999, p. 279), of particular interest for this thesis are the

conditions which this literature suggests as being important for an effective common property

regime. Dietz et al. (2003, p. 1908) did not offer any clear definitive conditions but suggested

that effective commons governance were “easier to achieve” when the following five

conditions obtained:

resources and resource use can be monitored;

rates of change are moderate – applies to resource, resource use, population,

technology, economic and social conditions;

frequent face to face communication and dense social networks among the

community; outsiders can be excluded at low cost;

users support effective monitoring and rule enforcement.

Page 70: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

52

However, they also insisted that few settings in the world would be characterized by these

features so that:

―The challenge is to devise institutional arrangements that help to establish such conditions‖.

Furthermore, given the dynamics of biophysical, socioeconomic and technical change, and the

inevitability of humans devising ways to evade governance rules, that institutions must be

capable of delivering ―adaptive governance‖. This is held to be particularly difficult in cases

where challenges involve ―systems that are intrinsically global‖ such as ―timber production

for the world market‖, and where situations ―differentials in power within user groups or

across scales allow some to ignore rules of commons use or to reshape the rules in their won

interest, such as when global markets reshape demand for local resources‖ (Dietz et al., 2003,

pp. 1908-1909)

Agrawal (2007) has reviewed the relationship between forest management and the common

property literature providing a more forest-oriented discussion of the conditions necessary for

effective common property regimes (see Table 2-3).

Table 2-3: Analytical Framework and Agrawal's Observations on the Literature

Cluster of variables Observations

The resource system Key variables include size of the resource system, its boundaries, rate and

predictability of benefits, ease of monitoring conditions.

Notwithstanding priority assigned by Ostrom (2005) and others, biophysical

properties of forests tend to be neglected in scholarship on forest-based

commons.

The users While, smaller, interdependent, relatively homogenous, well off and groups

that are very forest dependent and do not suffer sudden shocks in their

demand for forest resources are more likely to successfully create institutions

that effectively regulate forest governance, cause-effect relations of

particular variables are not linear or predictable “whether the relationship

between different measures of successful governance of commons, and

group characteristics such as size, heterogeneity, interdependence,

dependence on forests, and poverty is negative, positive, or curvilinear seems

subject to a range of other contextual and mediating factors, not all of which

are clearly understood”.

Institutional

arrangements

“Rules that are easy to understand and enforce, locally devised, take into

account differences in types of violations, help deal with conflicts, and help

hold users and officials accountable are most likely to lead to effective

governance”. Although what that really means is difficult to understand and

apply given the instabilities and breadth of terms, and the fact that “there

may be literally hundreds of thousands of rule combinations from which

decision makers can choose”

External

environment

“Demographic, cultural, technological, market-related factors, the nature of

state agencies, and the level of involvement of other actors and forces such

as NGOs and international aid flows are issues to which those interested in

deforestation have been more attentive than scholars of forest commons”.

Source: Adapted from Agrawal (2007, p.118-125)

Whilst the institutional economics orientation of Ostrom and her collaborators has paid more

attention to the structure of incentives required to enable effective institutional functioning,

the issue of the origins of common property rights regimes and management systems is also

important within the literature. For Alden Wily, for example, common property regimes are

by definition customary and indigenous (Alden Wily, 2008, p. 45). From a policy point of

view, this sets up the potential option of common property rights interventions as a

Page 71: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

53

formalisation programme analogous to the formalisation of informal possession into formal

legal tenure. In other words, that it might not entail engineering of incentives and building of

new institutions, but rather be a matter of providing legal title and recognition for already

existing processes. This shifts the discussion slightly, and, as we shall see, opens up debates

around what a common property intervention consists of (introducing a new development or

preserving an existing – though dynamic – institution), and around how the world of policy

and intervention apprehends (represents/misrepresents) what is informal, local or indigenous.

2.4.7 Critiques of Common Property Rights Approaches

While land titling programmes and the trend towards formalising individualised, private

tenure have been criticised on ideological grounds, for incorporating people in economic

relations which expose them to the vagaries of the market and the threat of dispossession, no

comparable critique is made against common property rights (CPR) and related community

based natural resource management (CBNRM) approaches. Scrupulously set within a context

of alternatives that include state and private individualised tenure and management, and

paying attention to natural science, economics and broader social science concerns the

CPR/CBNRM agenda is not typically regarded as carrying any particular ideological load

either as a project of the left or of the right. Critiques of CPR/CBNRM tend to nod

respectfully at the theoretical grounds (Blaikie, 2006, p. 1952), but protest at the way these are

mobilised in discourses which pay insufficient attention to either actual livelihoods or political

economy/ecology settings. Blaikie sees this as a global tendency and ascribes it to precisely

the sort of simplifications that Ostrom has repeatedly set out to counter in scientific work, but

which have a particular resilience in policy circles as, for example, Roe has argued in his book

on policy narratives and meta-narratives:

Stories commonly used in describing and analyzing policy issues are a force in themselves,

and must be considered explicitly in assessing policy options. Further, these stories often

resist change or modification even in the presence of contradicting empirical data, because

they continue to underwrite and stabilize the assumptions for decision making in the face of

high uncertainty, complexity and polarization (Roe, 1994, p. 2 cited in Blaikie 2006, p1947).

This tendency for CPR/CBNRM narratives to succeed at policy level has often led to

CPR/CBNRM being promoted and implemented in places where they are ill-matched to the

livelihoods and political ecology settings. This tendency is exacerbated by a tendency to focus

on local institional arrangements rather than broader political ecology contexts (“the

continuing and nearly single-minded concentration of commons scholarship on institutions

and property rights” as Agrawal, 2007 p.129 expressed it)

Walker (2004, p. 312) coined the term „arborealisation‟ to describe the way in which

community forestry discourses “recast upland livelihoods as forest livelihoods”. He argued

that this misrepresented both the main livelihood activities of the forest-dwelling poor, which

were primarily agricultural and not Non-timber Forest Product (NTFP) oriented, and also the

main forms of tenure, which in relation to agricultural land were private possession rights to

individual plots. Walker included four elements of misrepresentation in arborealisation, as

people were framed as: essentially non-commercial (so even where commercial activities are

acknowledged they are classified as non-authentic); shifting cultivators; NTFP gatherers – and

culturally disposed to be such; dependent on environmental services from forests. These

elements of misrepresentation were maintained in spite of lack of evidence to support them,

and even clear evidence to contradict them (Walker, 2004, pp. 313-315). These might be said

to comprise a „forest caricature‟ similar to the „rural caricature‟ first encountered in the 1990s

studies in Chapter 1, and found by Rigg et al. (2010) to still be in circulation in the late 2000s.

Page 72: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

54

Casting the net a little wider in Southeast Asia, Tania Murray Li has reviewed experience in

Philippines and Indonesia and concluded that “the forest-dwelling, resource-conserving,

„traditional‟ indigenous uplanders who serve as exemplars or embodiments of CBNRM are

relatively rare on the upland scene” (Li, 2002, p. 267). She found that this contrasted starkly

with the realities of upland livelihoods, which have long-since and irreversibly been

transformed, largely by smallholder initiatives, to an intensive, sedentary, cash-crop

orientation (Li, 2002, p. 269). She furthermore, again in ways that mirror Walker‟s

observations in Thailand, found that CBNRM discourses were mobilised by donor-driven

conservation campaigns aiming to resist the expansion of oil palm production, whilst the

interests of villagers would have been better served by improving the terms on which villagers

could deal with plantations (Li, 2002, p. 272).

At the same time, she found that, not necessarily by conscious and deliberate design, and still

at the same time as potentially opening up opportunities for dialogue and resistance,

community forestry also to some degree extended State control over communities and forests.

Communities were allocated “only land which is already denuded of trees and extracts from

them cheap labor in reforestation and protection” (Li, 2002, p. 274), while more valuable land

was allocated to logging or plantations as economic concessions.

Continuing the theme of misrepresentation Li argued, referencing Peluso, that CBNRM

rhetoric in Indonesia:

Tends to locate the essence of community in a pre-colonial past and then truncate the time

frame such that autonomous communities are assumed to have persisted throughout the

colonial and postcolonial period, up to the time of intensified logging beginning in the 1960s

(Li, 2002, p. 276).

In relation to the notion that CBNRM might empower communities in relation to the state she

argued that communities should be imagined within the state rather than in opposition to it30

,

and that:

Where citizens are indeed up against ―vicious states‖, the potential of CBNRM to empower

them is very limited (Li, 2002, p. 278).

While Murray Li‟s, Blaikie‟s and Walker‟s critiques of CBNRM speak to the dangers of

policy simplifications and incapacity to engage with the realities of local livelihoods and

political ecology, they also raise the question of policy intention. While common property

rights theories envisage benefits for both communities and the survival of commons

resources, the impulse for their implementation might be more one-sided. Specifically,

whether it is international conservation agencies seeking traction over resources in distant

places, or national forestry authorities seeking consolidation of their territory and cheap labour

for resource management, the policy intervention may effectively consist of an attempt to co-

opt local people‟s labour in the interests of the higher aim of resource management or

conversation. Murray Li, adopting a position that prioritises the rights of upland peoples

argues:

The search must therefore continue for legal strategies which secure for uplanders the benefits

of a fuller citizenship and which offer them, and expect from them, no more and no less than

other citizens. In order to tease out what these strategies might be, it will be necessary to go

beyond the simplifications of the CBNRM model, and locate its assumptions more precisely

within the changing political economy and ecology of upland settings (Li, 2002, p. 278).

30

This is coherent with arguments Li has made elsewhere in relation to the work of Scott where she argues that

there is no space beyond the State (nor indeed beyond the market), and that conceptualizations to the contrary are

misguided (Li, 2005).

Page 73: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

55

2.5 Conclusion

In the first section of this chapter a framework was developed. Bebbington has suggested a

form of geography of development intervention which maps development interventions

(intentional development) onto key features of political economy (immanent development)

and analyses the relationship between the two. My `Critical Geography of Development

Intervention‟ framework modifies the definitions of intentional and immanent development

somewhat, not least to stress that „immanent‟ development consists of a range of ongoing

material and ideological struggles which any development intervention must contend with. It

also complements the focus on the spatial distribution of phenomena with the use of

contextualised studies of place as a means by which to engage critically with the generalised

claims of development theory and policy, and the conceptualisation of development

interventions as journeys – real and metaphorical – in order to unpack the discursive and

political shapings of intervention and therefore the temporal and contingent nature, of any

given spatial arrangement of intervention.

In the second section, a selective three-stop guided tour of theoretical and empirical studies

relating to the travels of development journeys yielded perspectives that will inform the

arguments and findings in this thesis. First, the ever expanding nature of development

industry agendas, with the consequent risk of overreach were highlighted, as was the

possibility of unintended but beneficial events being set in motion. Institutional economics

perspectives explained how the incentives structuring the industry do not tend to hold it

accountable to the rural poor who might otherwise be regarded as its clients. Rather, the lines

of accountability point back to the donor country and tend to encourage reporting of success

based on the few direct outputs that interventions can best control. Second, national political

elites representing host governments are crucial as they play the role of gatekeeper and

development partner. The development industry tends to represent national governments as

„development partners‟ often framing them as having very similar motivations to development

agencies but lacking the capacities to implement them. Our reference to neo-patrimonialism,

shadow state theory and the Southeast Asian „Asian Values‟ developmental state have shown,

by contrast, how political elites will always have a political project of their own. Whether this

is aimed at national improvement or self-enrichment or a mixture of the two, it is unlikely to

be reflected in the formal positions adopted by the political elite. Shadow state theory in

particular is complemented by resource curse literature and work such as that by Ferguson

(2005) which puts the resource curse into a spatial frame. 3. Literature on livelihoods and

Southeast Asian rural transformation, has focused on economic relations and mobility. A

persistent debate between those who see agriculture as central to rural transformation, and

those who see other links to wider markets enabling economic transformations that do not

depend on the agricultural sector. These happen in a shifting landscape of frontiers and

hinterlands, but it is largely a gentler, less violent landscape than that portrayed in the shadow

state literature. Although the effects of recent transformation have been uneven, with winners

and losers; there is a sense on the one hand, that there have been more winners than losers in

recent times, but on the other hand that the gains are fragile and that populations may rapidly

become extremely vulnerable.

Finally, we turned to the theoretical underpinnings of the interventions that constitute this

case. Systematic land titling and common property rights (CPR) interventions are contrasting

from an ideological point of view. Land titling is a market enabling strategy and one that has

taken precedence over strategies that prioritise state interventions to allocate land. CPR on the

hand occupies a third space with neither market nor state as allocator and manager. Both land

titling and CPR interventions have been credibly shown to be effective in particular times and

particular places. Proponents of both approaches stress that the respective interventions,

Page 74: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

56

whilst having great potential, can only yield that potential if the context is suitable. Land

titling will have potential if there are competent authorities respectively to enforce ownership

and to register transactions, and if there are adequate supplies of credit. The extent of that

potential will be determined by the extent to which pre-titling conditions did not already

provide tenure security, credit and functioning land markets. Common property rights

interventions and community-based natural resource management initiatives will have more

prospect of success if the resource users can exclude non-members effectively and at

reasonable cost, if the resource users are not too many, too heterogeneous or too

geographically spread, and if there is not extreme instability in the biophysical, economic or

social and political relations around the common property regime. As with land titling the

clear paradox is that the more suitable the pre-intervention context is for intervention, the less

urgent the need for intervention is likely to be in that context.

The empirical chapters of this thesis will describe the distribution of systematic land titling

and community forestry interventions in Cambodia, and will provide detailed studies of two

places where these interventions were implemented. This will enable conclusions to be drawn

in the context both of existing literature on the respective interventions in Cambodia, the

broader literature on these sorts of intervention as reviewed in this chapter, as well as

attempting to suggest some broader implications for the development industry and for critical

geographies of development intervention. First, however, in chapter 3, I will describe and

justify the methods employed for this study.

Page 75: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

57

3 Investigating Intervention at National and Local Scales

3.1 Justification of Overall Approach and Scales

Chapter one has introduced this project which is an enquiry into the relationship between

property rights interventions and the lives and livelihoods of the rural Cambodians that they

are designed to assist. This is set in the context of a broader interest in the tendency of rural

development interventions both to fail to make a substantial difference to the people they are

intended to benefit, and to misrepresent their context.

In chapter two a critical development geography was proposed. This would, on the one hand,

use studies of place to provide a critical lens through which to view the generalised claims of

development policy and theory, and on the other hand would use studies of the spatial

distribution of interventions as a means of revealing key interests and ideas which are not

apparent in the policies that framed interventions.

Detailed case studies provide the possibility of “holistic understanding of complex processes”

(Mayoux, 2006, p. 117). In this case, then, village studies would provide the means by which

rural livelihoods could be seen in their everyday, lived context, and by which central concepts

and mechanisms envisaged in the interventions could be seen worked out in everyday life. A

detailed case study would provide us with insights as to how tenure insecurity was

experienced, or what the processes were which led to changes in levels of local control over

resources. At the same time, some weaknesses are typically associated with case study work

at the sort of small scale where these holistic understandings can be achieved. One is that of

representativeness. How can a single village represent a whole country? Another is that of

bias.

The „representativeness‟ of a detailed, contextualised village case study is different to the

„representativeness‟ of a large-sample survey. The main risk of a detailed case study is that it

might portray an exceptional case, or that it might prove impossible to tell from that case what

is specific and what is general. The main risk of a large-sample survey, on the other hand, is

that the meaning of the answers might be somewhat thin31

. Conventionally, these weaknesses

are complementary. A small scale study may identify a particular phenomenon or mechanism

and explain it in the study context. If this phenomenon is sufficiently important and the

explanation sufficiently convincing, these may then be tested against a wider sample using

quantitative methods. In practice, there are other matters of degree and debate around the

representativeness of any specific case, which might be characterised as discussions of what a

case might represent. In

31

In the context of this thesis, one thinks for example of the statistic cited by Deininger (2005) and Markussen

(2008) that 21% of respondents in the 2005 Socio-Economic Survey had land titles. As Markussen explained, no

titling had been done on that scale in Cambodia at that time, so the respondents must have meant something

different – but with only anonymous statistics available, it is only possible to speculate as to what the responses

meant.

Page 76: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

58

other words, a study of a remote fishing village might potentially represent other remote

fishing villages, and therefore a subsequent iteration of research using quantitative methods

might only extend its scope to include other remote fishing villages. Defining characteristics

of a case may be developed both in advance (as criteria for selection of the case) or in

retrospect (once the case has been analysed and key factors and dimensions more fully

understood). In this research, then, careful consideration has been given as to what the local

cases might represent.

At the same time, however, it should be noted that in practice this iteration between case study

and survey work is somewhat rare. The processes described by case study work may be too

complex or embedded to lend themselves to quantitative work. Or the case study might be so

convincing in its own right that it rapidly circulates and influences research and policy

without need to be tested against larger samples.

More vexed than the question of representation (though they are often related) is the question

of bias. Subjective biases are often held to be more likely in qualitative research which

focuses on contextualised studies at a small scale (Mayoux, 2006, p. 121). It is acknowledged

that bias is possible in the design and analysis of both qualitative and quantitative studies. The

response to this is that a researcher should firstly, strive after objectivity, even whilst

acknowledging that no method can be entirely value-free and objective, and secondly, should

attempt to specify and acknowledge biases (Holme & Solvang, 1997). In this study, I have

both attempted to be objective, but have also sought to acknowledge my biases. Thus chapter

one clearly situates me as a sceptic in relation to the effectiveness of rural development

initiatives generally, and also makes clear that I have an expectation that the development

industry may misrepresent rural livelihoods. These are not matters of uninformed prejudice,

but are rather grounded in personal experience and in my readings of development studies

literature. Nevertheless, in respect to the current thesis, they do constitute bias: I have

acknowledged that bias, explained where it comes from, and I have during design

implementation and analysis phases striven after objectivity notwithstanding any biases that I

have32

.

With regard to the study of the spatial distribution of the intervention, choices regarding

which phenomena should be identified to enable a mapping of “the uneven geographies of

poverty and livelihood under capitalist expansion and contraction” (Bebbington, 2004, p. 726)

followed the choice of intervention to be studied and will be treated below. The question of

scale, however, can be treated here. The spatial distribution of an intervention or its effects

could have been studied at various scales – at district or province level, for example, or within

a particular watershed. Indeed, the local case studies did provide the opportunity to study

spatial distribution of the interventions at the village scale. However, as we saw in Chapter 2,

given the national government in the crucial dual role of gatekeeper/development partner,

national scale investigations are particularly valuable for attempting to discern national scale

interests and dynamics not immediately apparent in policy framings.

3.2 Evolution of Research Design and Selection of Cases

In the context of a 4-year PhD employment, and given the difficulty and sensitivity of some of

my research interests, I determined to make the research phase of the project as long as

feasibly possible and to adopt an approach that would be flexible and iterative. The research

32

I might also add that another bias that I have is that in all the years that I have done development research I

have always hoped to find examples of intervention that have genuinely made a difference to people‟s

circumstances. My hopes are profoundly biased in a quite different direction to the acknowledged biases in my

expectations.

Page 77: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

59

plan therefore consisted of a one year inception phase followed by a two year main phase. In

total I had just over six months of field work available to me in Cambodia. This was divided

into six one-month research trips, two during the inception phase and four during the main

phase.

The intention during the inception phase was to ground the research in the study of the lives

and livelihoods of people in a single rural village, and to use that experience to identify an

issue of critical importance in their livelihoods. Leaving the decision about that issue until the

conclusion of the inception phase was an attempt to let the research respond to local

circumstance rather than just to my own interests. The methods for the main phase were

likewise not to be decided until the completion of the inception period in order that they could

be tailored to fit the research task that emerged. My assumption was that the issues identified

at village scale would be followed up by a larger scale quantitative survey thereby generating

an iterative process between small-scale and large-scale methods. As it turned out, local

circumstances did very much influence the shape and content of the research, although

contrary to my own expectations, the research effort included a sustained focus on two

villages over a three year period. Below I recount the process by which the two villages and

the research themes were selected, before, in the sections that follow, detailing the actual

methods used.

A village in Cambodia may be anything from a dozen to a thousand households, with the

rough average at the 1998 census being 164 households33

. For my purposes, a smaller village

was an advantage if I was to have a chance of developing an adequate understanding of the

entire village. I therefore made size of village a criterion and gave smaller villages priority

during the selection of a case.

The next criterion that I applied was to try and identify a village where there might be easily

traceable links to the sort of powerful and wealthy people who might have a dominant role in

setting the social and economic conditions for rural life, but not be resident in rural villages.

To do this I took advantage of some existing research in order to select a village with an

unusually wealthy resident. At the time that I was beginning my research, the international

NGO Oxfam had been carrying out some research on landholdings in rural areas of

Cambodia. They had a database where it was possible to identify villages which included

some residents with very large agricultural landholdings. Their largest category for an

individual land-owner was over 50 hectares. I reasoned that any individual who had acquired

that much land would not be a „normal‟ poor villager, and would have connections to wealth

and power beyond the local area. From the category of villages in the Oxfam survey which

contained land owners with more than 50 hectares I then chose the smallest rural village. It

was by this means that the village that I call Bey, in Chhlong district of Kracheh province was

selected as the study village for the inception phase34

.

After an initial overnight reconnaissance visit, the village research began in earnest on 26 July

2006, when I deployed for the first time to Bey village accompanied by a research team (see

33

This is a crude estimate achieved by dividing the 1998 census population of 11,437,656 by the number of

villages, 13,406, and then by the average household size, 5,2. These figures include both rural and urban

settlement so may not be perfectly accurate. (I suspect that the average rural village size is nearer 250

households). 34

Ironically, we were never able to identify who the Oxfam research had pinpointed as owning over 50 hectares.

We obtained the phone numbers of the students who had done the research in Bey village but were not able to

talk to them. Nobody in the village reported owning more than 50 hectares of land, although it is certainly

possible that landholdings of some of the wealthier households involved in trading land did extend that far.

Page 78: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

60

below). On our first evening we35

heard that officials from the Forestry Administration had

called a meeting in the village school. I attended that meeting, and was astonished to find

myself sitting alongside the villagers as a forestry official, employing the calmest and most

reasoning of tones, informed a third of the villagers that they were to be evicted from their

land so that the State could allow the forest to grow back again. That evening, I watched the

deputy village chief distribute and collect forms for villagers to protest the evictions. My

attention was caught by the fact that the villagers started to refer to these forms as „land titles‟.

One immediate concern was that if this village was to become a site of mass evictions that a

foreign researcher might not be a welcome witness to the conflicts and violence that that

might involve. I felt that I needed a contingency in order to be able to continue the project if I

was barred access to Bey.

At the same time, having heard the villagers talking of „land titles‟ I was struck by the

possibility of comparing the informal situation in Bey to the official land titling process that

was proceeding elsewhere in the country. I therefore decided to select another village which

could be the sole research village for the inception phase if Bey became inaccessible, and

which could also provide the basis for a comparision of informal and formal land titling

processes.

In order to do this, I chose Bati district, because this is the district where I understood that the

systematic land titling process had first been piloted and then implemented. Bati district town

is only a little more than an hour‟s drive from Phnom Penh. From amongst the communes in

Bati that had already been registered, I decided to try and identify a relatively remote

commune within the district in order to make the case study as „rural‟ as possible36

. Within

that commune I identified the smallest village, which I am calling „Buon‟ in this study, for the

reasons given above.

At that point I therefore had two small villages and one issue, namely land tenure security. In

Buon there was a development industry activity, namely systematic land titling within the

Land Management and Administration Project (LMAP), which had been implemented in

order to address the issue of tenure security. From the point of view of the development

industry, Bey was therefore the village where LMAP did not go. I was therefore interested to

look at the question of what sort of development industry intervention did go to this village.

The main development intervention in Bey was community forestry. This suited my purpose

well given that it was also a form of tenure security intervention.

By late 2006, then, after just one of the two inception visits, I had already identified two

villages, (whereas I had initially planned to only work in one) and also a broad theme,

property rights interventions, with two specific cases – land titling and community forestry –

when I had not intended to identify a theme until completion of the inception phase. Indeed, in

the case of the second village, Buon, the activity was identified not on the basis of the

interests and priorities of the villagers, but on the basis of my own interest that had been

catalysed by events in Bey. Already at that stage, then, the shape of the research was different

to what I had anticipated.

35

During village research I employed a team. I therefore tend to use the first person plural “we” to describe our

activities in the village, and the first person singular “I” where I am referring to decisions and actions that I took

alone. This is in addition to use of “we” where, as the context makes clear, it is the reader who is incorporated in

the first person … “as we shall see”, “as we have seen” etc. 36

At this stage nowhere in Bati could be described as „peri-urban‟, though this is likely to change in the coming

years and decades.

Page 79: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

61

At the end of the inception period there remained a question to answer about the approach for

the remainder of the study. Would I continue in the two villages, or would I attempt to scale

up, or could I do both? At that point in the research there were many unknowns in Bey: I was

in the midst of unravelling the motives behind the initial attempt to evict the villagers, as well

as following the processes by which the villagers‟ protests would be examined and

adjudicated, and working out the allegiances and intentions of various other actors rumoured

to be wanting to become active in the village. Meanwhile, I discovered that a well-designed

baseline study had been carried out to assess the impacts of land titling in rural Cambodia

(including field research in four provinces that had undergone land registration as well as in a

fifth village that would not be registered in the near future and would serve as a control case),

and that it would be followed up in 2007. The prospective availability of these research

findings allied to interest in understanding the dynamics that lay behind the mass eviction

initiative in Bey (which of course provided me with the possibility of the explicit link between

poverty and power that I had been looking for but not as I had intended) led me to continue to

focus the primary research on achieving a deeper understanding of unfolding events in the two

case study villages, and to put them in a wider context by means of secondary sources and

interviews with actors at provincial and national levels.

This one-thing-leads-to-another process of selecting interventions and villages meant that I

had, adopted one lowland rice village and one upland forest village. I had in other words

chanced upon the two types of landscape which dominate not only rural Cambodia, but the

whole of rural Southeast Asia. This clearly did not make them representative of all upland

forest and all lowland rice field villages: a village like Bey inhabited by people from the

Khmer majority would for example differ from a Phnong or Kravet minority village in one of

the neighbouring provinces; similarly a village like Buon with small landholdings, rain-fed

agriculture and poor soils would differ from the villages with irrigation, fertile soils and large

landholdings found in the same province but nearer the border with Vietnam. Nonetheless,

this possibility of broader resonances was at least opened up and was partly responsible for

inspiring the national level case study which is the first of this dissertation‟s three empirical

cases.

The national case study involved reviewing secondary sources, and supplementing these with

interviews with key stakeholders involved in order to construct the geographies of,

respectively, tenure insecurity, systematic land titling and community forestry.

3.3 Conduct of the Village Studies

The village studies each consisted of six stays of approximately a week once every wet season

and once every dry season from July 2006 until March 2009. In total, approximately 370

interviews were conducted, about 140 interviews in each village and a further 90 interviews

with government officials and development practitioners. At village level these were

complemented by a series of questionnaires and surveys. The rest of this chapter describes and

explains the conduct of the research

3.3.1 Research Team Composition

One of my advantages in conducting this research is my fluency in the Khmer language.

Bernard (2002) notes the risks attendant on being a researcher who does not know the local

language, especially those related to being considered a “freak” and to being given

mischievously false information. In his words, “The most important thing you can do to stop

being a freak is to speak the language of the people you are studying – and speak it well”

(Bernard, 2002, p. 339).

Page 80: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

62

The employment of a research team was a matter of choice, therefore, rather than of necessity.

A small team, I reasoned, would enable us to maximise the amount of information collected in

a (relatively) short period of time, and also to provide different interpretations of our findings.

Four heads, I decided would be better than one.

I assembled a team that included a mixture of age and sex, and also that included people who

had grown up in rural areas of the country (see photography at Figure 3-1) The assumption

here is that women like to talk to women, men like to talk to men, old people like to talk to

other older people etc. Obviously other dynamics also apply, but by ensuring that our team

was as heterogeneous as possible we maximised our chances of benefiting from those

dynamics. Myself and a lady from a village in Battambang whom I had known since 1998

were the older half of the team, while two students formed the younger half of the team. At

the outset these were two final year sociology students, who (as they became unavailable)

were then replaced by geography students from the Royal University of Phnom Penh. At the

risk of stating the obvious, the characters and abilities of the research team members were

crucial to the success or otherwise of the research (Simon, 2006, p. 165).

Photograph: Robin Biddulph

Figure 3-1: Research team in Phnom Penh, 2008. Saroth, Chanreth, Dina, Robin

In many ways the personality of the team members was more important than their intellectual

capacity. They must be the sort of people who villagers would want to talk to, and the sort of

people who would want to listen, and who would be curious enough to ask follow-up

questions and interested enough to remember and reflect on what they were told.

3.3.2 The Profile of the Research Team in the Villages

During the research we stayed in the villages overnight. This enabled us for a time to be as

involved in the life of the village as much as possible. We did not offer to pay for

Page 81: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

63

accommodation, but did pay for our food. As guests we developed relationships in the village

and particularly with the members of the households where we stayed. Typically we would

give small gifts as souvenirs of our visits and as tokens of our gratitude. This seemed to be

both basic courtesy and to fit with what is recommended in the literature (e.g. Brydon, 2006,

p. 30).

We sought to achieve a balance during our research between being seen to be approved of by

the local authorities (and therefore not a threat to them, which might cause people to avoid

us), and at the same time having enough distance from them that we might have the chance to

hear critical and dissident voices. This is part of the standard problem of both entering a

community at the same time as not being captured by „gatekeepers‟ who enable that entry

(e.g. Apentiik & Parpart, 2006, pp. 35-36; Brydon, 2006, p. 28; Momsen, 2006, p. 49; Willis,

2006, pp. 147-148).

On arrival in the village, especially for our first visit, and especially on any occasion when we

had new members in the research team, we always ensured that we went for a walk around the

village area, this was as much so that we could be observed as it was so that we could

observe. We would be in the company of the village chief, and therefore our presence was

tacitly approved. And people would have already seen us once, and possibly had their

curiosity aroused, so that when we arrived at their houses we would not be complete

strangers.

Typically, we would begin the first morning with a long interview with the village chief and

others in the village authorities. Partly this was strategic. By the end of that process they

would start to tire of us, and any desire they had to follow us around and monitor us would be

exhausted. Furthermore, by dividing the team of four to work as either pairs or individuals we

were effectively beyond the resources of the village authorities to monitor. Having said that

we made efforts to insulate ourselves from the oversight of the authorities in order to ensure

that we gave ourselves the best chance of hearing critical voices, it is also worth noting as an

aside that deputy village chiefs in each of the villages were clearly the men with the best

relationships with higher levels in the ruling party hierarchy, and were also the source of some

of the most critical comments we heard.

It is not, of course, certain, that deliberately being seen in the company of the authorities was

the best strategy for ensuring that we also heard critical voices. However, my reasoning was

that given the hierarchies and formalities of visiting a Cambodian village that distancing

ourselves from the authorities might have made people reluctant to be seen confiding in us.

By making ourselves as respectable as possible we tried to ensure that talking to us was not

seen or experienced as a seditious or dangerous activity. It was then up to us to win people‟s

confidence such that we could get the fullest and frankest possible answers from them.

Our selection of a place to stay involved a similar balancing act. Often in a village there is a

senior woman who is not in practice an everyday participant in the work of the authorities, but

who is formally involved and recognised as one of them. We succeeded in staying with just

such a woman in Buon. In Bey, however, we were immediately adopted by the deputy village

chief and his wife: they claimed that nobody else in the village would be able to cook food

good enough for us and insisted we stay with them.

During interviews we always explained that our work was to enable Robin to write a book

about people‟s life in rural Cambodia so that people in Britain and Sweden can know about it.

We always insisted that we were not going to help anybody and were nothing to do with any

development project. It is unlikely that this was completely believed, indeed the commune

chief responsible for Buon village was quite explicit in saying that he knew that we had to say

Page 82: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

64

this, but that in the end we would be providing assistance, or telling somebody else to provide

assistance. Presumably at least some of the people we interacted with acted on that

assumption and it is difficult to see what more we could have done to avoid that.

3.3.3 Conduct of Interviews

Priority was given to putting the interviewee at ease. To the extent that there is a trade-off

between getting the interviewee to talk freely, and capturing everything that they say, I

consistently prioritised the former. Decisions about how and when the interviews were

documented were also decentralised within the team. When we worked in pairs one person

typically took notes and the other asked questions. So in cases where we were carrying out

individual interviews (as opposed to administering questionnaires), researchers were given the

choice of whether they took notes during the interview or waited until afterwards. In practice,

the Cambodian team members always took notes when they interviewed respondents, and I

usually did so too. If I took notes afterwards it was more likely to be following a chance

encounter, or where a conversation had taken place when I was doing something else.

Working on the assumption that the interview itself might be sufficiently constraining for the

interviewee to result in much screening of information (as the informant kindly, and

desperately tries to second guess what the interviewer wants to hear and then to provide them

with that information), researchers were also encouraged to close their books at the end of an

interview, set their pens aside and have a bit of a chat, to give a chance for anything that was

on the interviewees mind to come out.

For this same reason I did not generally tape record interviews. This was a policy which I

modified towards the end of the study. For certain set-piece interviews, where I already

considered that I had captured the sensitive information, or where the information was not of a

sensitive nature, I recorded the interview37

. This particularly included some accounts of

village history with older villagers in Buon, and an interview with the head of the community

forestry group in Bey recapping all that we had talked about during the previous two and a

half years. This latter interview provided confirmation of the idea that people will not talk as

freely when they are recorded. Whilst he appeared as frank as usual, there were certain issues

and incidents where his position shifted, and where he specifically refused to make allegations

which he had made before. This set up certain questions which (every project must have a

finish) could not be resolved. Was it fear inspired by the recorder which made him more

cautious? Or had he been exaggerating earlier when he could speak without fear of

contradiction or consequence, and was the recorded response in fact the more honest one?

More generally, interview notes were gone through after lunch and in the evening of each day,

with the researchers reporting what they had learned and me translating and transcribing

directly into English in my notebook or (on later visits) laptop computer.

Interviews ranged in character. Generally there was a structured portion where researchers

would ask specific questions followed by a less structured portion. Chance encounters and

unexpected conversations also contributed to our data and were also on a few occasions

documented. On one evening, for example, we were washing at a remote spot at the stream

east of Bey after the water had risen to high at our normal washing place and were approached

by a villager who shared extremely sensitive information with us. On other occasions

information acquired in casual conversations could then be confirmed later in interviews.

37

All of these strategies – audio recording, taking notes during the interview, taking notes after the interview –

are recognized as legitimate options, each with relative advantages and disadvantages, in the method literature,

(e.g.Willis, 2006, pp. 149-150).

Page 83: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

65

The interviews have all been recorded in Word files and assigned a number. In my records are

the typed up notes/transcripts along with the names of the interviewee and interviewer, the

date and in the case of the village interviews the household number that we used to identify

the household in our records and maps. In the text interviews are referred to by a simple

number. All interviews referenced in the text are listed at Appendix 1 and there the date of the

interview, identity of the interviewer, gender of the interviewee and other limited descriptive

information which does not breach confidentiality is provided (c.f. Brydon, 2006, pp. 26-27).

3.3.4 Village Census and Developing Analytical Categories

The villages were assumed to be stratified and dynamic. In other words, it was not expected

that all household would have similar livelihoods. An early attempt to identify any patterns of

difference which might be used to disaggregate the village population was a village census.

This involved administering a short questionnaire at every household in the village. For every

household this told us when their household had formed in the village (i.e. when the couple

got married, or when they moved to the village); when they had occupied their current plot;

when they had built their current house; whether they owned a television and/or a motorcycle.

For every individual this told us: when and where they were born; their name and sex; their

location on the day of the census; their main activity on the day of the census (see Appendix

1). This enabled us to solve what Gould (2006, p. 82) has called one of the “classic technical

problems” of “having a systematic baseline and population or household universe for deriving

a community sample”

By comparing data on migration and livelihood activities and discussing these with our hosts

in the village we were able to make an initial disaggregation of the village population. These

disaggregations were different for each village, as for example, one of the villages had

undergone successive waves of migration which underpinned the class system and division of

labour in the village, whilst no such demographic changes were apparent in the other village.

A secondary benefit of beginning with the census was that very early in the research process

we had been in every household in the village. This meant that we could already at that stage

rely on our observations to inform our choice of case study households and interviewees and

not therefore be dependent on village „gatekeepers‟

3.3.5 Case study households

In each village, eight households were selected for more detailed study. We aimed to make

these representative of the broader population, and used the information from the village

census as well as our village maps in order to try and have a sample that drew from all

geographical areas of the villages as well as from the full range of household origins and

livelihood profiles (as far as we understood them after our initial visit).

Within the research team each person was allocated two households with whom they were to

become particularly well acquainted. This degree of familiarisation was designed to maximise

the chances of collecting information which was as full and accurate as possible. The

assumption here was that we could not hope to understand the situations and dynamics of all

sixty-six (in the case of Buon) or eighty-three (in the case of Bey at the outset of the research)

households in the villages, and that just as we had privileged knowing two villages very well

rather than, for example, thirty or forty villages less well, we also privileged knowing sixteen

households very well within those two villages. For those sixteen households, then, we have

life histories which were put together in a series of five or more interviews per household

between early 2007 and early 2009.

Page 84: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

66

The more time we spent with the case study households, the more that the relationship became

a personal one. The rules of the game become unclear and the research rested more and more

upon personal dynamics. There is a difficult balancing act within this approach. The most

fundamental problem is that the stronger the emotional bond between the researchers and the

villagers, the more there is the potential that the emotional relationship is being abused in

order to garner information. On the one hand, this was exactly what I was aiming at: to build

open and trusting relationships in order that I could obtain as much accurate information as

possible. Given this, we were scrupulous in reminding the interviewees of our role as

researchers, and that they were aware that, while we would not identify them individually,

anything that they said to us could be used in the book I was writing. In other words we

attempted to always maintain “informed consent” to the greatest extent possible (cf. Brydon,

2006, p. 26) .

3.3.6 Iterative Research Process

3.3.6.1 Inventory of Research activities

With the village census as the start point, and the case study households as a continuous

resource we had the basis for an iterative research process. The intention was that we would

begin by only focusing on livelihood issues – both how people made a living and what

particular factors enabled and constrained those livings – and that only in the later stages

would we turn our attention to the development interventions. That strategy was designed to

try and prevent answers being distorted by villagers assuming that we were actually

development providers (and that if they gave the right answers about how important and

necessary the particular products we might have to offer were that they might receive our

assistance).

In addition to this general trajectory, we were constantly identifying gaps and anomalies

which we then tried to follow up. These might be small issues identified during our reporting

and discussions at the evening of each day, and might result in a researcher going back to the

same household to ask some supplementary questions, or going to another household to

“triangulate” some piece of information that did not seem quite right. Or they might have been

longer term issues, perhaps with me reflecting on what we had learned from one visit during

my five months in Sweden, and feeding these reflections into the choice of methods and

questions for the next trip. Likewise, they might be a particular sort of enquiry, trying to work

out the supply chain in the local resin trade, or the barriers to entry for villagers wanting to

work in garment factories, or they might be a more specific question regarding a particular

period in history or a particular meeting that we had heard about but were not yet clear on.

Table 1 below gives an overview of methods used. The bold type highlights the name for the

research method that is given in the text. Comments on reliability were based on either

triangulation with other explicit research methods, or with our own observations either of

material conditions or of how (in the case of wealth ranking) judgements did or did not appear

to be influenced by personal attachments or animosities. The remainder of this section

consists of an account of the specific methods utilised on each field visit, supported by

Appendices which provide supplementary information in the form of question lists and survey

forms etc.

Page 85: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

67

Table 3-1: Summary of Village Research Methods used in Bey and Buon case studies 2006-2009

Date Activity Comments

Autumn

2006

Village census (all

households and all

individuals)

Quantitative information. Reliable. Enables good demographic

overview of population. See Appendix 2.

Autumn

2006

25% Livelihood

survey (20 households

per village)

Quantitative information. Reliable. Includes detail on

indebtedness, livelihood activities, health crises and coping

strategies, travel beyond the village. Questions at Appendix 3.

Spring

2007

10% Income and

Expenditure survey of

8 case study

households – using

MOPS questions.

Incomes and expenditures do not tally well and seem to be

under-reported. Information somewhat unreliable and to be

used cautiously. Summary information at Appendix 4.

Autumn

2007 10% Life histories of 8

case study households Rich and varied.

Spring

2008 Land and Livelihood

survey (I) Information on land holdings and yields in both villages.

Probably reliable. Also information on livelihood activities,

reliable but probably understates the number of activities.

Information on incomes in Buon – very unreliable. Questions

at Appendix 5.

Spring

2008 Mapping of selected

land claims in Bey Accurate to within 11 meters according to the Global

Positioning System. Mapped a number of claims, mainly

belonging to case study households, some of which may be

contested during the project period.

Spring

2008 Wealth ranking in

Buon by village chief

with commune

councillor

Convincing information on relative wealth of households

according to three categories.

Autumn

2008 Repeat of Village

Census in Bey and

Buon

Detailed, reliable information allowing us to document

demographic change within the course of the project. See

Appendix 2.

Autumn

2008 Land and Livelihood

survey (2) in Bey Just four questions. Provided wet season comparison with

spring activities, as well as a check on reliability of

landholding information. See Appendix 7.

Autumn

2008 Land titling impact

survey Reliable information on extent to which villagers felt tenure to

be more or less secure after titling, and whether titling had

made a difference to agricultural practice. Summary findings

at Appendix 8.

Spring

2009 Wealth ranking in Bey

with deputy village

chief

Fairly convincing information, but slightly less reliable than

the same exercise in Buon.

Spring

2009 Survey of land

transactions in Buon Detailed information on how transactions have been secured

historically, (following up respondents who reported having

bought or sold land in Land and Livelihood Survey (I).

Page 86: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

68

3.3.6.2 Field Visit 1 July and November 2006

A village census was conducted in each village (Bey in July and Buon in November38

), see

3.3.4 above and Appendix 2, and the results entered into two quantitative databases, one of

which recorded household and the other individual information. In addition to collecting this

basic information our purpose was to establish good relations with villagers, including that

research team members start to identify people in the village with whom they could develop

particularly good relations.

A 25% livelihood survey was a questionnaire administered to over twenty households in each

village (see Appendix 3 for details). This provided information by household on land

holdings, dry season and rainy season livelihood activities, including information on both

sources of money and sources of food. Questions on health were used in order to identify the

means households had at their disposal to support themselves through shocks and crises.

Questions about debt were used in order to identify the extent to which either business

development and small-scale capital accumulation or indebtedness and potential dispossession

might be underway, and also to get insights into the extent to which the villages had economic

relations beyond the village. Questions about the village were used to help us get a sense of

the sort of village this was, and questions about journeys to other locations were used to get a

sense of the degree of and reasons for mobility within households.

3.3.6.3 Field Visit 2, Spring 2007

During this second visit, based on the results of the village censuses, the eight case study

households were identified in each village, aiming to represent a cross-section of different

sorts of household in the village, especially regarding diverse ways of making a living and

differing degrees of wealth and poverty.

In order to attempt to quantify information on incomes and expenditure that we could

compare with other existing surveys, we used the sections of the questionnaire used by the

Cambodia Development Resource Institute (CDRI) Moving Out of Poverty Study (MOPS)

(Fitzgerald & Sovannarith, 2007) which related to income and expenditure. The validity of

this was limited by the fact that the original study did not have clear protocols regarding how

to deal with responses which gave widely divergent incomes and expenditures, and that we

encountered just such divergences from some of our respondents. Nevertheless, this did give

us some insights into the economies of the case study households (see Appendix 4).

3.3.6.4 Field Visit 3 September 2007

The main task at this stage was to compose life histories of the eight case study households, to

help us understand their long-term livelihood trajectories, and also to build up an account of

village history complemented by interviews with older villagers. At this stage we began to

focus a little more on the interventions in our interviews and conversations, having up to that

point tending to avoid them and focus on discussions of livelihood.

3.3.6.5 Field Visit 4, January 2008

By now we had from our contacts with the case study households quite strong suspicions of

what was and was not important in household livelihoods, however, we sought to obtain

confirmation through data on all households in the village, including if possible reliable

quantifications. A Land and Livelihood Questionnaire (see Appendix 6) included information

38

The first trip in July 2006 included only a research trip to Bey, with a two-day reconnaissance visit followed

by a week-long stay. The decision to adopt a second village was made after I returned to Sweden, so I made an

extra trip to Cambodia so that I could incorporate the second village in that first rainy season.

Page 87: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

69

on land holdings and yields which appeared quite reliable and gave us insights to the

importance of agriculture in the two villages; a „livelihood matrix‟ enabled us to tick off

which household members had participated in which activities during the previous year.

Questions about income were administered in Buon. As a check we also conducted a Wealth

Ranking exercise with the village chief. There were huge discrepancies between the reported

incomes and the wealth ranking. On the basis of our own knowledge and judgement, the

village chief‟s assessments were more reliable than the financial information we got from

interviewees. These findings, then, could only be used with the utmost caution if at all, as they

seemed to be biased by better off households under-reporting their incomes.

3.3.6.6 Field Visit 5, October 2008

The village census was repeated in both villages, enabling comparison with the censuses taken

two years earlier in July 2006 in Bey and October 2006 in Buon. Photographs of all houses

and all available household members were taken as a supplementary documentary record.

The Land Titling Impact Survey in Buon enabled us to compare the impacts expected to

accrue from systematic land titling to those actually experienced. The simple survey consisted

of just three yes/no questions. 1. Do you currently worry that your land could be taken from

you? 2. Were you worried before titling that your land could be taken from you? 3. Have you

changed the way you farm since you received your title? Wherever there were anomalous

answers, those were followed up for clarification. Where respondents answered yes to

question 3, a crucial element of the justification for land titling, follow up was carried out to

ascertain whether the land titling was a causal factor in the changes in agricultural practice.

In Bey a land and livelihood survey was conducted. This was to gather information about

landholdings, area farmed and yields, and provided a direct comparison between the 2008

agricultural season and the 2007 agricultural season. Villagers were also asked about their

main source of income.

3.3.6.7 Field Visit 6, March 2009

In Buon, all households who had reported buying or selling land in the land and livelihood

questionnaire were interviewed in order to ascertatin information about the land market in Bey

before and subsequent to land titling.

In Bey, a wealth ranking exercise was conducted with the assistance of the deputy village

chief.

3.4 Conduct of National Study

3.4.1 Approach: Adopting and Adapting Bebbington

According to Bebbington‟s presecription, a development geography of intervention would

consist of three analytical moves:

1. Trace the uneven geographies of poverty and livelihood under conditions of

capitalist expansion and contraction, explaining how these are produced.

2. Trace and explain the emergence of uneven geographies of intentional intervention.

3. Analyse the interactions between these geographically uneven processes of immanent

and intentional development. (Bebbington, 2004, p. 726)

For the purpose of the thesis there was no need for the concern to span as ambitiously to

produce a geography of “poverty and livelihood”. Rather, the first step was a national

Page 88: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

70

geography of tenure insecurity in Cambodia. The geographies of intentional intervention,

systematic land titling and community forestry, constituted the second step. Thirdly and

finally, the interaction between the „problem‟ of tenure insecurity and the „solutions‟ of

community forestry and systematic land titling was analysed, starting with the simple matter

of examining the extent to which there was geographical congruence between the problem and

the posited solutions.

3.4.2 Database Access for National Case Study

The data used to construct the national case study was a combination of primary sources in the

form of interviews with key stakeholders, secondary sources in the form of existing literature

– principally „grey literature‟ and newspaper reports – and databases. Effectively there were

three phenomena to be mapped: tenure insecurity; systematic land titling; community forestry.

In each case, securing interviews with relevant informants, and accessing relevant literature

proved relatively unproblematic. These provided the basis for a narrative account of the

geographies. In order to adequately map these geographies, however, I needed more

comprehensive GIS-linked databases. These existed for all three geographies that I was

attempting, but accessing those proved problematic.

Table 3-2: Database and Map Access for National Case Study.

Data Database owner Access39

Implications

Tenure

Insecurity

NGO Forum of

Cambodia

Access to reports, but not to

database on grounds of

confidentiality.

Analytical categories used in the

report do not tally with my

analysis so difficult to use. Access

to full database may not solve this.

Community

Forestry

(CF)

National Forestry

Administration

National map but not yet

the database that underpins

it.

Gives clear picture of location of

CF but not of the relation to

quality of forest/deforestation.

Systematic

land titling

Ministry of Land

Management

Urban Planning

and Construction

Have obtained a map down

to district level, but not the

database that underpins it.

Map only provides detail down to

district level, whereas patterns of

distribution are more interesting at

more detailed level.

Source: Author’s derivation.

3.5 Ethics and Anonymity

As explained above, we strove not to wake false expectations amongst villagers, both by

telling a clear and simple story about why we were in the village (Robin works at a university

and is writing a book about rural Cambodia so that people in England and Sweden can

understand more about life here), and by explicitly repeating that we would not be helping in

any way, including that we would not be attracting others to assist in the village.

We also made it clear that whilst anything that was said we would use as material for our

writing, that we would not use individual‟s names. We have respected this promise, and we

have also further protected the identities of villagers and of the villages by concealing the

names of the villages and the communes in which they are situated. This means that the

substantial photographic record I have of the villages, as well as the painstakingly drawn

maps of the villages have not been used in this thesis.

39

All data owners were cooperative and in principle willing to consider sharing more information. Ongoing work

on databases, and a lack of time allocated by me to follow up with relevant owners to get the appropriate

permissions were the reasons access was not fuller.

Page 89: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

71

This should be considered an extra precaution, and certainly not a watertight one. Anyone

who has been involved in our work, including from senior government officials, to local

authorities to noodle shop owners can easily find out where we have been if they do not

already know. The real protection for informants is the fact that information in this thesis is

not surprising or new to anybody who is directly affected by it. We did receive one or two

pieces of information that could have proved incendiary and those we have not shared.

Nevertheless, commonsense and the cautions in the methodological literature, suggest that it

is impossible to know what might prove to be controversial at a later stage, and that it is

therefore sensible to protect identities to the extent possible (Brydon 2006).

My own road to hell paved with good intentions has related to consultation with development

professionals and government officials working on the interventions discussed in this thesis.

Good ethical practice would have included sharing drafts with them in good time before this

thesis was published. Failure to do so was entirely because of the difficulty I had in writing

drafts of sufficient standard in good time to circulate. I did make a presentation at the

Community Based Natural Resource Management Learning Institute offices in Phnom Penh

in March 2009 to people in the community forestry sector where most of my most

controversial and critical findings were shared, and discussed. However, I did not manage to

organise anything comparable for people involved in systematic land titling. The thesis will be

circulated to people involved in both interventions, and their comments will be considered and

given due weight in any subsequent publications relating to this research.

3.6 Limitations

The events of our first morning in Bey meant that in some respects the inception phase lasted

barely a day, rather than lasting a whole year. The consequence was that the project had from

the beginning a double-focus rather than the single-issue, single-location start point that had

been envisaged. There had been a trade-off between depth and breadth of coverage here. The

enhanced breadth has meant that the two villages can be mobilised to construct a case that

engages with issues affecting both halves of the dichotomised rural Cambodian landscape

agricultural rice plains and more or less forested uplands. However, this has meant that my

resources have been spread more thinly with regard to engaging with the respective

agriculture and forestry sectors, and the histories and geographies of interventions in those

sectors.

The structure of the research, with a month‟s field research in Cambodia, followed by five

months of writing and analysis and reflection in Sweden, had different implications in each

village. In Bey, where the period 2006-9 represented a period of significant upheavals at the

village level, and where much information was controversial and not readily shared, stretching

the research over a three year period had clear advantages. Visible changes could provide the

impetus for questions (as for example certain families built larger houses while others

remained in fairly miserable conditions), and we could trace events over the months it took for

them to unfold (as the provincial authorities undertook to review the protests made by the

villagers against their evictions, and then abandoned that investigation whilst shedding light

on the events that had set the process in motion). The repeated visits over time increased the

chances of obtaining interviews with certain people including the well-connected businessman

who had direct responsibility for the forest concession in the area of Bey. Effectively it meant

that I had six chances to try and arrange an interview with him – and it was on the fifth of

these six that I succeeded in doing so. Likewise, at village level, where people may be

protecting information, stretching the research over three years has advantages. People are

very happy to tell what they think you already know, and are unlikely to remember what they

told you six months previously. By hinting that I had picked up information from a meeting

Page 90: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

72

with officials elsewhere, or giving the impression that I was already informed about a

particular deal (and perhaps because issues become less controversial with time), I often

obtained information in one visit that I had not been able to obtain in a previous one.

Buon, on the other hand was not subject to dramatic changes during the research period, at

least not at the village level: the village had undergone dramatic changes in the decade before

we arrived, and it seemed on the threshold of other quite different changes, but 2006-9 was an

interim of relative calm. The extended time span did give us an opportunity to witness some

of the dynamics within households, countering an implicit weakness in our approach of

dealing mainly with the household as a unit, and particularly highlighting some of the crucial

gender dynamics. Overall, though, it is likely that our understanding of the situation in Buon

(unlike that in Bey) could have been enhanced by spending a longer period of unbroken

research there, rather than being disrupted by half a dozen sets of entry and departure rituals.

None of the national data sets currently available provides a comprehensive overview of

tenure security in Cambodia. The content of supplementary interviews gives strong support to

the geography of tenure insecurity outlined in this report. Access to an updated land dispute

database might also have indicated whether there is any beginning of change to the broad

trends established.

As noted above, an important limitation relates to engagement with the officials, agency staff

and consultants working in community forestry and systematic land titling in Cambodia

during the closing stages of the thesis preparation. In addition to my own inability to meet

deadlines I set myself, contacts with systematic land titling appear to have been hampered by

the ongoing investigation into the World Bank support for LMAP. I sent questions to people

supporting land titling, to elicit their views in relation to main lines of argument generated in

the thesis, but only one „person close to the LMAP project‟ answered the questions, whilst the

only other response was a polite apology for the inability of World Bank staff and consultants

to answer (see Appendix 9 for the list of questions and the World Bank response).

3.7 Summary

The question of the relationship between property rights interventions in Cambodia and the

lives and livelihoods of rural people who they were designed to assist has been addressed by

means firstly of a „geography of development intervention‟ incorporating a national

geography of tenure insecurity and geographies of the implementation of community forestry

and systematic land titling, and secondly through the means of two village studies,

implemented between 2006 and 2009, which described villagers‟ livelihoods, explained the

actors and processes shaping those livelihoods, and then reported the differences made to lives

and livelihoods by the respective community forestry and systematic land titling interventions.

The three chapters that follow present the findings from these studies at national and village

level.

Page 91: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

73

4. The National Case Study

4.1 Introduction

This chapter contributes to the overall enquiry of the thesis into the relationship between

property rights interventions and rural livelihoods by investigating the relationship between

the (immanent development) geography of tenure insecurity and the (intentional development)

geographies of systematic land titling and community forestry. It relies primarily on

secondary sources, complemented by interviews carried out during field research between

2006 and 2009. On occasion these are supplemented by earlier direct observations 40

.

The chapter begins with a historical background to Cambodia, culminating in the transition of

the 1990s and the (re-)consolidation of power by the current Prime Minister. The geography

of tenure insecurity discusses both the distribution of tenure insecurity in rural Cambodia, and

the political and economic factors which shaped that distribution. The geographies of the

respective interventions, systematic land titling and community forestry, likewise discuss the

distribution and the factors which shaped that distribution. In order to complete the

geographical analysis at the national scale there is a discussion of the “mutually constitutive

interactions” (Bebbington, 2000, p. 515) between the “geography of immanent development”

of tenure insecurity and the “geography of intentional development” of the tenure security

interventions. Finally, the chapter is summarised.

4.2 Historical Background

4.2.1 Rural Inertia in Cambodian History

David Chandler‟s History of Cambodia gives prominence to four themes: the effects of its

location between Vietnam and Cambodia; the relationship of twentieth century Cambodia to

its past, and particularly to the Angkor period; “the pervasiveness of patronage and

hierarchical terminology in Cambodian thinking, politics and social relations”; “the inertia

that seems to be characteristic of rural society” (Chandler, 1992, pp. 1-2, my italics). All four

of these themes remain resonant in contemporary Cambodia and can readily be traced into the

discussions in this thesis.

Chandler is cautionary regarding the apparent continuities of rural life in Cambodia.

Commentators mention the similarity of the rural scenes depicted on the temples of Angkor

Wat (built between 800 and 1300) and the rural Cambodia of today. In terms of everyday

practices, the few detailed studies which have been carried out have supported this41

. Chandler

40

Made during the time I lived in Cambodia, 1991-2001, or during visits I made there during the time between

moving to Sweden in 2001 and commencing doctoral research there in 2006. 41

Academic studies of rural Cambodia appeared during the 1960s. Jean Delvert was a french geographer whose

1961 doctoral dissertation Le Paysan Cambodgien (1961) attempted a detailed account of peasant life. Just prior

to this the American anthropologogist May Ebihara had completed twelve months of field work in a village just

Page 92: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

74

affirms that Cambodia‟s “rural technology” has remained largely unchanged “until very

recently”. Certainly in the 18 years since I have been acquainted with rural Cambodia many of

the things that had been continuous for centuries have changed. Milling rice by hand was the

norm two decades ago, but is rarely if ever seen now, as most villages have at least one

household with a petrol fuelled milling machine where people pay to have their rice milled.

Oxcarts had wooden wheels for centuries, but in the past decade almost all of these have been

replaced by car or tractor wheels. However, our readings of studies from the 1990s (Ferguson,

1994; T. Mitchell, 1995; Porter et al., 1991) should warn us about the dangers of generalising

such continuities into a picture of unchanged, undisturbed agricultural rural isolation, and this

is also Chandler‟s main point. He argued that every one of his thirteen chapters represented a

major transformation in Cambodian life and that:

The notion of changelessness is a myth or at least an oversimplification of events, but it has

persisted for too long among students of Cambodian history and among Cambodians who

make a virtue of a conservative point of view (Chandler, 1992, pp. 2-3).

When Chandler identifies the importance of the relationship to the past, this is not simply a

historian prioritising his own subject. The temples of Angkor Wat provide a symbolic

reminder that Cambodia stood at the centre of a powerful empire between the ninth and

thirteenth centuries, controlling vast tracts of land that are now in the territory of Thailand and

Vietnam. Since the colonial promotion of this stage of Cambodian history as a central part of

the construction of national identity (Edwards, 2008), Angkor Wat has appeared as the central

symbol on every one of the five national flags that have been adopted during Cambodia‟s

tumultuous and sometimes disastrously nationalist post-independence history.

4.2.2 Colonial Influences

French colonialism was not only central in the construction of a national Cambodia identity,

but also in the survival of the Cambodian state itself. Throughout the „dark ages‟ from the fall

of Angkor in the fourteenth century up to colonial times the struggles for power in Cambodia

were inevitably between factions supported respectively by Vietnam and Thailand. Each

victory led to deals whereby the victorious faction granted its supporters in the neighbouring

country land or influence in Cambodia. Had France not intervened Cambodia would quite

possibly not have survived as a nation into the twentieth century (Osborne, 1997, p. 175).

Cambodia first concluded a treaty with France in 1864, and became a fully-fledged

protectorate in 1883 (Chandler, 1992, pp. 141-144). The main historical sources privilege

events at court and allow few glimpses of rural life, except in those rare periods when the

peasantry became an actor in national politics through organised revolt, such as 1884-6

during the period of insurrection after the protectorate was established (Osborne, 1997, pp.

206-231) and the 1916 riots against French policies on compulsory labour and the abuse of

those policies when implemented by the Khmer administration (Osborne, 1978). Otherwise,

even French colonial officials complained of knowing very little about the rural areas of the

country, including not knowing how many people lived there or who had what rights to land

(Chandler, 1992, p. 147).

Much of French policy focused on establishing new institutions in rural areas. Some of the

institutions created by the French are still found in modified form today, notably the system of

south of Phnom Penh which she called „Svay‟ and which was subsequently documented in her unpublished but

widely circulated and influential PhD dissertation (Ebihara, 1968).

Page 93: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

75

forest concessions and the commercial rubber plantations in the eastern central province of

Kampong Cham. Some of the reforms tried and failed under the French, such as

democratically elected local councils and the establishment of a cadastral register are now

being repeated by the modern development industry. Chandler‟s analysis of the early French

„will to improve‟ in the form of abolition of slavery and introducing land ownership rights

was that the French vision was of “a liberated Cambodian yeomanry responding rationally to

market pressures” (Chandler, 1992, p. 144). One of the Cambodian Princes, King Norodom‟s

favourite son Yukanthor, went into exile in protest at the French policies and claiming that

they, by creating property had created the poor, which Chandler judged “largely true” (1992,

p. 147).

Researchers are beginning to mine the national archives in Phnom Penh, and the French

colonial archives (in Aix-en-Provence and elsewhere) to give a full account of the French

reforms in Cambodia42

. Margaret Slocomb‟s (2007) history of the development of

Cambodia‟s rubber plantations will hopefully be the fore-runner of a number of works on land

management and politics during the colonial period.

4.2.3 Post-Independence

Independence from French rule came to Cambodia twice. On 13 March 1945, at Japanese

prompting, Cambodia declared itself independent, invalidating all existing Franco-Cambodian

agreements. The defeat of the Japanese in the war brought the French back to power, but only

following negotiations that yielded new arrangements between the countries. Chandler

(Chandler, 1992, p. 172) noted that, “The agreement promised Cambodia a constitution and

the right to form political parties, but French control remained in such fields as finance,

defense, and foreign affairs.”

In the following years Cambodia‟s newly-formed political parties were frustrated in their bid

to persuade France to grant independence. The young King Sihanouk, however, utilizing his

ability to mobilize mass demonstrations and his superior relations with the colonial power,

was able to gain credit for the achievement of independence in 1953. During this period,

Sihanouk gradually learned how to use his increased personal popularity and power to

extinguish the pluralistic electoral politics that had been introduced in 1946 and establish his

own personal control (Chandler, 1992, p. 184). Summing up the failure of the 1946

constitution to usher in a Western political system Osborne wrote (no doubt with one eye on

contemporary events):

Most fundamentally, the constitution assumed that a population that had never experienced

anything remotely like democracy could quickly adopt the attitudes and practices of a largely

alien system (Osborne, 1994, p. 59).

Abdicating in favour of his father in order to become Prime Minister, Sihanouk (now Prince

Sihanouk) presided over a one-party system of government. All political hues were welcome

in the party (which was both „royal‟ and „socialist‟), and even within government, but anyone

voicing opposition was likely to disappear from the scene (Kiernan, 2002, p. 484). This period

(1955-70) constituted the formative years of the older members of the post-1993 ruling elite:

it would, with its patronage, sponsorship of development, “cancer of corruption” (Osborne,

1994, p. 137) vote-buying and manipulation of elections (e.g. Osborne, 1994, p. 187) and

42

In Phnom Penh I was, confidentially, given the outlines of one edited book involving international and

Cambodian scholars that would attempt to commemorate the hundred years that had passed since the

establishment of the cadastral system and the concession system.

Page 94: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

76

underlying brutal menace, be their most recent memory of „peace‟ or „normality‟ before civil

war and worse engulfed the country.

Sihanouk cultivated friendships within the non-aligned movement and attempted to maintain

Cambodia as an „island of peace‟ in the face of the overtures from both sides in the USA war

in Vietnam. This proved an impossible balancing act and arguably the decline in his fortunes

in domestic politics could be traced back to when he broke off US military aid which up to

1963 had constituted a 15% subsidy to the national budget (Chandler, 1992, pp. 201-204). In

1970, while Sihanouk was away overseas, a coup by a right-wing pro-American faction led to

the creation of the Khmer Republic under former police chief and Prime Minister Lon Nol.

His urban-based regime underwent a five-year civil war in which a countryside-based

resistance comprising royalists and communists eventually triumphed, marching into Phnom

Penh and evacuating it (Chandler, 1992, pp. 204-208). During the three years, eight months

and 20 days of Khmer Rouge rule that followed, virtually the entire population was resettled

in the countryside (Kiernan, 1996, 2002, pp. 485-486). Forced labour, communal living and

starvation rations were standard43

. This work regime, overlain with successive purges, first of

external enemies before 1977 and then of (real and imagined) enemies from within after 1977,

led to a death toll that is most commonly estimated at about 1.7 million out of a population of

7 million. This is alleged to have been the highest per capita rate of killing in modern world

history (Ledgerwood, 2002) and meant that almost everyone lived with extreme fear, and that

most lost immediate family to either execution or forced starvation.

Purges in the Khmer Rouge Eastern Zone were met with resistance by military units there

who mutinied and after prolonged fighting took flight to Vietnam. They returned as part of a

Vietnamese led force of 150 000 on 25th

December 1978, and in a matter of days they had

driven the Khmer Rouge out of power and taken over the country (Kiernan, 2002, pp. 486-

487). It was from these mutineers that the country‟s leadership during the 1980s and 1990s

was taken, including the current Prime Minister Hun Sen, who became Foreign Minister at the

age of 28, and then in 1984 at the age of 32 succeeded Chan Si as Prime Minister. The

overthrow of the Khmer Rouge did not herald peace in Cambodia. For geopolitical reasons,

the United States and China, supported amongst others by regional allies in Thailand and

Singapore, wished to oppose the new Vietnamese- and Soviet- supported government in

Phnom Penh and were prepared to rehabilitate and support the Khmer Rouge in order to do so

(Chandler, 1992, p. 231). Cambodia therefore endured an extended period of isolation and

guerrilla warfare as US and Chinese opposition to Vietnam and the Soviet Bloc took the form

of UN recognition of the Khmer Rouge and their allies as the rightful government of

Cambodia. As a result of the government‟s need to defend against this internationally

sponsored guerrilla resistance, local government and authority remained militarised and

hierarchical tendencies in Cambodian governance remained firmly in place, as, for example,

Slocomb (2001) has outlined in her account of the role of the national defences erected in the

north-west in the nation building project of the 1980s.

Cambodia‟s international isolation became a campaigning point for the international NGO

Oxfam, who had had an office in the country since responding to the starvation conditions in

the immediate aftermath of the overthrow of the Khmer Rouge in 1979. Their country

representative Eva Mysliwiec (1988b) authored an account of the effects of isolation on

Cambodia under the same title as the campaign Punishing the Poor. The international

isolation and internationally sponsored civil war only concluded when the collapse of the

43

Although not totally standard. Vickery (1984), taking exception to what he calls the “Standard Total View”

(1984, p. 36) of the 1975-79 Khmer Rouge period has written about regional variation, instances of resistance

and exceptions to the general trends of educated people being victimised and often killed.

Page 95: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

77

Soviet Union led the major powers to conclude that their interests would be better served by

finding a face-saving way of switching from undermining the Cambodian state to supporting

it44

.

Timber became a key source of revenue to both government and guerrilla forces, and a key

element in their dealings with their respective Vietnamese and Thai patrons. Gottesman45

documents how as early as 1980 Vietnamese and Cambodian officials were involved in

logging, and how attempts to control this centrally were frustrated by the participation of both

provincial authorities and national officials in the trade (Gottesman, 2004, pp. 156-158). He

likewise shows how military units asserted their right to log in order to support themselves

(2004, p. 230), and how negotiating timber deals with the Thai authorities became a key part

of Cambodian government strategy to attempt to undermine the assistance being given to the

guerrilla resistance (2004, p. 291).

4.2.4 UNTAC and Cambodia’s Second Transition to Democracy

The Paris Peace Agreements signed on 23 October 1991 were the outcome of the international

realignments following the collapse of the Soviet Union and led to the creation of the United

Nations Transitional Authority in Cambodia 1992-94 (UNTAC). Over twenty thousand

international civilian and military personnel and a budget of over 4 billion US dollars were

deployed to support an UNTAC mission which would include enforcing a cease-fire,

organising demobilisation of armed factions, returning all refugees from the Thai-Cambodian

border, organising democratic elections, and establishing a permanent government. Operating

under an advisory council comprising all four of the rival factions, UNTAC was to have direct

control over five key policy areas: foreign affairs; defence; finance; public security;

information. It also had the right to investigate and sanction those parts of the administration

not directly under its control (Matheson, 2001, p. 3). The political parties that emerged under

UNTAC differed little in their stated ideologies and platforms. All proclaimed support for the

monarchy, Buddhism, and liberal democracy, and all enthusiastically welcomed the prospect

of cooperating with the international community to democratize and develop Cambodia. The

main parties were descendents of to earlier ruling factions, often featuring survivors from the

pre-1975 times. FUNCINPEC (United National Front for an Independent, Neutral, Peaceful,

and Cooperative Cambodia), led by Prince Norodom Ranariddh, was a royalist party founded

by supporters of Sihanouk‟s rule during the 1960s. The Cambodian People‟s Party (CPP), led

by Prime Minister Hun Sen, was the ruling party during the 1980s and had very largely

maintained its structures and personnel. The Buddhist Liberal Democratic Party (BLDP) led

by Son Sann was descended from the supporters of the pro-US Khmer Republic (1970-75).

Absent from that role call of recent Cambodian regimes by the time of the 1993 election were

the Khmer Rouge who withdrew from the peace process, boycotted the elections and

continued to fight a guerrilla war from their bases in Anlong Veng in northern Cambodia and

Pailin in the north-west. Operating now without the international sponsorship that they had

previously enjoyed, they intensified their logging operations and trade with Thailand in order

to finance themselves (Kiernan, 2002, p. 490).

The results of the 1993 election and subsequent formation of a government provoked

controversy. FUNCINPEC won 45 percent of the vote and CPP 38 percent, yielding 58 and

51 seats respectively. While scholars are divided regarding the legitimacy of what occurred

44

Becker (1998, pp. 437-507), a journalist who had worked in Phnom Penh before 1975, in the 2nd

Edition of her

history of modern Cambodia provides a particularly rich account of the political processes leading to peace. 45

Gottesman, working as a UN lawyer in Phnom Penh in 1992-4 stumbled across official records of government

meetings from the 1980s and wrote a valuable and highly-regarded history of that period based on those sources.

Page 96: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

78

between the announcements of the election and the formation of the new government

(Roberts, 2001, pp. 104-120; Vickery, 1999), the requirement of a two-thirds majority to

approve a new constitution meant that a coalition government was always the likely outcome

and few would disagree with the following summary:

All parties were eventually made aware that without a satisfied CPP in a position of strength,

UNTAC and Cambodia could be held hostage. Sihanouk observed that ―we have to share

power equally otherwise the violence cannot end.‖ (Roberts, 2001, p. 112).

In retrospect, UNTAC ambitions to take over the Cambodian administration, establish a

neutral civil service and thereby create a neutral and fair environment for elections were never

realistic and never came close to being achieved (Doyle, 1995, p. 35; Peou, 1997, p. 197).

Drawing conclusions for international peacekeeping Findlay (1995, p. 170) wrote that

UNTAC in Cambodia had been a “salutary reminder of the limitations of multilateral attempts

to fast-track the socio-political re-engineering of a nation-state.”

Pieterse‟s (2009) observation about the development industry principally achieving “paradigm

maintenance” rather than substantive change seemed to apply perfectly to the UNTAC

intervention: the idea of democracy was introduced and recycled, but little impact was made

regarding the substantive achievement of democracy. The new, UNTAC drafted constitution,

far from constituting Cambodia, became a piece of presentational paraphernalia. In many

respects, then, UNTAC, with its ambitious agenda, but its very limited effects (Hughes, 2009,

pp. 89-93) provided a parable about the capacity of international interventions to initiate

change in Cambodia, and an indicator of what would follow.

The partial peace that followed the elections resulted in an intensification of forest

exploitation, which became a central issue in the negotiation of power as the country

underwent the transition to a market economy. There was sufficient peace to greatly intensify

logging in ways which Le Billon (2000, p. 787) interpreted as being in line with both shadow

state theory and Southeast Asia regional developments. In those terms, logging was

“politicized and sustained the power of the army and the political elite” and “forest dwellers

were adversely affected and progressively disempowered by large scale logging”. While on

the one hand shadow state style “clientelist and corrupt governance” meant that “virtually

none” of the logging revenues went into the national accounts. On the other hand, winning the

competition for these resources and ensuring that former rivals had an (informal) economic

stake in a post-conflict landscape, was not part of an extreme predatory shadow state endgame

where the leadership attempts to undermine all formal sources of political and economic

security for the people, but rather led, Development State style, to peace and stability which

enabled the decade of investment and growth which followed from the late 1990s to the late

2000s (Le Billon, 2000). The priority which was given to logging in the personal dealings of

the shadow state/Developmental State elite was indicated by the way in which the post-

election co-prime ministers Ranariddh and Hun Sen on the day of the investiture of the new

government revoked a ban on logging exports and signed a deal with a Thai company

allowing them to export 55 000 cubic meters of round logs (Le Billon, 2002, p. 571).

Le Billon‟s comments on the international response to forest management during the 1990s,

and the effects it had, are relevant to the concerns of this thesis. The international community

was critical of the fact that the forest resource was being exploited without transparency and

without benefit to the national treasury, and advocated stronger management. According to Le

Billon (2002), the Cambodian elite co-opted this agenda and used it to both legalise its own

activities and to use logging bans to crack down on small businesses and poorer people who

were making a living from timber. Again, then, as was the case with UNTAC, national elites

were able to shape development interventions and discourses to their own objectives (good or

Page 97: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

79

bad, shadow or developmental). As we will see, however, at least at some times and in some

places, the consequences of the logging bans for poor people may have been precisely the

opposite to what Le Billon suggested, in other words, opening up rather than closing off

opportunities for small-scale operator and labourers (see Chapter 5).

4.2.5 Cambodia Today

As we have seen, beginning with Sihanouk‟s coup against the elected government in 1952,

four successive regimes in Cambodia had taken power unconstitutionally and by force prior to

the 1993 national elections. Lacking a strong sense of security and legitimacy, each regime in

turn (and to very differing extents) used state violence and killing in order to suppress real and

potential opposition in times of both war and peace. For successive generations of

Cambodians, politics has been bloody and dangerous:

A winner-takes-all political culture based on endemic distrust has impeded the development of

a civil society, stifled free expression, encouraged cronyism and violence, and exacerbated

people‘s tendency to distrust and fear those in power (Chandler, 1998, p. 43).

Understandably, therefore, politics remains a sensitive subject associated with danger in the

Cambodian countryside. This does not mean that it is never discussed, but it does mean that

people are often cautious regarding when and with whom they discuss political issues.

Certainly anybody involved in opposition politics will have included in their calculations the

risk that retribution, possibly lethal, may follow. This is not just a reflection of the specifics of

current politics, but a continuation of the situation since before Independence.

Recent political analyses examine the emergence of the current ruling group centred around

the Prime Minister Hun Sen, who became prime minister in 1984 following the death of Chan

Si and who has retained the position since46

.

Hughes (2003b) in her account of the political economy of Cambodia‟s transitions during the

1990s argued that Cambodia‟s “triple transition” from command economy to free market,

from war to peace and from authoritarian rule to democracy was dominated by the nature of

the transition from command economy to free market. Central to this transition to market, and

to what Heder (2005) has called turbo-capitalism, has been a network of commercial, military

and political interests linked to the Prime Minister. In recent years, and especially since 2004,

the Prime Minister has consolidated power in ways that have been compared with “similar

trajectory-defining periods” elsewhere in Southeast Asia47

(Heder, 2005, p. 125).

Possibly the defining feature of the new polity is the extent to which the key political

decisions are off the record and outside the mainstream political process, while huge portions

of the national economy are off-budget. A recent newspaper article on the children of

Cambodia‟s elite does not necessarily overstate the case:

Cambodia‘s official economy largely depends on garments, exports, but there is a much larger

shadow economy in which only the ruthless and the well-connected survive and prosper. ―If

you‘re doing business, you have to know someone high up, so he has your back‖, says Victor

(Marshall, 2009).

By their nature the shadow economy and shadow politics of the “shadow state” (Le Billon,

2000) are difficult to research or assess. Forests and forest management have attracted

46

Between the 1993 elections and the fighting of 1997, Hun Sen was officially the Second Prime Minister, whilst

the head of FUNCINPEC, Sihanouk‟s son Norodom Ranariddh was First Prime Minister. 47

“Philippines in the late 1940s and 1950s, Thailand, Malaysia and Singapore in the late 1950s and 1960s and in

Indonesia in the late 1960s and 1970s”

Page 98: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

80

attention because of the huge amount of money involved, but also because they are so much

more visible than other informal flows. Percentages taken off development assistance projects

or foreign investments cannot be captured by aerial photography or interviews with rural

villagers.

While it is clear, not least from the highly visible assets and lifestyles on display in the

national capital, that a super-rich (by recent Cambodian standards at least) elite has emerged

(Marshall, 2009), the relations of this class and their wealth to the rest of the country are far

less clear. Patronage payments circulating in the system might be generating some form of

informal, shadow social welfare and safety nets. Some of this is visible in the form of physical

infrastructure projects sponsored by senior figures, and is attracting interest in Cambodia from

researchers looking at the potential accountabilities involved in mass patronage on the

patrimonial side of the neo-patrimonial equation (Craig & Kimchoeun, 2009). However, there

remains little empirical basis to answer questions about the wealth circulating in the informal

economy, or about the politics of mass incorporation/exclusion in relation to that wealth.

Within the formal economy, official statistics have suggested that for the decade to 2006,

economic growth has averaged around 8% per annum (Sjöberg & Sjöholm, 2007). Poverty,

meanwhile, has been held by some to have marginally decreased, although this is contested

and at other times the same data sources have led analysts to conclude that poverty has

marginally worsened. There is, however, agreement that any benefits of growth have been

unevenly distributed leading to a society that is becoming more and more unequal. The elite

have become much richer whilst the poor have become relatively poorer (World Bank, 2006,

2007b).

The steady record of economic growth has been reflected differently in urban and rural

landscapes (as well, of course, as within them). In the capital city, Phnom Penh, there have

been rapidly rising land prices, a construction boom and, since 1996, a rapidly expanding

garment sector that has employed over 300 000 low-skilled, low-waged workers at its peak

(Salinger, 2006, p. 1)48

. The garment industry, however, is only the most formal and easily

monitored of a range of employment opportunities available to people migrating from rural

areas. The construction industry has been thriving in all urban centres, and especially in

Phnom Penh, providing a similar scale of labour opportunities to the garment industry, but

generally on more casual terms - with the gender division of labour, overlaying existing

gender relations, meaning that while young women were working 28-30 days a month and

returning to the villages en masse on pay day to hand money over to their families, young men

were much better placed to negotiate both their own terms of incorporation into the industry

and to decide when to go home and how much of their income to share. The Ministry of

Labour has reported 200 000 Cambodians working abroad in Thailand, Malaysia and South

Korea (Sakada, 2008), and especially in the case of Thailand (where agricultural work in the

north-east and construction work in the capital seem to be the main sources of employment),

this is likely to be a serious under-estimate. While the clothing industry has provided a labour-

intensive „engine of economic growth‟, tourism has provided a second engine. Despite at

times having the fastest growing tourist industry in the world and attracting increasing

numbers of foreign visitors (Chens, Sok, & Sok, 2008, p. 42), the tourist industry, focused

mainly on the Angkor temple complex in the north of the country, has fewer links with the

rest of the economy, employs few people, and tends to rely on imported goods (World Bank,

2006).

48

Makin (2006, p. 3) reported 290 000 garment factory workers in 2004, of whom 90% were women, and 72%

of those women single. She characterized them as principally rural women sending money home to households

with typically 4-9 members.

Page 99: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

81

The economic transformation of the rural landscape has been more partial. After several false

starts (with roads being „rehabilitated‟ and then rapidly deteriorating to a worse condition than

previously) there is now a comprehensive system of all-weather asphalt roads throughout the

country. Along these roads, in contrast to the early 1990s, it is common to see parcels of land

with boundaries marked by barbed wire fences or brick walls topped with broken glass. Land

prices have soared as roadside land is demanded not only for residential and business uses, but

also for speculation. The new owners are typically non-locals, not well-protected by the

locally secured informal or, as So Sokbunthoeun (2009) aptly terms them, quasi-formal

property regimes. There are therefore good reasons for them to take all available measures to

secure their property, both by physical means and by paying the fees to acquire sporadic land

titles49

.

District towns, previously little more than rural villages, are often adorned with air-

conditioned brick residences of a sort unthinkable 15 years ago. Further away from the roads,

rice field landscapes and the settlements they host often remain strikingly similar, although it

is increasingly common to find brick houses, and even brick boundary walls topped with

broken glass or barbed wire in rural villages. Forest landscapes are more likely to have been

transformed, with forests often replaced by either temporary waste lands, or by new

plantations, and with extensive ribbon development along new roads, as well as new villages.

As we have seen, intensive logging of Cambodia‟s forests generated incomes from timber that

were key to the off-budget funding of Cambodia‟s „shadow state‟ during the 1990s. However,

it seems that economic land concessions oriented towards agricultural development, but also

largely located on land officially designated as State forest, have taken over from logging

concessions as primary earners, and also that elite business interests have now migrated to a

greater degree into casinos, coastal resort development and the Phnom Penh construction

boom (Sjöberg & Sjöholm, 2007).

Within the agricultural sector, rice farming dominates the landscape physically, comprising

88% of cultivated land, while only providing 54% of crop value and 9% of GDP. Most rice

farmers have less than one hectare of rice land, and are therefore not in a position to produce a

marketable surplus (or even enough rice for their household‟s consumption). There are areas

of the country where either land holdings are larger or land is irrigated where rice farming

may be the largest part of a successful family business, however these are exceptions rather

than the rule. The idea that Cambodia should improve its agricultural productivity, and

various arguments about whether it could or should do have continued for the past decade and

a half: in that time, however, rice farming has for the most part continued to be rain-fed and

low-input rather than evolving into the more intensive, productive practice that policymakers

and developers have envisioned (Sjöberg & Sjöholm, 2007, pp. 503-507).

4.2.6 The Myth of Dependency in Contemporary Cambodia

The political „transition‟ which the United Nations‟ Transitional Authority in Cambodia 1992-

4 (UNTAC) was supposed to herald was to a large degree a tradition from one façade to

another. Cambodia transited from the appearance of State communism to the appearance of

liberal democracy. In fact, as we have seen above, the real political trajectories involved the

reassertion of power by the CPP and within the CPP by a faction around the Prime Minister.

This was within a process of competition and contestation which started long before UNTAC

and continued long after and which was little-affected by the international intervention that

49

The distinction here is between systematic land titling, where an entire community is titled en masse at the

initiative of the state, and sporadic titling, where an individual goes to the land office in order to obtain a title.

Prior to the Land Management and Administration Project (LMAP) there was only sporadic titling.

Page 100: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

82

was intended to facilitate change. In this sense, then, UNTAC serves as warning parable

regarding what an international development intervention might achieve.

The inability of international donors to make any difference to domestic Cambodian politics is

highlighted by Heder (2005). He described how the donors acquiesced in Hun Sen‟s

consolidation of power in 2004, refusing support to domestic political opponents who

criticised Hun Sen on human rights and governance grounds50

, but instead “universally”

welcoming the formation of the new coalition, partly justifying this in terms of the sphere of

influence politics: if they did not support the government then it would simply receive

unconditional support from China.

However, as I have suggested above, it is also possible to read the UNTAC process more

simply as a transition from isolation to intervention by the West. Instead of financing refugee

camps and guerilla armies on the Thai-Cambodian border, the West now sought ways to

finance the Cambodian state and the development of its people. Arguably, the real political

agenda was not about achieving peace or democracy or even development, but simply

enabling the sponsors of Cambodian conflict to exit from those positions without losing face,

in order that they could pursue improved relations with each other.

Given the scale of official development assistance (ODA) in comparison to national budgets,

it is in some ways not surprising that „aid dependence‟ began to be a theme in discussions

about Cambodia:

For the period of 1992-2000, external assistance disbursements totalled to US 3.67 billion.

Bilateral and NGO organizations provided US 2.4 billion or 64.50% of total; the balance is

financed by multi-lateral organisations; all of these accounted for 50% of total public

expenditure. From 1992-1999, ODA [Official Development Assistance] continued to increase

by an average of 9.1% annually (Chhieng, 2001).

The idea of Cambodia becoming „dependent‟ on aid was intensified by commentators who

followed Cambodia during the 1980s and drew unfavourable comparisons between the

(possibly exaggerated) level of responsibility and self-reliance demonstrated the state before

and after the UNTAC intervention (e.g. Curtis, 1994). Nevertheless, the „aid dependent‟

literature has indicated a number of ways in which intervention might feed certain

pathologies. These include: international financial assistance removing incentives for the

government to collect revenues or provide services (Chhieng, 2001); international technical

assistance substituting for and marginalizing national capacity rather than building it (Godfrey

et al., 2002); aid programs, even when claimed to be “national” or nationally-owned, being

piecemeal, uncoordinated and tending to pay civil servants to neglect their government job in

favour of the donor program (Godfrey et al., 2002); policy instruments such as Financial

Policy Frameworks, Medium Term Expenditure Frameworks, Poverty Reduction Strategies

and other “national” planning documents introduced to Cambodia during the last decade

providing legitimate access points for donors rather than in any way guiding the development

of the nation (Biddulph, 2001b). Overall, though, this narrative of „dependence‟ is highly

misleading. The idea of dependence here is misleading: the fact that it has been sustained for

as long as it has is surely partly symptomatic of the post-colonial and „Development‟

imaginary which sees poor countries as resembling small children with rich countries in loco

parentis (Baaz, 2002). As we have already seen, the determinants of Cambodian politics and

50

Heder notes the irony of the fact that having refused support to the domestic opposition that western donors

and organisations released “a flurry of highly critical donor and other assessments of Cambodia‟s governance,

poverty reduction and human rights protection, slamming previous Hun Sen governments‟ lack of political will

to achieve any of these goals” (Heder, 2005, p. 124).

Page 101: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

83

economic are long-term; much of the crucial political and economic action in the country

happens off-stage in the “shadows”. Foreign money and foreign advisors have been allowed

to colonise many of the more visible and formal areas of public administration and policy, but

to imagine that Cambodia is dependent on this is an unwarranted leap. Caroline Hughes in a

recent book argues that the informal economy has been a key source of funds enabling

Cambodia‟s leadership to resist donor pressures:

There is no doubt that the amount of unofficial funding available to the government, at least

on a temporary basis, considerably outweighs the amount of international aid that might be

cut by donors determined to establish conditions that the Cambodian government repeatedly

fails to meet (Hughes, 2009, pp. 161-162).

If the control of the informal economy makes for shadow state activities of extreme

enrichment, however, it has also been accompanied by Developmental State achievements in

terms of macro-economic and political stability as well as “the delivery of respectable figures

in terms of economic growth, human development and poverty reduction” (Hughes, 2009, p.

163). With China offering substantial funds, and with the prospect of offshore oil in the Gulf

of Thailand, there is every prospect that the Cambodian leadership will continue to be able to

continue to do its key business in the shadows, and to pursue strategies of its own choosing.

4.3 Immanent Development: A Geography of Tenure Insecurity in Cambodia

In Chapter 2 we saw how the literature on property rights interventions focuses on tenure

security as the fundamental element leading to potential benefits from those interventions. For

an individual rights holder, it is the security of tenure which gives the confidence to invest in

land, gives credit suppliers the confidence to lend to the land-owner, and which give buyers

and sellers the confidence to transact land in the market. For common property rights holders

it is the ability to exclude others from the land and its resources which provides the

fundamental difference between the potentials of a functioning common property regime and

the almost inevitable tragedies of open access regimes. In Chapter 3 we saw how the threat to

villagers‟ security of tenure in Bey prompted an interest in tenure security, and attempts to

guarantee it, in this thesis.

Immanent development, meanwhile, a synonym for political economy or political ecology,

was characterised as embodying the struggles between Development and development (Hart,

2001, 2010), or between the disembedding and re-embedding tendencies inherent in

capitalism (Polanyi, 2001). In taking up Bebbington‟s (2000, 2003, 2004) proposition to

„map‟ immanent development in terms of poverty and livelihoods, it was therefore logical, as

I explained in Chapter 3, that in this thesis tenure insecurity should be the immanent

development variable to be mapped.

4.3.1 The Emergence of Tenure Insecurity as a Political Problem

It was in the mid-1990s, at the juncture where the CPP leadership was establishing its primacy

over its coalition partners/rivals at the same time as finalising the victory over the Khmer

Rouge that the issue of rural land tenure security began to be prominent in Cambodia.

Political analysts, observing the gradual success of the government‟s defections policy looked

for other potential sources of instability51

. Land disputes were often presented as the most

likely source of any future troubles, with the problem being made visible by newspaper

51

I remember reading articles to this effect at different times between 1996 and 2000 and also to meeting risk

analysis consultants looking at tenure insecurity in the context of political stability, although I have not been able

to track down specific references to these.

Page 102: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

84

reports of land grabs, angry speeches by the Prime Minister and a stream of victims of forced

eviction camping outside the parliament building and requesting help (Ear, 2005; Hay, 2007).

In 1999 reviewing land issues literature, Williams wrote:

During the course of preparation of this review, local Cambodian newspapers carried almost

daily stories of court cases and protests by farmers' dispossessed by officials and military

officers who have misused their authority. Sales of public property for personal gain,

including ministerial head offices, schools and land within national parks were openly

reported and unprosecuted (S. Williams, 1999, p. 3).

The first comprehensive documentation of an individual case was a study of land

expropriation by local authorities in north-west Cambodia (Kato, 1999). In that case, refugees

repatriated from the Thai-Cambodian border had been allocated land and land titles near a

village in Battambang province. However, a portion of the land had been sold to unidentified,

non-local buyers. The returnees had received official titles from the cadastral office, and also

had a letter recognizing these as legitimate from the commune52

chief. However, they were

unable to farm the land that they had been allocated. Informal militia recruited by the

unknown „buyer‟ forcibly kept them off the land. Despite high profile support from various

national and international organisations, and the unquestionable legitimacy of their claim, the

returnees never gained access to their land. Various rounds of protest came to nothing and

eventually disintegrated as some families accepted payments from the buyer‟s agents and

others drifted away in search of other land and livelihood opportunities53

.

This first case typified the way that land disputes would come to be seen: pitting groups of

poor people against powerful but often shadowy alliances between private businesses and

senior political or military figures. The depiction of land disputes as the result of the predatory

activities of business and military elites operating with the complicity of the authorities was

not only promoted by NGOs and the media. The Prime Minister himself repeatedly

characterised land disputes in precisely the same way, and presented himself as a champion of

the poor in such struggles.

...some well-to-do government officials put up fences on land for speculation ... and they are

no ordinary people but people with power and rich merchants ... I will never side with them

but support our people‘s claim ...I will inform the villagers to take back their land with my full

support ...(the Cambodian) people must have the priority to development, not the investors

(Sen, 1998, p. 4).

And, employing a formulation that would be repeated verbatim in successive speeches, (Sen,

2000a, p. 4, 2000b, p. 4):

I have taken personal interest in addressing many cases of illegal land grabbing. The RGC

has recently confiscated many plots of land grabbed by some powerful, crooked officials and

given them back to the state or to their previous owners (Sen, 1999b, p. 6).

During the following decade a number of NGOs involved in land issues began compiling data

on land disputes. While none of these were comprehensive, they did yield some statistics and

analysis. Cooper‟s (2002) review of the reports from four NGOs with major land case loads in

52

Commune is the lowest formal level of government in Cambodia, and the next administrative level up from the

village. 53

After Kato‟s original study highlighting the case I was able to follow it up when I evaluated the development

NGO supporting the villagers in 2000 (when I stayed with the village chief in the village) and on later

evaluations of the effectiveness of support provided by human rights and legal aid NGOs in land conflict cases

(Biddulph, 2003a).

Page 103: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

85

2001 suggested that allowing for some overlap that perhaps there were about 240 cases pitting

200 000 poor people against powerful opponents in large scale land disputes .

A recent analysis of cases reported in the media in 2008 by the NGO Forum on Cambodia‟s

Land Information Centre (LIC), found that over 80% of the disputes were long-standing and

remain unsolved (Land Information Centre, 2009). In this sample cases on average involved

200 complainants, and average land size under contest was 50 hectares (Land Information

Centre, 2008, 2009).

Research findings confirm the profile of the protagonists reproduced by the NGOs and the

Prime Minister. The LIC analysis was based on information from 107 cases54

and found that

the defendants were in 30% of cases private companies; 21% military authorities; 21%

unknown; 20% local (up to district) authorities; 4% provincial/national authorities; 3%

„community‟ and 2% police (Land Information Centre, 2009, p. 8). An earlier study looking at

rural landlessness found that 74% of households who reported having had their land taken

from them, identified the provincial administration or the military authorities as responsible

(Biddulph, 2000c, p. 2). The exact classifications, however, may be of limited value given that

the identity of buyers is often quite uncertain. Private sector actors will need to recruit the

support of civilian authorities and/or a credible security force, and may prefer to keep their

identity concealed behind those of their local clients; conversely, if a member of the

authorities, civilian or military, is engaged as a private investor they may prefer to conceal this

by implying that they are agents for another, wealthier, better-connected actor.

A study completed in 2006 looked in detail at seven land in two provinces in Cambodia, and

sought to learn more about the way in which collective action was triggered and the extent to

which it might be “harnessed to increase the responsiveness of the state to the needs of the

poor” (Center for Advanced Study, 2006, p. 8). Collective strategies were focused on

patrimonial rather than legal-administrative solutions: in other words “villagers employed a

variety of tactics in pursuit of a single strategy, that is, to get a powerful administrative

decision maker to intervene on their behalf” (Center for Advanced Study, 2006, p. 37). The

authors found that frustration with the disputes was giving rise to “uncertainty, frustration and

political pressure” (Center for Advanced Study, 2006, p. 38).

The sense that land grabs continue to represent a threat to social stability continues up to the

present time. Leading human rights organizations in Cambodia, both international

(UNOHCHR, 2007) and national (see Chakrya, 2009; Licadho, 2009) continue to highlight

land rights abuses as central to their case loads. A case reported in the media at the time of our

final field visit in March 2009 was illustrative of both the violent resentment that may be

generated by land rights abuses, and of the potential for them to rebound on politicians. In

March 2009 a security guard in Phnom Penh violently attacked the 70 year old senator whose

house he was guarding. The guard had owned land on the outskirts of the city, but it had been

taken from him. The senator had not personally been involved in the case, but the guard was

overwhelmed with anger and frustration towards all high level officials and vented this

general frustration against that whole class on the nearest available target (Macan-Markar,

2009). The sense that land disputes are a politically flammable issue that could potentially

lead to social unrest is, of course, balanced by the fact that after over a decade of disputes,

despite the sense of anger and injustice, and despite daily national newspaper headlines and

the continuation since the 1990s of the succession of dispossessed villagers camping outside

the parliament building or the Prime Minister‟s residence to plead their cases, there have been

no serious breakdowns of law and order. Grievances have remained but the aggrieved have

54

Total sample was 173 cases. Information on defendant available for 107 cases.

Page 104: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

86

been effectively pacified, often having been adopted by a succession of NGOs each of whom

made a series of interventions on their behalf but ultimately moved on to other cases

(Biddulph, 2003a).

4.3.2 Landlessness was not a Tenure Security Issue

Another problem which came to prominence at the same time as land disputes in rural areas,

and was often linked with tenure insecurity and dispossession, was the issue of rural

landlessness (e.g. Sen, 1999a, p. 7). To some extent this was also a product of the same

anxious worries about alternative sources of instability and danger when the Khmer Rouge

threat finally started receding. Rural landlessness seemed to be a significant and growing

phenomenon: national socio-economic surveys in 1997 and 1999 found landlessness to be

13.0% and 15.8% respectively55

, but shed no light on the causes.

A piece of research commissioned by an international NGO in 199956

(Biddulph, 2000d),

made it clear that landlessness was chiefly related to poverty, and would have been growing at

about the same rate regardless of whether tenure security had been a problem or not.

Expropriation and land disputes (i.e. lack of tenure security) simply were not a major cause of

landlessness. In a sample of 145 villages comprising over 30 000 households, 13% were

found to be landless. Only a small fraction (6.2%) of those landless households reported

having become landless as a result of expropriation. Overwhelmingly, the landless had either

never owned land (55%), or had sold the land they had as a result of financial pressures (39%)

often related to an episode of ill health. A later iteration of this research using a smaller

sample which was arguably more nationally representative57

yielded a comparable level of

landlessness (11.9%), but found that less than one percent (4 of 526) of landless households

reported having had their land taken from them (Biddulph, 2004).

Households who had never owned land were either younger couples who had got married

since the 1980s and had not received land, or were households that had moved around, often

former refugees who had been in camps during the 1980s when land was distributed, and had

arrived in new villages where there was no available land for clearance, and where they had

insufficient capital to buy. Poor Cambodians could have been blessed with the most secure

private property rights in the world, but these households who had never had land, and those

who had needed to sell would nevertheless have become landless. The only possible link to

tenure security suggested by the landlessness research related to the security of public land: a

theme to which we will return.

Despite this conclusive evidence that landlessness was not a product of expropriations (i.e.

lack of tenure security) the myth remained prevalent. The two issues have continued to be

55

Differences in method suggested that it was not possible to interpret this as meaning that landlessness

increased by 2.8% in the two year period, but that the two figures give a reasonable idea of the possible scale of

the problem from a nationally representative sample (Biddulph, 2004, p. 8). 56

The research was conducted not only as an exercise in discovering the causes of landlessness, but also to raise

awareness amongst development workers and organizations of the problem of landlessness and to generate

lessons about the extent to which existing practice was effective in either preventing landlessness or assisting

households that had become landless. In accordance with that goal, organizations were encouraged to volunteer

to conduct research in the villages where they worked. The sample of 45 organizations and 145 villages

generated in this way therefore reflected biases in the organizations‟ choices of location. Nevertheless the

similarity between the headline landlessness figure in the research and that in national statistics, as well as the

broad geographical coverage (15 out of 24 provinces) lent some credence to the results. 57

The sample design was not in fact representative as it drew samples in equal number from the four agro-

ecological zones of Cambodia whose share of the national population varied by a factor of over ten (Biddulph,

2004, p. 13)

Page 105: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

87

linked, and a causal relationship often suggested, as the following citation from a recent

UNDP report on land and human security illustrates:

However, many rural households in Cambodia suffer either from landlessness or near

landlessness, or lack of formal property rights to the land they live on...A likely consequence

of the many disputes is that landlessness or near landlessness is also on the rise (UNDP, 2007,

p. 11)

Having introduced the issue of tenure insecurity, and established it as a significant social

problem, though not the driver of rural landlessness that it was sometimes misrepresented as,

we can now turn to its geography.

4.3.3 Regional Distribution of Tenure Insecurity

The most reliable available proxy for tenure insecurity is the records of cases where people

have reported being dispossessed. Such cases are recorded on land dispute databases held by

various organizations engaged in land rights work. These record cases where there are five or

more parties to a land dispute, and thus potentially provide a geographical overview of tenure

insecurity. Unfortunately, the databases have not been well-maintained, and have not been

shared by the agencies, so it has not been possible to achieve a national overview of the

problem of tenure insecurity (Biddulph, 2003a)58

.

According to Kato, during the 1990s:

Expropriation – especially expropriation of large tracts of land – appears to happen most

frequently in the northwest, particularly to returnees and internally displaced people whose

occupancy of the land is either recent or who were forced to abandon the area at some point

because of the war. However, cases of eviction have been reported throughout Cambodia

(Kato, 1999, p. 1).

These two statements – that tenure security is prevalent „throughout Cambodia‟ and

particularly in the north-west of the country appear to be borne out by subsequent reports.

Cooper‟s review of data, for example, noted that the most cases were found in Battambang

and Banteay Meanchey in the north-west, in Kandal in the centre of the country, in Kampot in

the south-west and in Kampong Cham in the eastern central part of the country (Cooper,

2002). Recently, NGOs, while still not managing to combine their data to produce a decent

statistical overview are at least starting to map some of their own cases. One of the country‟s

two leading national human rights NGOs, The Cambodian League for the Defense of Human

Rights (LICADHO), recently published a report documenting a steep rise in the number of

dispute cases that it is involved in. The map of the cases where they are providing support

shows that there are land disputes in all of the provinces where they work (see Figure 4-1),

and that the north-western provinces of Battambang, Banteay Meanchey and Siem Reap are

particularly prone to disputes (Licadho, 2009, p. 5)

58

The NGO Forum‟s Land Information Centre was in the process of addressing this gap in the course of this

research, but had only produced a pilot study report (Land Information Centre, 2008) and an analysis of cases in

the media in 2008 (Land Information Centre, 2009).

Page 106: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

88

Figure 4-1: Land Disputes in Cambodia Monitored by Human Rights NGO LICADHO 2003-2008.

Source: (Licadho, 2009, p. 5)

The NGO Forum Land Information Centre (LIC) used the data from 173 cases recorded from

local media during the year 2008 to generate maps showing both provincial aggregates

(Figure 4-2) and individual dispute locations (Figure 4-3).

Page 107: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

89

Source: Land Information Centre, 2009, p.10

Figure 4-2: Land Disputes in Cambodia Reported in the Cambodian Media 2008

Page 108: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

90

Source: Land Information Centre, 2009, p. 2

Figure 4-3: Location of Land Disputes Reported in the Cambodian Media 2008

A refining of the “throughout Cambodia” geography, however, comes from a 2006 study

commissioned by the World Bank and the federally owned German Gesellschaft für

Technische Zusammenarbeit. The purpose of the report was to review the effectiveness of

donor-supported government land dispute mechanisms, but amongst the authors‟ key findings

was:

Ownership of the well established rice farming land which makes up the bulk of Cambodian

land holdings is relatively uncontentious as compared with other sorts of land holdings,

particularly chamcar land, common pool resources and land which was cleared by the parties

themselves (Adler et al., 2006, p. ix)

This suggests that while land disputes are „everywhere‟ in the sense of being found in all rural

provinces, there may be certain sorts of land that are more vulnerable than others, and that a

closer look at the geography might yield a more differentiated picture. Alert to this warning, I

will now seek to explain the geography of land disputes in Cambodia in relation to their

causes.

Page 109: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

91

4.3.4 Explanation

Cambodia underwent a triple transition during the late 1980s and early 1990s. A transition

from a planned to a market economy, from conflict to peace and from authoritarian rule to

formal democracy, with the transition to a market economy seen as the dominant of those

transitions (Hughes, 2003a). While the idea that Cambodia has been „democratising‟ has been

convincingly rejected as an explanatory framework (Öjendal & Lilja, 2009), the transitions to

market and to peace provide the key dimensions to explaining the geography of tenure

insecurity in Cambodia in the late 1990s and early 2000s.

4.3.4.1 Rice Farming Landscapes and the Transition to Market.

The majority of the Cambodian population are rural smallholders. The dramatic changes in

the political systems and formal institutions for managing land during the half-century since

Independence suggests that the tenure rights of smallholder households have changed

radically and often. During the 1960s landholdings were based on a combination of what

households had received from their parents and what they had cleared themselves. By farming

their land, households established and maintained their right to that land. During the Khmer

Rouge rule 1975-79 all private ownership was abolished. All farming was communal, and the

state exercised the right to decide where people would live, often separating families, setting

people to work in mobile labour gangs, and relocating whole populations often for reasons

relating to security and regime survival. In 1979 one communist regime replaced another as

the Vietnamese supported People‟s Republic of Kampuchea supplanted the Khmer Rouge‟s

People‟s Democracy of Kampuchea. Again, farming was to be communal, with the state

owning all land and villages organised into krom samaki (solidarity groups) of about ten

households per group. Land was to be redistributed equally amongst the population according

on the basis of family size and available labour. A transition to market was mentioned in

political speeches from 1985, some private ownership was allowed from 1986 and land was

formally redistributed to farmers in 1989. The passage of the 1992 Land Law, established the

mechanisms by which individuals could set about obtaining ownership title, which set in

motion a titling process that was never completed 59

(Sovannarith et al., 2001, p. 188; S.

Williams, 1999, pp. 7-9).

Despite these apparent upheavals, however, there was in fact a large element of continuity in

land ownership and land use for individual farming households. When land was redistributed

to the solidarity groups in 1979 it was often done in such a way that in practice families

returned to farming the land that they had owned prior to 1975. In other cases, land was

claimed on a first come, first served basis after 1979, and then those patterns of ownership

confirmed under the supposedly communal farming arrangements. In addition to land that was

officially under communal farming, households were often also able to clear land from nearby

forests and this was treated wholly as private (Kusakabe, Yunxian, & Kelkar, 1995, p. 89).

Communal farming, furthermore, was often only practiced for a short time, sometimes only

for the year or so that it took to overcome the acute shortage of rice seed, draft animals and

other inputs in the immediate aftermath of the Khmer Rouge regime (S. Williams, 1999, p. 8).

As one history of the 1979-1989 period concludes, this was in fact a time when the free

market flourished and “the PRK encouraged the family economy and made this the

foundation of its rural legitimacy” (Slocomb, 2003, p. 263). There has been no comprehensive

research on the various ways in which land redistribution was interpreted and implemented,

59

Applications were made and receipts for these applications were issued. The titling process was never

completed, however the receipts, which looked a little like a bird‟s wing and were known locally as „chicken

wing forms‟ were kept by many households as a proxy for a title.

Page 110: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

92

but it is clear that in some places there was a genuine attempt by local authorities to follow the

central directive to redistribute, whilst in others there was basically a return to former

ownership patterns. Gottesman found that the system of collectivization had already failed,

and cited central government discussions of particularly unruly cases where local cadre had

been involved in selling off the best land on the private market and leaving only the poorest

lands to be farmed collectively (Gottesman, 2004, pp. 272-273). I have not heard similar

stories to this during my years in the Cambodian countryside, so suspect that these were

exceptional cases, nevertheless what is clear is that the „redistribution‟ of communal land that

is commonly referred to as having occurred after the Vietnamese withdrew their support in

1989 was simply a question of the legislation catching up with something that had already

happened up to a decade previously.

Buying and selling of land, meanwhile, occurred as early as the very early 1980s, as has been

made clear by interviews with landless households (Biddulph, 2000d). There has always been

a degree of stigma attached to trading of land – the social norm is to farm the land and then to

hand it on to your children - but it has also been a recognised and accepted part of village life

and of coping with crises60

. While there was no legal way to transfer land privately during the

1980s, transactions were secured by either community recognition or informal written

contracts by the transacting parties or the local authorities or an informal witnessing of the

transaction by the village chief (or some combination of these). These practices continued

after formal privatisation in 1989 and the passage of the 1992 Land Law as land transactions

became legally possible, but only through channels which were never realistically available to

poor rural households. In practice, then, for rural smallholders, the transition from planned to

market economy had little or no effect on their tenure arrangements as land was already

effectively under private ownership.

Overall, the norms relating to land tenure of smallholder agricultural land remained

consistent. Possession and de facto ownership were established by farming land. Families

could acquire land by inheritance, and could also expand their holdings by clearing new land

at the edge of the village. Selling and buying land were likewise recognised and accepted

ways of acquiring or disposing of land, but with selling a reluctant response to crisis. My

experiences of carrying out research into the causes of landlessness led me into countless

conversations with rural Cambodians who had sold their land between the early 1980s and the

early 2000s. I had the impression of a well-functioning local land market where selling and

buying were not problematic, and therefore of rather secure tenure arrangements. As Adler et

al. pointed out, only 1.8% of plots in the 2004 socio-economic survey were reported as ever

having been subject to a conflict, with two-thirds of those disputes already resolved, leading

them to conclude that “tenure in Cambodia is more secure than is generally assumed” (Adler,

Porter, & Woolcock, 2008, p. 2). Adler is particularly interesting on the subject of the urban

fringe around Phnom Penh. The city has been expanding and investors have been acquiring

ever larger tracts of land outside Phnom Penh, effectively transforming it from rural to urban.

However, this process has been geographically differentiated. Various sorts of public and

common such as lakes and marshes have been expropriated by investors through opaque deals

with authorities. In the case of rice lands however, and regardless of whether the owners have

official title or not, investors have acquired the land by purchase.

60

Interview 178, with a provincial cadastral official in Takeo.

Page 111: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

93

4.3.4.2 State Land and the Transition to Market.

If tenure of smallholder agricultural land was generally secure, where did the protests about

land grabbing and dispossession which attracted the headlines in Phnom Penh come from?

While the informal arrangements around rural smallholdings have remained stable and

governed by the same norms and practices through the decades, the same continuity has not

been found with other land. After the signing of the Peace Agreements in 1991 and the formal

change from the People‟s Republic of Kampuchea to the State of Cambodia, there was

suddenly a situation where the State had vast assets, no legal way to divest itself of those

assets, and no intention to continue with a command economy. In Phnom Penh the

consequences were rapid and visible: State factories and other assets were sold off by ministry

officials, provoking protests by suddenly unemployed former workers, and the violent

suppression of such protests (Sanger, 1991)61

.

In the countryside a similar vacuum was created. Suddenly, all land which had not been under

the plough was subject to contest. And at all levels this became an unfair contest between

people who could mobilise the authority of the state, and much poorer people who lacked

such connections. Previously, the land between villages had been forest or scrub which

provided a reserve of agricultural land which could be cleared as the population expanded, as

well as a source of food and firewood. Suddenly, villagers discovered that all of the land

between the villages, which previously „had no owner‟ in their eyes, was now privately owned

(Biddulph, 2000d). Small areas of communal land held in trust by local authorities rapidly

became the private property of village chiefs and their families, while vast areas of forest and

scrub were turned over to national and international business interests as agricultural or

forestry concessions (Van Acker, 1999, p. 54).

In addition to the intensified logging and granting of timber concessions already discussed,

the State began issuing Economic Land Concessions, mainly for plantation agriculture, again

with limited compliance with relevant legislation (UNOHCHR, 2007, p. 49). In addition to

the 943,069 hectares of economic land concessions documented, there have been rumours of

land deals struck with foreign governments for huge areas (Minder, 2008), as well as a brief

flirtation during 2008-9 with the policy of allowing provincial governors to issue concessions

of up to 1000 hectares. None of these is on land that is in any way „empty‟ or unclaimed. In

addition to various authorities jostling to broker investment deals there has also been a steady

flow of migrants into forested regions looking to secure new agricultural land. Any

Cambodian household using or occupying land in forest or forest margins has tenure that is

insecure in the extreme. In many respects, then, the division that Alden Wily made in Africa

seems to apply well to Cambodia: smallholder agricultural and residential land is relatively

secure, whilst other public or commons land to which people have had various de facto rights

is extremely insecure (Alden Wily, 2008 see chapter 2)

4.3.4.3 The Transition to Peace.

Following the ouster of the Khmer Rouge regime by Cambodian defectors supported by the

Vietnamese army in 1979 came a period where the primary sources of regional difference in

the Cambodian countryside were security related. The prolonged guerrilla war which took

place from 1979 did not reach many parts of central Cambodia which effectively enjoyed

peace from that time on. The resistance forces, with their bases and supply lines among the

61

I was resident in Phnom Penh at the time and recall being out on the streets on one of the evenings when

people were protesting in the streets and police accidentally shot dead a bystander watching from a balcony

above the angry crowd.

Page 112: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

94

refugee camps on the Thai border were most effective in the north-west of the country, but

also established bases in the forests in north-east and south-west of the country. After the

peace process and UN sponsored elections in 1993 the Khmer Rouge continued their struggle,

which was not finally ended until the death in 1998 of Pol Pot and the integration of the final

remnants of the Khmer Rouge military into either the national military or civilian society. As

a result of this conflict large tracts of the country, especially in the north-west, but also in the

south, south-west and north-east of the country were insecure. The combination of military

activity and risk of land-mines meant that much cultivable land remained unoccupied. As

peace came, these areas opened up. Families in search of land, including many of the 350 000

former refugees from the Thai-Cambodian border, moved in. At the same time, military

commanders often had their own plans for that land, thus many of the land conflicts that were

documented during the late 1990s involved a single commander on the one side in conflict

with sixty or seventy households on the other side. During the 1990s the places with most

fighting and the largest and longest military presence were those worst afflicted by

widespread tenure insecurity (Cooper, 2002).

Related to this were land conflicts along the Thai-Cambodian border. The refugees who had

lived in the camps in Thailand during the 1980s had well-established livelihoods there. They

had the connections required to engage in cross-border trading or smuggling, and to access

casual labour markets in agriculture and construction. Many of these people having returned

to Cambodia found it difficult to establish themselves and often came back to the border in

order to earn a living. Large informal settlements grew up along the border, and especially

near the main crossing point between Poipet in Cambodia and Aranyaprathet in Thailand

(NPA, 2003). Meanwhile, this land was also prime real estate, not least for the construction of

casinos and hotels which could be built on Cambodian soil in order to cater for wealthy Thai

clients (casinos being illegal in Thailand). As a consequence there has been a series of

settlements and often violent evictions in the Poipet area (for example CHRAC, 2005;

Woodsome, 2005).

It is thus a combination of insecurely resettled returned refugees, military interests, a

population which has been more prone to displacement by fighting and land-mines than in

other parts of the country, and lucrative investment opportunities along the national border

that have made the north-west particularly prone to tenure insecurity.

4.3.5 Immanent Development and Tenure Insecurity in Summary

The consequences for tenure security of Cambodia‟s transitions to market and to peace were

minimal in the areas where smallholder rice farming had been practiced since the ouster of the

Khmer Rouge in 1979. Both peace and markets had come to these places a decade before the

1991 peace agreement and the 1993 Constitution, and villagers‟ relations to land were firmly

established within long-standing social norms. By contrast, areas that had formerly been under

State management, or under conflict, were subject to competing claims, often including

competition between settlements of poor people and well connected military commanders or

business people. In such situations, poor people‟s tenure has been extremely insecure. A 2002

report looking into land policy and conflicts in Cambodia pieced together data from various

organisations involved in land related conflicts, concluded that by the end of 2001 there were

“at least 200,000 poor Cambodians involved in land disputes with powerful people including

generals, high government officials and large businesses” (Cooper, 2002, p. 8).

The idea that tenure insecurity is „throughout Cambodia‟ is justifiable in the sense that it is

found in all provinces to a greater or lesser extent. On the other hand, it is not prevalent on all

sorts of land. Up to this point, whether as a result of the ruling party‟s political allegiance to

the population who remained in place during the 1980s, or because of a respect for the rice

Page 113: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

95

farming norms that have been seen as central to Khmer culture, it appears that the smallholder

rice lands where the majority of the population have their residential and farmland have

remained secure.

4.4 Intentional Development: A Geography of Property Rights Interventions in Cambodia

4.4.1 Systematic Land Titling

In 1992, following the 1991 peace agreements, the Cambodian government passed a new land

law and began the process of issuing land titles to all citizens who had occupied their land

peacefully for five years or more. Four million applications were made for title, of which 15%

were reportedly processed62

. However, the State‟s bureaucratic capacity could not match its

vision and the process ran out of steam. A request was made by the government in 1995 for

donors to assist with a land titling process. Eventually, after a number of pilot projects

financed principally by the Finnish and German governments, a Land Management and

Administration Project (LMAP) was agreed63

. Originally this was a 5-year programme

running from 2002 until 2007, with a total cost of 33.4 million USD financed respectively by

the International Development Association of the World Bank (23.4 million USD); the

Government of Finland (3.5 million); the Federal Republic of Germany (3.5 million USD);

the Royal Government of Cambodia (3.0 million USD).

The project consisted of 5 components, as follows:

1. Development of land policy and regulatory framework.

2. Institutional development.

3. Land titling programme and development of a land registration system.

4. Strengthening mechanisms for dispute resolution.

5. Land management.

It is component 3 which is the focus of interest for this study. Two sorts of land titling are

distinguished: systematic land titling and sporadic land titling. Systematic land titling refers to

a process whereby a whole community is surveyed at the same time and titles issued en

masse. This is systematic in the sense that survey teams can cover each district, commune by

commune and each commune village by village until all of the land in an administrative area

has been titled. Systematic land titling was the central element in the LMAP titling

programme; the other components can be seen as providing the regulatory and institutional

framework to enable systematic land titling to succeed. Sporadic land titling refers to cases

where person/legal entity in an area which has not yet been titled makes an application to get

their land individually titled. Typically, it is non-local buyers who have used sporadic land

titling to secure their purchase of land in the Cambodian countryside. In a pre-study for the

LMAP project, sporadic land titling was identified as a source of tenure insecurity in rural

areas, as outsiders could potentially develop a legal claim, supported by documentation, for

land used by rural dwellers without such documentation (Sovannarith et al., 2001).

The local origins and motivation to the land titling programme could be traced to the

Cambodian government wish to complete the process which it had begun but been unable to

62

Williams (1999, p. 10) suggests there should be some scepticism about this figure by noting that “many

commentators” question this figure both how it can be so large, and how in practice a count was accomplished. 63

Unless otherwise specified, information below comes from the Project Appraisal Document (World Bank,

2002)

Page 114: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

96

complete in 1992, and to speeches made by the Prime Minister emphasising the importance of

secure land titles (World Bank, 2002, p. 9). The project‟s overall goals were “to reduce

poverty, stimulate economic development, promote social stability and improve

environmental management”, and these were to be achieved via its specific objectives which

were “to improve land tenure and promote the development of efficient land markets” (World

Bank, 2002, p. 2).

These goals and objectives were set in the context of a project description which related

tenure insecurity to a lack of investment:

It is overwhelmingly clear to both government and donors that the overriding problem and the

one with the greatest contributed to poverty is lack of land tenure security (and the associated

landlessness) and restricted access to common property resources. Symptoms of the problem

are clear from the rising number of landless people due to forced or distressed sales and the

high number of land disputes clogging the judicial and other institutions for resolving land

conflicts. (World Bank, 2002, p. 3).

There are suggestions that state agents such as the military and politically connected people

have dispossessed people of their land which is being facilitated by the lack of formal

recognition of rights on these lands (World Bank, 2002, p. 3).

The economy has also been growing steadily, an average annual rate of about 5 percent per

year. However, unclear rules governing rights to land threaten both political stability and

economic development (World Bank, 2002, p. 3).

Finally, the low output of Cambodian rice farming compared with the remainder of the region

was highlighted, and it was posited that increasing tenure security would remove a barrier to

investment in irrigation:

Lack of clear title is also hindering economic growth in Cambodia by reducing incentives to

invest...Rice output in Cambodia is enough to feed the average family for only seven months a

year. Low yields are primarily due to low investments in water control technologies essential

to take full advantage of high yielding rice varieties...Low investment in agriculture is in part

a result of lack of security over rights to land (World Bank, 2002, p. 4).

During the course of the research for this thesis the World Bank repeatedly presented the

systematic titling under LMAP as having the potential to transform smallholder agriculture in

Cambodia by removing the “primary binding constraint” to agricultural growth, namely “ill-

defined property rights” (World Bank, 2006, p. 74). It was claimed that titled land would in

consequence deliver yields that were 73% greater than untitled land, meaning that the

issuance of one million titles would enable 438,345 individuals to escape from poverty and

would reduce the national poverty rate by 3.36%. These impressive figures were derived from

a study (Deininger, 2005) which unfortunately was impossible to locate during the research64

,

but which in turn appears to be based on very unreliable answers from the 2004 Cambodia

Socio-Economic Survey (Markussen, 2008, p. 2280)65

.

If the claims made on behalf of the LMAP project were somewhat doubtful, its success in

delivering outputs both ahead of schedule and at a lower than anticipated cost was indubitable

64

Two colleagues of Deininger who were in possession of the report suggested that I contact him directly for a

copy. Deininger (who given his prominence no doubt receives a very large amount of correspondence from

fellow researchers) did not respond to my communications. 65

According to the survey responses 21% of parcels of land held official title. This was not feasible in 2004,

before LMAP was implemented. The answers may relate to receipts issued during the abortive registration and

titling begun in 1992 by the Cambodian government, or it may have been that respondents felt it was in their best

interests to claim that they had title even when they didn‟t. Instructions given to enumerators failed to clarify the

matter (Markussen, 2008, p. 2280).

Page 115: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

97

likewise its track record in building up the technical capacity of the staff employed by the

Ministry of Land Management, Urban Planning and Construction (Anttonen, 2010). The

project was extended twice and was eventually completed on 31st December 2009

66. By its

original completion date, it had delivered 794,639 signed titles to land owners, thereby

exceeding the project document target of 760 000 (World Bank, 2009a, p. 8). With 700

trained staff working in registration teams in 11 provinces, producing on average 20 000

legally registered titles per month this reflected an impressive training and management effort

(Sovann, 2005). With titles costing less than 10 USD per parcel to produce, it has also

reportedly been the most cost-efficient land titling system in the Southeast Asia region

(FINNMAP, 2008).

Despite its successes in achieving intended outputs, the project was not without controversy

during the course of this research. World Bank complaints about procurement processes,

strongly disputed by the LMAP project director, led to an international procurement agent

being appointed for the project (World Bank, 2009a), and then late in 2009 a group of NGOs

working with urban communities in Phnom Penh initiated a complaints procedure against the

Bank staff on the project via the World Bank‟s Inspection Panel (World Bank Inspection

Panel, 2009). That complaint related to the inability of a group of urban dwellers living

around a lake in Phnom Penh to get their tenure secured by the project. The issues raised in

the urban complaint – where does the project go, and where does it not go, reflect the

concerns of this research in rural areas, and we will return to that later.

4.4.1.1 Geographical Distribution

In rural areas, the focus of this research project, LMAP systematic land titling has been

implemented in the seven provinces and two municipalities67

. As can be seen in Figure 4-4,

the northeast of the country, has not been included. These four provinces play host to forest-

dwelling ethnic minority communities. The west and north-west of the country has also

largely been avoided. This is another part of the country with large expanses of forest. The

main concentrations of titling have therefore been in central and southern Cambodia.

Data available at district level gives the impression that the titling programme covers more

territory than is actually the case: within these districts only some communes will have been

titled, and within those communes it is only private land that has been fully adjudicated and

titled. Selected State land, in particular the sites of public utilities such as wells and schools

have been titled, but other State land remains untitled. What the villages that have been titled

in rural areas have in common is that they are located in the landscapes of the “well

established rice farming land which makes up the bulk of Cambodian land holdings” (Adler et

al., 2006, p. ix).

66

LMAP is one in a series of projects coordinated by the Ministry of Land Management Urban Planning and

Construction as part of a programme which will envisages registering and titling all land in Cambodia within

about 15 years. LMAP was superseded in 2009 by the Land Administration Sub-Sectoral Project (LASSP),

which continues to be supported by Finland and Germany but no longer by the World Bank. 67

Provinces of Battambang, Kampong Cham, Kampong Speu, Kampong Thom, Kampot, Kandal, Prey Veng,

Siem Reap, Takeo. Municipalities of Sihanoukville and Phnom Penh. Whilst provinces are notionally rural and

municipalities are notionally urban, all municipalities include some rural areas, and provinces all include urban

areas.

Page 116: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

98

Figure 4-4: Districts in Cambodia With Systematic Land Titling as at July 2009 (Source: LMAP)

4.4.1.2 Explaining the Geography of Systematic Land Titling

In the geography of tenure insecurity in Cambodia we found that the one sort of land that was

generally not prone to insecurity was that belonging to smallholders in established rice

farming areas. Yet LMAP, a programme that intends to address the problem of tenure

insecurity, is only being implemented in areas where tenure security is not generally a

problem. Why might this be the case? Part of the explanation relates to project management

strategies. The LMAP Director (Interview 219) explained that it was important to begin the

programme in areas where it would be able to succeed. He used the metaphor of a cock-fight

to explain the process and said that if a cock is sent to fight and loses, that will be the end of

the cock with no second chances. So it is always wise to send the cock out to fight against

some weaker opponents first to get some victories and become stronger before fighting a

stronger opponent. For this reason, he argued that it is beneficial that the systematic land

titling programme has been implemented in areas where tenure is already secure.

This risk-aversion is also enshrined in the project appraisal document which suggests that

difficult areas will be avoided: “The project will not title lands in areas where disputes are

likely until agreements are agreed on the status of the land” (World Bank, 2002, p. 24).

In addition to the central policy choices, there is also a decentralised safety valve which

ensures that systematic land titling only travels to places which government feels comfortable

Page 117: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

99

with. According to the relevant legislation68

, it is provincial governors who must allocate an

adjudication area and determine its boundaries, before initiating the work of officials of the

Ministry of Land Management Urban Planning and Construction to conduct the registration

process. At this stage, therefore, strategic choices may be made about project location on the

basis of the sort of vested interests and networks that order the economic development of

contemporary Cambodia. The assertion that risk-aversion (only taking the tenure security

programme to already secure lands) is only a temporary phase at the beginning of a project

whilst the project becomes „strong‟ should be treated with some scepticism. Cambodia‟s

systematic land registration resembles earlier titling processes also supported by the World

Bank in Thailand and Indonesia, where it has been argued that the main lessons learned were

“ways to avoid complex tenurial situations, as well as complex land types such as forests, so

as to be able to concentrate on reaching high production targets in non-contested areas” (S.

Williams, 2003, p. 8).

The logic of the intervention suggests that titling might improve tenure security resulting in

the promised benefits of improved agricultural productivity and poverty reduction. Research

carried out so far has suggested that while people are pleased with the process and often report

that the title gives them improved security, it has not impacted on the way that people farm

(Deutsch, 2006; McAndrew, 2007). A well-designed research project implemented by the

Cambodia Development Resource Institute (CDRI) incorporating a baseline study in five

districts, four where titling was to occur and a fifth which was to be a control, was due to be

followed up in 2007 (Ballard & Sovannarith, 2004). That study would, by virtue of having a

larger, more representative sample, have provided more valid results. Unfortunately, the

follow-up has yet to occur69

.

In interviews with cadastral officials at district (Interview 230), provincial (Interview 232) and

national (Interview 220) level I asked them if they could direct me to other locations where

systematic land titling had resulted in observable changes in agricultural practice. No such

places could be identified. This lack of impact is, of course, consistent with the geography of

tenure insecurity (found everywhere apart from smallholder agricultural regions) and the

geography of the systematic land titling intervention (found only in smallholder agricultural

regions). The one problem identified by the project document that is found in the areas where

the programme is being implemented is landlessness, but that, as already noted, is not a

problem that is caused by tenure insecurity and not, therefore, one that can be solved by

improving or formalising tenure security.

In the context of the scrupulousness with which systematic land titling has avoided

Cambodia‟s forests, and the key role that forests have played in Cambodia‟s elite politics, this

difficult and contested terrain does not seem a promising area for internationally supported

property rights interventions. However, community forestry is an intervention of a quite

different type, and we turn to that now.

4.4.2 Community Forestry

Community forestry has been implemented in Cambodia since 1991 when two international

NGOs established projects in Takeo and Kampong Chhnang provinces. By 2002, 57 projects

had been identified, and by 2005 the head of the national Forestry Administration listed 274

68

Sub decree on the Procedures to establish Cadastral Index Map and Land Register (MLMUPC, 2002) 69

The choice to focus on village-scale studies throughout the period of this research was partly informed by the

expectation that my village level work would be complemented by the CDRI larger-sample work.

Page 118: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

100

community forestry project sites spread through 19 of Cambodia‟s 24

provinces/municipalities (Heng & Sokhun, 2005).

As Poffenberger (2006) has explained, communities were, at least in some places, managing

forest long before international agencies began advocating community forestry. He illustrates

this with two examples which indicate effective management over several decades. First, in

Ratanakiri province70

research showed how forest cover during a fifty year period had shown

little change apart from a rotation in the mosaic of land use systems thus demonstrating the

sustainability of the swidden management regimes of the native ethnic minority peoples living

there (Fox, 2002 cited in Poffenberger, 2006, p. 60). Second, in a village in Siem Reap

villagers primarily depended on fisheries, which in turn were dependent on hatcheries in

flooded forests on the northern banks of the Tonlei Sap lake. About sixty years ago forests

were cleared by farmers wishing to grow water melons. When this damaged fish stocks the

local community began organising to protect the forest and have done so up to the present day

(Poffenberger, 2006, pp. 67-68). However, whilst such examples of local management do

exist, the initiative to promote and formalise community management as an alternative to

centralised state control has initially come from international actors.

A diverse range of national and international NGOs as well as bilateral and multilateral

agencies were involved in supporting community forestry during the 1990s. Whilst focusing

on establishing projects with communities they also advocated for recognition and legitimacy

for community forestry management from the government. During the 2000s, after a new

Forestry Law was passed in 2002, this advocacy eventually resulted in the issuing of a

Community Forestry sub-decree71

in 2003 and a Community Forestry Prakas in 2006.

4.4.2.1 Geographical Distribution

The total land area devoted to community forestry is 367 943 hectares (see Figure 4-5), which

is 3.31% of the total national forest estate of 11,104,285 hectares (Forestry Administration,

2004, p. 3). The geography of community forestry is a patchy one, spread mainly through

forest areas, but also sometimes in rice field landscapes.

There are certain areas of concentration, which tend to reflect the presence of larger

International Organisations or NGOs, such as the cluster of projects in degraded forests in

Kampong Chhnang that were supported by the international NGO Concern Worldwide during

the 1990s, and the project sites in the flooded areas north of the Tonlei Sap lake in Siem Reap

province that were supported by a UN Food and Agriculture Organisation programme from

the mid-1990s until the mid-2000s.

What these scattered areas have in common, however, is that they are overwhelmingly in

degraded forest. In a review of the 57 community forestry sites existing at the time, Fichtenau

et al. (2002, pp. 25-26) found that none of the community forestry sites was in „undisturbed‟

forests, so all were to a greater or lesser extent „degraded‟, with 67% located in areas that

were defined as either „heavily degraded‟ or having „little or no forest‟. The secondary forest

which remains in the community forestry locations has been found to have very little

70

Ratanakiri is at the north-east tip of Cambodia, has low population densities, high forest cover and traditionally

large native ethnic minority forest-dwelling population. 71

Cambodian legislative practice is such that laws are not normally framed in full detail, but require subsidiary

legislation in order for them to be enacted. There is thus typically a hierarchy of formal regulation: laws, then

sub-decrees, then prakas, then guidelines

Page 119: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

101

Figure 4-5: Community Forestry Areas, Cambodia, June 2009 (Source: Forestry Administration)

Page 120: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

102

commercial value (McKenney, Chea, Tola, & Evans, 2004). Fichtenau et al. (2002) suggested

that there was potential for a far

larger proportion of Cambodia‟s territory to be allocated to community forestry and argued that

all forest land within 10 kilometres of a settlement be handed over to community management.

This proposition has not been adopted, and community forestry projects continue to be negotiated

on a case by case basis.

4.4.2.2 Explanation of the Geographical Spread of Community Forestry

A geography of community forestry that locates it on degraded lands is not unique to Cambodia:

Poffenberger identifies this as typical in Southeast Asia:

Most national community forestry programmes, at least in their initial phases, focus on degraded

forest restoration through natural regeneration or plantations. In other cases, projects are geared

towards community management of small-scale timber operations. Commercially and biologically

valuable forests, typically of older growth, have generally been retained by the state for industrial

use or placed under protected area systems (Poffenberger, 2006, p. 64).

Interestingly, from the point of view of the arguments in this thesis, Poffenberger points to the

contrast between host government and development industry actors in their follow up of new

legislation.

In terms of the impact of new policies and legislation empowering community forest management,

they appear to have had more influence in helping leverage donor investment in this sector than in

securing community rights to state forestlands. Many of the initial policies have been cautiously

framed, restricting community rights to income flows from forestlands (Poffenberger, 2006, p. 63).

The location of community forestry sites in degraded forests means that they do not promise

much impact on livelihoods and local economies in the short to medium term. The first fifteen

years is often seen as a preparatory phase to build up the resource such that significant incomes

can be derived from it.

This narrative of development, with the poorest people being allocated the poorest land and being

supported by the development industry to improve it has not passed without criticism or

contestation. It does, after all, directly contradict the literature consulted in chapter 2, which in its

milder formulations suggested that community based natural resource management (CBNRM)

would be more realistic in cases where communities were very dependent on the resource

(Agrawal, 2007), and in its more fundamentalist iterations builds on the idea that common

property regimes (CPR) are by definition indigenous and that interventions therefore facilitate the

continuance of already existent common property regimes resource and management systems

(Alden Wily, 2008, p. 45).

One critique of the tendency for community forestry to be implemented away from high value

forests came from the authors of a „Special Report‟ by researchers from CDRI, Cambodia‟s

leading independent policy research organisation, and the international conservation NGO the

Wildlife Conservation Society (McKenney et al., 2004). The authors of this report found that

there were enormous incentives for all actors to „cut and run‟. In other words, that given the

general insecurity of forest tenure it made more sense for people to cut down trees for immediate

Page 121: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

103

economic rewards rather than to take the risk of managing them long term and seeing somebody

else cut them down. Their policy response in relation to community forestry was two-fold.

Firstly, they did not see economic value for communities in managing degraded forest, and

therefore proposed that communities should be allocated higher value forest and, crucially, be

allowed to harvest and trade timber on a commercial basis. Secondly, given the broader political

economy and the incentives to cut and run, they suggested that this so-called „commercial

community forestry‟ be piloted in places where there was exceptionally strong political support

from powerful actors (McKenney et al., 2004, p. 95).

A second critique came from researchers who had been looking at the role of harvesting resin

from hard-wood trees in people‟s livelihoods, and found that it was the central element of the

livelihoods of forest-dependent people in many areas of the country. Furthermore, that in some

places in the country there were informal tenure systems with households „owning‟ the right to

tap certain trees (Cock, 2004). The logging of resin trees had never been permitted under

Cambodian law, but concessionaires during the 1990s had flagrantly ignored this stipulation and

had been taking all of the hard wood trees from the areas where they had acquired logging rights.

Community forestry, particularly allied to community organisation and non-violent action, was

seen as a way for communities to resist the logging companies and to protect their access to resin

trees to which they had strong rights both by the letter of the law and according to established

cultural norms.

Community forestry projects have, however, in almost all cases been developed in cooperation

with the offices of the national Forestry Administration. Their location has been decided in

negotiation between NGOs, forestry officials and representatives of companies with economic

land concessions or forestry concessions in the areas. For such community activists, government

recognition and regulation of community forestry was a kiss of death because their short-term

objective was to resist the very companies who were being ushered in by the forestry authorities.

The communities and local NGOs with whom they worked would go to meetings with the

Forestry Administration and instead of being allocated the areas of forest where there were still

resin trees that they had requested, would instead be given degraded land. And, to the immense

frustration of the activists, neither the community representatives nor the NGO representatives

wished to alienate the Forestry Administration officials and gratefully accepted the degraded land

that they were given (Interview 254).

The similarities with the systematic land titling case become clear. Just as private titling has been

diverted away from the landscapes where elite interests are busily acquiring and dispossessing,

community tenure projects have also been similarly diverted, away from the high value forests

and towards the marginal lands. What is also clear given the contrast between the rather strong

form of property rights awarded under systematic land titling (i.e. full ownership) and the much

weaker rights in the community forestry regime (i.e. limited management rights for a limited

period of time, with regular review and the threat of withdrawal of those rights on inspection even

within that limited time), is that it is only appropriately diluted interventions that are allowed to

travel into what one interviewee called the „hot‟ areas.

Page 122: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

104

4.5 The Relationship between the Two Geographies

4.5.1 Geographies of Evasion, and the Beginnings of Theory

Bebbington envisaged a three-step analytical process: having mapped out the immanent

geography (in which the problem of poverty and inadequate livelihoods was embedded), and the

intentional geography (in which the planned interventions were mapped out) there would then be

an analysis of the mutual interaction between the two. In this case, therefore, I have mapped out

the phenomenon of tenure insecurity in Cambodia, as a feature of the ongoing processes of

„immanent development‟, and I have mapped out the interventions of systematic land titling and

community forestry as examples of „intentional development‟ which set out to address the issues

of tenure insecurity.

An analysis of mutual relations between the insecurity and the interventions, however, does not

seem to show them mutually influencing each other. The pattern of tenure security interventions

is defined by (avoidance of) the patterns of tenure insecurity. There is no corresponding evidence

that patterns of insecurity have been influenced or modified by the tenure security interventions.

What we have seen, in fact, is a „geography of evasiveness‟ where the interventions have

systematically avoided the places where the problem of tenure insecurity is located.

We have seen a geography of tenure insecurity in rural Cambodia which indicates that

smallholder rice farmers are very secure in their tenure, but that almost all other land is insecure

and prone to competing claims and predatory land grabbing. We have also seen two tenure

security interventions, one aimed at securing private individualised tenure of agricultural and

house land, the other aimed at providing community tenure over forest land. The systematic land

titling has only travelled to places where tenure is already secure, namely smallholder rice

landscapes. Community forestry has only been implemented in places where the forest has

already been degraded. How have these geographies been accounted for in the project literature

of the respective interventions?

The titling component of the LMAP project was to improve land tenure security through issuance

of a million land titles, increase investment and generate greater efficiency of land use through

the development of land markets, improve tax collection and land use planning (World Bank,

2002). These benefits were anticipated from a programme which was justified in terms of its

ability to address “the overriding problem and the one with the greatest contribution to poverty”

in Cambodia, namely “land tenure security (and the associated landlessness)” (World Bank, 2002,

p. 4) and that this was related specifically to “suggestions that state agents such as the military

and politically connected people have dispossessed people of their land, which is being facilitated

by the lack of formal recognition of rights on those lands” (World Bank, 2002, p. 5. See also

section 4.4.1 above)

As we have seen, these statements are a lumping together of unrelated problems which occur in

quite different places. Rural landlessness was indeed prevalent and increasing throughout the sort

of agricultural smallholding regions of rural Cambodia where systematic land titling has been

implemented. However, it was not a product of tenure insecurity but of poverty, as was clearly

established by research into landlessness carried out in 1999-2000 that is cited elsewhere in the

LMAP Project Appraisal Document (Biddulph, 2000d). If rural landlessness had been the main

problem, then the programme might arguably have been being implemented in the right place, but

Page 123: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

105

it would have been the wrong programme. The other problems mentioned: tenure insecurity,

restricted access to common property resources and dispossession of people by well-connected

business interests are, as we have seen, all problems which occur outside the agricultural

smallholder regions and therefore outside the places where LMAP has been implemented.

The World Bank, the major financier of the LMAP project, however, especially during the early

years of the research for this thesis, continually related the tenure security argument to

smallholder agriculture. For example, in its 2006 Poverty Assessment where it was suggested that

Cambodia needed a third engine of economic growth to complement the existing drivers of

garment factories and tourism. The poverty assessment suggested not only that smallholder

farming had the potential to be that third engine, but that the most important measure for enabling

smallholder farming to realise that potential was enhancing tenure security (World Bank, 2006, p.

88).

Community forestry, meanwhile, in so far as it is intended to extend rights to forests to people

who live in and near them, does potentially challenge elite interests. It requires the redistribution

of (at least) usufruct rights from powerful commercial interests and their partners within the

national political and military establishments, to local communities. However, progress with

approving community forestry initiatives was so slow and so partial that it would be difficult not

to interpret this as a form of quiet resistance on the part of the national leadership. Moreover,

where community forestry projects have been implemented, the role of the Forestry

Administration as both partner and regulator has led to the projects being diverted towards areas

which are relatively small and already degraded. So again, the intervention has been diverted

away from the places where its theoretical justification suggests it should be (forests which have

not yet been severely degraded and which offer livelihood possibilities), and instead diverted to

places where it cannot make much difference (areas where the resources are already degraded and

where the resource needs to be rehabilitated).

It is at this point that we encounter the central argument emerging from this thesis, which links

the geographies of evasion found in this chapter to the cases of misrepresentation in the early

chapter by means of the identification of a particular sort of development industry overreach.

Generally, the term overreach might be applied when an organisation attempts to implement

plans which it does not have the capacity or resources to carry out. In the specific terms of this

thesis, overreach by the development industry is defined in terms of its relationship to the

national elite and its political projects (understood in terms of the operation of a

shadow/developmental state). Systematic land titling is allowed to travel freely in the lowland

areas of Cambodia where there are no major accumulation projects by the political elite. In those

areas it is not in overreach. To the extent that land titling or community forestry, attempt to

generate entitlements to land which is coveted by the elite, they have to be resisted. The

resistance here involves diverting systematic land titling away from the places where the elite

have their projects, and diluting community forestry such that it is in such weak forms that it does

not present a threat. Meanwhile, however, the output-oriented management and reporting of the

development industry means that this resistance, which robs the interventions of the major

potentials claimed for them, is concealed by the fact that the outputs continue to be produced.

Land titles continue to be issued, community forestry sites continue to be registered, and all of

these are marked press releases ritually celebrating the interventions as successes.

Page 124: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

106

These then are the beginnings of theory in relation to geographies of development intervention.

The development industry attempts to extend its reach beyond where the host nation political elite

is comfortable; the result of this overreach is not the cancellation or visible thwarting of

interventions, but rather a quiet resistance which involves them either being diverted away from

places where the elite and their clients have interests, or diluted such that they have little effect.

This geography of evasion – solutions missing the problems they are claimed to address – goes

relatively unremarked as a facade of success is constructed linking project outputs to a

misrepresented version of the lives and livelihoods of the people who are scheduled to benefit.

The village case studies in Chapter 5 and Chapter 6 will provide a critical lens with which to view

this nascent theory. First however, I will illustrate the issue of overreach in relation to the land

sector in Cambodia with reference to my own earlier experiences, and also with subsequent

events relating to the LMAP project in the urban areas which are beyond the immediate empirical

scope of this thesis, but which help to illuminate its arguments and their relevance.

4.5.2 Applying a Geographies of Evasion Hypothesis

The implied hypothesis from the argument above is that if the development industry goes into

overreach (attempts to extend rights to people which conflict with the interests of the national

elite), geographies of evasion (comprising diversion, dilution and facades of success) will result.

During 1999 when working with the Oxfam GB Cambodia Land Study Project I accompanied a

colleague on a tour of informal settlements in Phnom Penh. People crowded onto the sides of

railway lines, on the public land by the entrance to pagodas, on rooftops of apartment buildings

and in large settlements by rivers and lakes. All of these communities were recognised up to a

point by the city authorities. They were organised into groups, and had village or community

leaders who were recognised by the state and who the government would deal with. What the

government did not recognise, however, was their permanent right to settle the land which they

occupied. Government officials stressed that this was State land and that people were living there

on sufferance. In the decade since that time urban tenure security has continued to be a front-page

issue in Cambodia, as one by one many of those informal communities have been displaced from

their land and more or less willingly resettled onto more or less suitable out-of-town sites. The

intentions of the (shadow/developmental) state were never in doubt.

Shortly after the completion of the field work for this thesis an NGO report called Untitled

(Grimsditch & Henderson, 2009), was issued which linked developments in these informal

settlements to the implementation of the LMAP project. A community settled in and around a

large lake near the centre of Phnom Penh had been scheduled to have their title registered by the

LMAP project. However, in anticipation of a land development deal struck between the

(shadow/development state) authorities and a private company, the community was quietly

removed from the schedule, an example of the geography of evasiveness described in this thesis.

The report was followed up by a request from the NGOs (COHRE, 2009) for an investigation of

the LMAP project, and of the World Bank support to that project for failing to uphold World

Bank standards in relation to involuntary resettlement and project supervision (Zoellick, 2009).

This prompted a World Bank commissioned external review of the project (Bekhechi & Lund,

2009) and a World Bank Management Response to the request (World Bank, 2009b).

Page 125: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

107

Here, then, was a case of international development actors (in this case NGO workers in projects

with the urban poor) attempting to push a rights-based intervention into a place where powerful

figures in the shadow/developmental state would rather it did not go. The World Bank response

was partly to begin dismantling the facade: it no longer pointed to the project document‟s

ambitious claims, but rather to its ambiguities:

The project was to be a limited and phased in contribution to a very complex development

problem, although the Project Description in the PAD (Project Appraisal Document)

failed to make this clear (World Bank, 2009b, p. 26).

And began stressing the geographical distinctions that had previously been glossed over:

The Project was never envisaged, nor did it have the resources, to address all of the land

conflicts in the Project provinces (World Bank, 2009b, p. 26).

In addition to highlighting the limitations of titling, the Bank also reflected on the less successful

elements of the LMAP project. These were precisely the elements that involved extending the

reach of the programme beyond simply issuing title in dispute-free areas. LMAP had not made

progress with land management (which would mean taking official control of the State land

which, as we have seen, constitutes an insecure landscape of accumulation and dispossession in

the Cambodian countryside), nor had it made progress with legal assistance for the

disadvantaged, safeguards or community participation. Once the project attempted to go beyond

the landscapes where the shadow/developmental state was comfortable with its operations it had

floundered.

Nevertheless, the NGO report encouraged the Bank to try and ensure that rights were extended to

the people living in and around the Boeung Kak lake. What possibility was there that the

development industry might be able to resist the attempts by the shadow/developmental state to

divert it? I will answer this question indirectly at first by looking at the results of attempts to

achieve justice for groups threatened with dispossession, before returning to the cases in this

thesis.

In 2003 I conducted an evaluation of British Embassy support to a Legal Aid NGO and a Human

Rights NGO for their work in relation to land rights. As part of that evaluation I asked not only

those two organisations but all other legal aid and human rights organisations working in the field

for examples of cases of land disputes where the plaintiffs had successfully received back all of

the land that had been taken from them. There was just one such case. A land dispute in

Ratanakiri which after exceptional efforts by a range of organisations over several months,

involving lobbying the government via the king and various foreign embassies eventually led to

the Prime Minister ordering a senior military officer to return land to a native ethnic minority

community (Biddulph, 2003a). By 2008 a similar situation obtained. Little progress was being

made generally by human rights and legal aid NGOs in relation to land disputes, but there was

one outstanding case where a USAID supported NGO had successfully lobbied for “fair and just

compensation” for a group of 78 households who were due to be evicted from an island on the

Mekong (Blue & Underwood, 2008, p. 35). However, the evaluation of the programme which

supported them concluded that the main effect of the case was to ensure that the government

became more careful in ensuring that investors had a strong legal for evicting communities, for

Page 126: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

108

example by issuing case specific sub-decrees supporting the investment. Generally, according to

the evaluation,

In cases where very ―powerful and wealthy‖ people from outside come in with

government issued documents, villagers can organize and protest, but the best they can

hope for is that the situation ―remains unresolved‖, while they continue to live on their

land as long as possible. There is little optimism or faith that ―powerless‖ people can

receive justice in the courts against more ―powerful‖ investors. They also said that when

very powerful outside interests are involved, local commune leadership is co-opted,

threatened, or ―bought‖ to insure [sic] cooperation with the investors (Blue &

Underwood, 2008, p. 31).

In other words, the cumulative experience of attempts by development industry actors to extend

rights to people in conflict with business interests connected to the shadow/developmental state,

reinforce the main findings and conclusions of this chapter. The geographies of evasion that see

interventions located away from the main problems they claim to address are rooted in a dynamic

where the development industry has ambitions to extend rights that the shadow/development state

is not prepared to enforce. Development industry attempts to try and combat the

shadow/development state projects are likely to be thwarted.

4.6 Summary

This chapter has contributed to the overall enquiry of the thesis into the relationship between

property rights interventions and rural livelihoods by investigating the relationship between the

geography of tenure insecurity and the geographies of systematic land titling and community

forestry.

Twice in its post-colonial history, Cambodia has been endowed with the trappings of multi-party

democracy, and each time a leader consolidated his power such that his rule became immune to

interruption by electoral means. In the patronage systems headed by Sihanouk and then by Hun

Sen, security, to the extent that it has been available to poor people, has come not from the rule of

law, but from the ability to at best be recruited into patronage networks, and at worst, at least

avoid conflicts with anyone better connected.

Post-colonial interventions, whether military or developmental have ultimately proven unfruitful.

The UNTAC intervention became emblematic of a tendency for international actors to promise

transformation, but to effect change at only the most superficial of levels. The peace promised by

UNTAC was only forthcoming five years later when deals brokered by Cambodian politicians

came to fruition. The democracy promised by the 1993 Constitution and the electoral political

system, much like its 1946 predecessor, has become a more distant prospect with time.

The current Prime Minister has consolidated power, including by allowing economic opportunity

to supporters and rivals on the condition that they ally themselves to him. During the 1990s,

forest management played a critical and contradictory role. On the one hand the destruction of the

forest resource, with negligible gain to the national treasury, was criticised, as was the way in

which the deforestation funded the conflict after international patrons ceased to finance the

guerrilla war of the 1980s. On the other hand, the general reorientation of the military of all

factions towards economic goals, and the way in which the current Prime Minister was able to

Page 127: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

109

use the exploitation and distribution of rents to consolidate his power laid the ground for the

demobilisation of the Khmer Rouge and the conditions of peace, stability and growth that

followed.

Tenure insecurity in Cambodia has been shaped by the nature of the transitions that the country

has undergone, particularly the transitions from a State to a market economy, and from war to

peace. The transference of State land into private use has proceeded ahead of any legal regulation

that would allow such transfers. All land that might previously have been considered State land or

common land has become de facto potentially private land reallocated through neo-patrimonial

networks to behind-the-scenes shadow/developmental state actors. Poorer households settled on

such land are insecure in their tenure because they find themselves in competition with wealthy,

well-connected business interests who are able to mobilise local and/or military support for their

investments. The transition to peace has been geographically uneven: many parts of central

Cambodia have been at peace since 1979, whilst more remote forested areas, especially in the

north-west, were still host to fighting up to the mid to late 1990s. In these places, the combination

of displacement of civilian populations and the establishment of military interests has led to

uncertainty over ownership rights. Again, poor settler households are particularly insecure when

their interests are set against those of wealthy military commanders, who are again networked

into shadow/developmental state relationships.

By contrast, for smallholder rice farming lands that have been at peace since the early 1980s,

tenure insecurity has not generally been a problem. Possession has been secured by traditional

norms of inheritance and usage, and the existence of a market for land since the early 1980s

indicates that this possession is de facto ownership.

There has been some tendency for economically valuable land to become insecure, but again, this

seems to follow the distinctions above: so where land is communal or former State property it is

more likely to be taken from the possessor, but where the land has been inherited or distributed

by the authorities in the early 1980s, then it is likely to be purchased rather than expropriated.

The Land Management and Administration Project (LMAP) of the Ministry of Land

Management, Urban Planning and Construction receives financial and technical support from the

World Bank, and the governments of Germany, Finland and (in the latter part of this research)

Canada. The systematic land titling component of that project aims to stimulate economic growth

by improving tenure security such that: farmers dare to invest more in their land, therefore

increasing agricultural productivity; farmers are able to use their land as collateral and therefore

access credit either for agricultural or other investment; the land market operates more efficiently

such that land ends up in the hands of the most efficient farmers.

Thus far, in rural areas, systematic land titling has only been implemented in smallholder rice

farming landscapes. The LMAP project director has explained that he is reluctant to begin the

programme in places where it might suffer reversals and difficulties. The procedures for

identifying implementation areas, whereby provincial governors make a request to the Ministry

for assistance in a particular district, also ensure that the programme is not implemented in areas

where it might prove troublesome for the authorities.

Community forestry has been implemented by a broad range of international development

organisations throughout the country since the early 1990s. These organisations have also lobbied

Page 128: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

110

for government recognition of community forestry initiatives, leading to the adoption of a

Community Forestry Sub-Decree in 2003 and the issuance of a Community Forestry Prakas in

2006. Community forestry has been promoted as a means of maintaining „traditional‟ forest-

based livelihoods, especially in relation to harvesting of resin, but also enabling improved

management of degraded forests.

Efforts to support community forestry have recently concentrated on winning government

approval for all proposed community forestry projects. Community forestry projects are scattered

across the country in various provinces. This geography often reflects the operational areas of the

organisations who have supported community forestry. The common trend, however, has been for

community forests only to be approved in forests that are already degraded, and not in areas

where high value resin trees remain uncut. This is partly attributable to the Forestry

Administration directing communities away from high value forests which may be of short term

commercial interest and towards degraded forests.

When looking for the relationship between the geography of immanent development in the form

of tenure insecurity and the geography of intentional development in the form of the property

rights interventions of systematic land titling and community forestry, the relationship appears to

be one way. The pattern of tenure insecurity has influenced the distribution of the tenure security

interventions, but the tenure security interventions have not modified the patterns of tenure

insecurity. Overall, this could be characterised as a geography of evasion, with systematic land

titling being implemented only in places where tenure is secure, and community forestry

implemented only in places where forest has already been degraded. To the extent that national

authorities have channelled interventions away from areas where insecurity is a problem this

might be termed diversion, while to the extent that the interventions have been allowed but in

weakened form, this might be termed dilution. The reporting against indicators which show

progress but do not in fact represent the changes that they purport to represent might be

characterised as the production (or co-production) of a facade. The combination of factors

constituting a geography of evasion is initiated by development interventions going into

overreach, in other words attempting to extend their influence to places and issues where the

shadow/developmental state is not supportive of their agenda.

Page 129: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

111

5. Community Forestry in Bey village

5.1 Introduction

In the early months of 2003, a community forestry project was initiated in by a local organisation

I shall call the Better Lives Organisation72

(BLO) in a village in north-east Cambodia which I

shall call Bey. BLO is based in the provincial town of Kracheh, and initially received funding

from a small US-registered NGO called here Active Communities (AC). BLO‟s community

forestry projects were subsequently incorporated into an internationally-supported project co-

financed by the European Union and managed by the British NGO Oxfam. This chapter will

describe and analyse the community forestry project in Bey village. It will describe the

intervention as it was experienced in the village using the results of our interviews and surveys in

the village to inform the narrative. Perspectives from other actors in the story will then follow:

Cambodian and international NGOs, a multilateral donor organisation and the local representative

of the foreign company that has a concession in the district. Finally, I will reflect on the case in

terms of its contribution to our knowledge and understanding of community forestry in Cambodia

in relation to themes established earlier in this thesis, including how it develops our

understandings of the “geography of evasiveness” which started to emerge from the national case

study in Chapter 4.

Before focusing on the intervention, however, the village itself and its recent history will be

described in order to give insights into the livelihood trajectories of the villagers and the forces

and actors which shape those trajectories. These constitute the local geography of immanent

development onto which the local geography of intentional development will be mapped.

Trajectories and pathways are metaphors which are used in the literature on livelihoods to suggest

a balance between structure and agency in shaping people‟s livelihoods. As such they are

something of a statement of the obvious: of course people‟s livelihoods are not wholly

determined by outside forces, but of course people‟s livelihoods are not entire in their own hands

either. This statement of the obvious represents the striking of balance in the debate. The

livelihoods literature itself arises as a development of Chambers‟ (1983)„farmer first‟ and „putting

the last first‟ arguments, which are based on the idea that intervention needs to be better informed

by an understanding of the situation and of the poor and of their own knowledge and abilities.

The concept of „trajectory‟ or „pathway‟ simply redresses the balance by clarifying that people‟s

knowledge and ability alone are unlikely to be sufficient to change their economic situation

(Scoones, 1998, p. 10). The image of a path is particularly useful here, as a path can be imagined

in different landscapes: one might have an open view and be able to see where paths lead and

72

BLO is a pseudonym, as is AC.

Page 130: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

112

make an informed and safe choice about which to take. On the other hand paths may be winding

and unpredictable as well as difficult and dangerous to leave. Without labouring the point further

I would suggest that one thing that is lacking in livelihoods literature is a sense of what particular

pathways might look like. In the experiences of the village of Bey it is possible to discern some

general lessons that might usefully be highlighted regarding livelihoods trajectories in landscapes

undergoing deforestation, a point that I will return to later.

5.2 Immanent Development: Lives and Livelihoods in Bey

5.2.1 Modern history of a Village in Forest

5.2.1.1 Location

Bey is located in northeast Cambodia, in the north of Chhlong district, in Kracheh province.

Chhlong district town is located on the eastern bank of the Mekong river about 240 kilometers

from Phnom Penh and about thirty kilometres short of the provincial town of Kracheh, and about

20 kilometers from the district town of Chhlong.

Bey is one of the remoter villages in the district accessible by four-wheeled vehicle only in the

dry season. It is also remote within the commune as the commune office is about ten kilometres

south of the village, not on the routes used regularly by the villagers to travel down to the

Mekong, and barely traversable during the wet season. There are two other settlements in the

area, which officially constitute one village. One of them, which I shall call „Pram‟, is about two

kilometres south-west of Bey, the other - „Pram Toich‟ - is about six kilometres away. At the

beginning of the research period Pram Toich barely existed, but by the time our work was

complete in 2009 it contained about 40 households.

5.2.1.2 1950-1970 Pre-War Lives and Livelihoods

Fifty years ago Bey was a village of 15-20 households found along the banks of the river Bey. At

night villagers were fearful of elephants and tigers (Interview 115). They were also afraid of

bandits who might raid the village. To ward off these threats a fence was built around the village,

fires were lit and maintained all night, and villagers took it in turn to patrol the perimeter fence.

Recalling those times, none of the older villagers can ever remember a time when they were

raided by bandits, but they do recall villagers‟ dogs being taken by tigers (Interview 93, 109).

Unlike today (when radios and televisions and even the occasional karaoke machine can be heard

in the village), it used to be quiet at night, with only the sound of somebody playing a traditional

three-stringed instrument (Interview 89).

Page 131: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

113

Figure 5-1. Map of Cambodia Showing Districts Where the Case Study Villages are Located

While physical security was a concern, food security generally was not. The forest and the river

at that time provided abundant animals, fruits and fish (Interview 115). There was little farming

done in the village: in order to obtain rice villagers mainly traded forest produce such as resin,

animals and illicitly cut wood with traders down on the Mekong. Such farming as was practiced

took place in an area to the east of the village – this was often swidden farming, with small areas

of land being cleared and burned and then planted for just a couple of years. Some rice would be

grown but mainly people traded rattan, resin, vines and leaves for rice that was imported to the

district from Battambang province (Interview 12). Rattan was abundant then compared with

today, and was possibly the most important source of income ahead of resin, (Interview 13, 31).

The forest was dense and from the Mekong, fifteen kilometres away, all the way to the village,

the road was overshadowed by tall hardwood trees, which villagers recalled with some nostalgia

(Interview 12, 31). It was not a good road and when it rained it became a stream (Interview 109).

While some villagers say that there was no trading of timber in those times and that it was only

cut for local use (Interview 109), others say that there was always some trading of timber, but that

cutting was by hand and therefore not on a large scale (Interview 85, 97). Although the main

access road was hardly more than an oxcart track, forestry officials could drive along this road in

an old jeep left by the French. The forestry officials were a rare example of the reach of the state

extending to the village. However, villagers cutting timber for sale would evade these officials in

their vehicles by following narrow oxcart tracks that wound through the forest (Interview 89).

Page 132: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

114

The location along the river banks prior to the 1960s had been partly to have access to water and

partly because the access to road, which was little more than a track, was used by wild animals,

including elephants, which the villagers did not want to lead into the village area. In the late

1960s a senior official close to Prince Sihanouk encouraged the relocation of all settlements to the

road, promising that the road would be built properly and there would be development73

.

However, the 1970 coup occurred before that promise could be fulfilled (Interview 93).

This relative isolation from the wider society was to change dramatically over the years, as first

war and then machines and markets transformed the physical and social landscape to produce the

village that was the subject of my research at the beginning of the twenty-first century.

5.2.1.3 1970-1994 Conflict and Its Aftermath: A local history

According to where people lived in Cambodia before and during the 1970s, their experience of

civil war and of the Khmer Rouge period was radically different. People from Phnom Penh and

its environs refer to the Khmer Rouge time as being 3 years, 8 months and 20 days. This covers

the span between 17 April 1975, when resistance forces led by the Khmer Rouge took Phnom

Penh and 7 January 1979, when the Vietnamese supported the overthrow of the Khmer Rouge.

In the north-eastern province of Kracheh, where Bey is located, the transition to Khmer Rouge

control was early, and the population was already wearing the distinctive black uniforms

demanded by the Khmer Rouge long before 1975 when the population of Phnom Penh welcomed

the child soldiers who proclaimed revolution and victory over Lon Nol and the Americans

(Interview 108).

After 1979, furthermore, when much of southern Cambodia was relatively peaceful, the forests of

Kracheh remained immersed in conflict. Just two or three kilometres east of Bey, Khmer Rouge

battalions were based in the forest. When they launched raids against the district town, villagers

from Bey were often co-opted as foot soldiers (Interview 69). Meanwhile, the government

military were also regular visitors to the village. In common with many other such villages in

forest fringes throughout the country, the villagers had to learn to host both sides, and to deal

with the consequences of being fully trusted by neither. Soldiers would interrogate and beat

villagers, with forces on each side trying to make sure that they were getting honest answers to

questions about the movements of the other (Interview 108).

During the 1980s the population of the village varied between about twenty and thirty

households. Of these about a dozen remained in place throughout those years, while the

remainder rotated, villagers successively leaving the village to join the Khmer Rouge, but then

after a time leaving the Khmer Rouge and handing themselves into the authorities at district, and

then later perhaps returning to the village again. Meanwhile, trade between Bey and the villages

on the Mekong continued. Oxcarts would travel up to the village carrying fish and prahok74

, and

would travel back down to the river laden with forest products. Traders going out to the forest

73

It seems safe to assume that there would have been a security aspect to this as well as a development aspect: that

government wanted populations on roads where they were easily monitored and accessible rather than in remote

forests where opposition militaries might organize. 74

A form of crushed, salted, fermented fish. Ubiquitous in the countryside it is considered to be both essentially

Khmer and to be poor person‟s food.

Page 133: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

115

would carry rice with them, hidden from view so that government soldiers would not see it. Then

when out in the forest they would leave bags of rice well in front of the places where they were

cutting leaves or wood, this in the expectation that the Khmer Rouge soldiers would take the rice

and in return let them work uninterrupted (Interview 108).

Following the failure of the United Nations peace process to bring peace throughout Cambodia,

Bey continued to be insecure. As late as early 1994 a villager trod on a land-mine just east of the

village and died from his injuries. In mid-1994 the Khmer Rouge units based in the forest near

the village finally surrendered to the district authorities in order to be reintegrated into

mainstream society (Interview 108).

The deputy village chief also arrived in the village in 1994, taking up his appointment there as

soon as he moved and in many respects becoming the de facto village chief. This was probably

because the authorities down at the river wanted to consolidate their influence in the village by

placing somebody trusted in a position of influence in the village75

. Even those who are most

implacably opposed to him and accuse him of serving only himself and not the community,

acknowledge that he is the most literate and capable person in the village (Interview 64).

Meanwhile, two Khmer Rouge commanders, both originally from neighbouring Kampong Thom

province, settled in the village at the end of the conflict and are prominent figures in village life.

Their popularity and respect amongst other villagers is indicated by the fact that both men were

elected to serve on the lay committee for the village pagoda in 2008, coming first and third in the

election (Interview 71). One, Loke Peit, was the only private medical practitioner in the village

until 2008, so had been invited into nearly every household in the village over the years. As a

youth he had been one of the soldiers who entered Phnom Penh in 1975 to first liberate and then

evacuate it. He learned his medical skills when he was posted away from a fighting unit on the

border with Vietnam to command a medical unit, where he learned informally from the soldiers

under his command. He is married to a cousin of the deputy village chief, indicating that even if

old allegiances have some influence, it is also possible to transcend, or at least blur, them

(Interview 11). The other former Khmer Rouge commander, Chan, built a house slightly outside

the village, though recent migration into the village and the expansion of the village area means

that he is now surrounded by neighbours (Interview 64). He has been the leader of the village

Community Forest project since shortly after its inception, being elected in 2003 and re-elected in

2007. He also provides health services through being a village volunteer in an anti-malaria

programme – for which he receives a monthly fee the equivalent of 12.5 USD. Villagers who

suspect they have malaria get a blood test from him and if it is positive he can treat them

immediately, as several testified (e.g.Interviews 6, 18, 45, 54). Another Khmer Rouge soldier had

defected from the Khmer Rouge earlier after her husband had, without telling her, left the

movement, taken another wife and become a government informer. She had initially struggled to

gain acceptance in the village, her residence being vigorously opposed by some of the older men

who have since died (Interview 22). Nevertheless, other villagers befriended her, and she is now a

75

He was by no means new to the village. He and his father used to travel through it to cut leaves and timber and

trade them in pre-war times. Indeed, it was on a journey back from the village in 1973 that his father dropped him to

do some work on a rice field and he watched as his father continued his journey and was killed by an American

fighter plane (Interview 108). The pattern of a milder, village chief being slightly peripheral compared with a more

competent, better-connected figure (usually but not necessarily the deputy) is not universal but is certainly common,

as is also reflected, for example in the village of Buon and in the village studies in Hasselskog (2000).

Page 134: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

116

popular and respected figure, and was also amongst those elected to the first community forestry

committee in 2003 (Interview 71).

5.2.1.4 1994-2006 Peace and Development

Throughout its modern history as a village in forest, Bey had previously had a relatively stable

relationship with both the forest, and with the state as a somewhat remote custodian of the forest.

After the uncertainties and challenges of war, however, peace brought a new set of uncertainties

and challenges to the village. The forest‟s permanence was challenged, and the state‟s role, and

especially that of the officials responsible for forests, became far more ambivalent. The main

manifestation of this, which influenced not just Bey, but the whole of Chhlong district and part of

neighbouring Snoul, was the government signing a forest concession agreement with a joint

Soviet Union-Cambodian venture called Casotim (Cambodia Soviet Timber76

). The industrial

scale logging which followed transformed livelihoods in the village. The succession of new

actors and activities associated with the logging over that period are described below. One

consequence of the logging was that the road to the village was no longer in the shade of forest

(Interview 41). New villages, mainly populated by Cham settlers from along the Mekong, were

established along the road, and areas of the degraded forest were claimed for agriculture both by

these new settlers and also by other Cham households who remained on the river.

5.2.2 Livelihoods Shaped by Deforestation

5.2.2.1 Loggers and Rent-seekers Transform the Landscape

During the initial period after peace broke out change was gradual. Many former residents came

back to the village, which brought it back to its pre-war population of about thirty households.

Trade between Bey and the villages on the Mekong began to intensify as oxcarts could move

without fear. One visible change was the arrival of very large oxcarts which were used for

transporting large hard-wood tree trunks out of the forest. Apparently, these had huge wooden

wheels, up to two meters in diameter, and were pulled by as many as five pairs of buffalo. They

were mainly owned by Cham people who lived near the Mekong, though members of the Khmer

majority also had such oxcarts (Interview 108).

The major changes, however, were initiated when the Casotim company became operational in

the area. Casotim had obtained a 120 000 hectare forest concession covering all of the forests of

Chhlong district as well as a portion of neighbouring Snoul district. Initially, it only had eight of

its own trucks operating in the area. Each of these might carry 10-15 cubic meters of wood per

journey, and make 4-5 journeys per day. Within a year or so, however, the logging operation had

opened up. Anyone with a tractor or truck that could carry felled trees from the forest to the

Mekong was able to pay a fee to Casotim to go into the forests, cut wood, and then sell it to the

company. As many as fifty locally owned tractors and trucks participated in this business

(Interview 108).

This relatively free local trade continued for the last years of the 1990s with the Casotim

company, local business people and villagers apparently unregulated. In about 2000, however,

76

I am indebted to one of my interviewees for pointing out to me that this name was in fact an English acronym .

Page 135: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

117

there was change as other institutions became active out in the forest. First amongst these were

the military and the Forestry Administration (FA)77

. Villagers‟ perception was that both the

military and the FA worked for the concessionaires. In the case of the military, the ties with

villagers were sufficiently strong (including soldiers who married into the village) that villagers

knew that the military received two salaries: one from the ministry of defence and another from

the logging company. For the villagers, these soldiers were known simply as the „Casotim

soldiers‟. Villagers did not know for sure that the Forestry Administration officials received

payments from Casotim in the same way, but they assumed that the relationship was similar

(Interview 108).

These institutions played the role of informal regulators and tax collectors. Anyone operating in

the forest was now supposed to have permission otherwise they risked having to pay a fine or

having their equipment confiscated. The local police were soon active in the same practice, and

finally also the „Gendarmerie‟ or „PM‟ – French-trained “military police” units.

Amongst our interviewees the fees that people paid to be allowed to cut and transport wood

varied. The lowest reported monthly fee was by a household that reported paying 10 USD per

month to the military and nothing to the police apart from small voluntary payments of 3-5 USD

“because I have known them for years and they are like relatives” (Interview 112). The highest

was reported by a household who reported paying 25 USD per month to the military and 25 USD

per month to the PM (Interview 43). The deputy village chief, reporting the general rates,

suggested that they were even higher (50 USD per month to the military, 20 USD to the PM and

10 USD to the police), and that these were just the fees for villagers; that traders from the

Mekong had to pay much higher rates (Interview 108). On occasions a villager would have their

chainsaw confiscated by the Forestry Administration, or by the police or military. In these cases

the chainsaw could often be reclaimed by the owner who paid a fee and could be back in the

forest cutting again within a couple of days (Interview 99). The amount that had to be paid to

recover a chainsaw if it was confiscated varied from as low as 50 USD (Interview 77) and as high

as 100-150 USD (Interview 104). Notwithstanding the variations from household to household,

the fees were experienced as fairly predictable, but also unfair, especially in that police and

military never charged or fined each other (Interviews 26, 101).

Following the onset of activities by these institutions in about 2000-2001, came another

significant change to the local timber economy. Coinciding with a moratorium on commercial

logging in 2002, the logging trucks ceased their work and the industrial scale transport of huge

trunks ended. This was not, however, an end to the logging, but a signal for its continuation by

other means (Interview 108). Five local business men made agreements with Casotim, and as a

result were able to place a total of ten sawmills in the forest east of the village (Interview 101).

From that time, instead of a stream of heavy duty trucks carrying huge logs, there was a flow of

sawn planks on smaller improvised trucks or on oxcarts. Locally, this seemed to be understood as

being because there were no longer sufficient big trees for the industrial scale logging to

77

The Forestry Administration was until 2003 the Department for Forestry and Wildlife at the Ministry of

Agriculture Forestry and Fisheries, but was renamed the Forestry Administration and became more autonomous

following the passage of the 2003 Forestry Law. I recall occasional patrols of rifle-bearing officials in near-white

uniforms passing the minefield where we were working in late 1993 in Krakor district of Pursat province, and being

told by my Cambodian colleagues that these were forestry officials (or mei prey as they are colloquially known).

Page 136: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

118

continue, and therefore the processing of smaller trees via the sawmills in the forest became

prevalent (Interview 96, 108).

When our research began in 2006, this was still the state of affairs. Oxcarts passed through the

village every day: we never attempted to count them systematically, but perhaps between 15 and

30 oxcarts every day, occasionally more. Sometimes they travelled just one or two at a time,

sometimes in long convoys of eight or ten.

The landscape in which the village was set had thus been under transformation in the years of

peace prior to our research beginning. In 1994 Bey, was clearly a village in forest. At that time

the villages along the Mekong were beginning to gain the character of logging and timber trading

villages, but the forest frontier was essentially still along the river bank. The phase of industrial

logging, however, led to a degradation of forests. Hard wood trees, including the resin trees

which had been central to the livelihoods of many of the villagers who grew up in the forest, had

been removed from the landscape. When we arrived in 2006, there were large tracts of cleared

agricultural land along the road to the village, and much of the forest was scrubby and low.

Villagers and outsiders seeking commercial timber were already in 2006 having to travel further

and further to the east of the village to find suitable trees. Demand for timber was still the main

economic driver, and land prices were still remarkably low in comparison to lowland Cambodia.

However, the deforestation was taking its toll: Bey was no longer unequivocally a village in

forest. Whilst already in 2006 villagers were reporting that all of the good quality wood had

already been taken (Interview 96), by 2009 the flow of oxcarts and trucks had almost ceased and

villagers working in logging were heading to the neighbouring province of Mondolkiri in order to

find work (Interview 29).

5.2.2.2 2004-2008: Demographic Transformation – a trickle becomes a flood

During our village censuses in 2006 and 2008 we asked when each person in the village was

born, and when they first came to the village. By this means we were able to gain an impression

of how the village‟s population had fluctuated over the years. During the twenty-five years from

1975-2004 an average of 2.1 new households were formed each year (either through marriage or

through immigration of new couples). The steady trickle of households coming into the village

did not seem to have been matched by a flow out: the deputy village chief could only recall two

families having left the village (both to go and live down on the Mekong) in the 12 years that he

had been keeping records (Interview 96). However, during 2005-6 there was a sudden

acceleration in household formation with 19 new families established in the village during the

twenty months before our research got underway (January 2005-August 2006). During that same

period, 31% of all households in the village reported occupying new house land and 48% of all

households built new houses. So not only were new household moving in to the village, but

existing households were rebuilding and often relocating their houses.

By August 2006 there were 86 households in the village. At that time only 48% of Bey‟s adults

were born in the village, whilst 36% of adults were members of households that contained no

adult members born in the village. This was a situation that had evolved over time. During the

course of the research the influx continued. When we repeated our census in 2008, the village had

grown from 83 to 137 households (a 65% increase in just two years). Only three of these new

households were formed through marriage of existing villagers – the remainder were all new in-

Page 137: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

119

migrants. This is reflected in Figure 5-2 which classifies village households according to the

birthplace of the adults in the village. The number of households where all adults had been born

in the village remained constant at 23, but this represented a decline from 34.8% to 16.8% of the

village population. Meanwhile, the number of households consisting solely of adults born outside

the village rose in absolute numbers from 14 to 75, and as a proportion from being the smallest

group within the village (21.2%) to the largest (54.7%). Villagers commonly spoke in favourable

terms of the increased population saying that having more people in the village made it „happier‟

(Interview 21, 80, 85, 87, 110).

Source: Field Data, Village Censuses, Bey 2006 and 2008

Figure 5-2: Origins of Households in Bey in 2004, 2006, 2008 by Birthplace of Adults.

The source of migrants into the village has changed over time. Those adults born outside the

village but moving to it in the quarter of a decade prior to 2004 were almost all from within the

district: either from the nearby village of Pram, or from one of the villages on the Mekong.

Virtually all of the immigrants who came after 2004 came from neighbouring Kampong Cham

province. The three types of villager, then, original villagers, pre-2004 migrants from within the

district, and since-2004 migrants from Kampong Cham, each have quite different backgrounds

and abilities.

Firstly, there were the „original‟ villagers born in Bey. The village had not previously had a

school. Their educations were poor, and whilst they had a history of trading forest products for

food, they did not have a history of being involved in business. Their comparative advantage was

in the forest where they knew what was available in terms of timber, animals and other non-

timber forest products. Most of these „original villagers‟ had grown up in the old village centre

0

20

40

60

80

2004 (n=66)

2006 (n=83)

2008 (n=135)

All adults in HH are native to village

Mix of native and in-migrant adults

All adults in HH are in-migrants

Page 138: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

120

between the road junction and the eastern stream, although a number of them have recently

moved out of the centre of the village to either Bey Toich to the east, or to the Casotim road west

or south of the village.

Secondly there was the „first wave‟ of immigrants, who were part of the steady trickle into the

village up to the mid-2000s. They had grown up in villages along the Mekong, where there were

schools. In addition to being better educated, many had grown up in business-oriented

households, and specifically had been involved in the timber trade. In contrast with the „original‟

villagers they are entrepreneurial – constantly looking for opportunities to buy and sell at a profit.

The half a dozen little trading stores in the village are all run by in-migrants, and not by original

villagers.

Table 5-1: Location of Adult Residents of Bey, 1-3 August 2006

Location Frequency78

Percent

In or near village 186 92

Beyond village area but within province 12 6

In another province (not Phnom Penh) 2 1

In Phnom Penh 2 1

203 100

Source: Field Data, Village Census 1-3 August, 2006.

This is reflected in Table 5-2 which shows the main source of income reported by each household

in a questionnaire administered in our penultimate field trip in late 2008.

Thirdly, there was a „new wave‟ of immigrants who had been part of the sudden flood into the

village since 2005. They come from neighbouring Kampong Cham province and their intention

has been to buy land and clear it for agriculture. Some were poorer households who had been

forced to look for a cheaper place to live having come upon hard times in their home districts

(e.g.Interview 15). Others were better off households, often late middle-aged couples who had

left their land at home to their adult children and had come to the village with surplus capital and

perhaps adult labour in the form of more adult children, so were well-set to make a new start

(e.g.Interview 3). Unlike the first wave immigrants (some of whom had been regular visitors to

Bey since the 1960s and knew the forest extremely well), the new wave from Kampong Cham are

not familiar with the local area, and are not used to moving around in the forest and harvesting its

resources.

Villagers themselves were very aware of the differences between them: the original villagers‟

comparative advantage at gathering NTFPs, the early migrants‟ comparative advantage at doing

business and the recent migrants‟ advantage at smallholder farming (e.g. Interviews 51, 85).

78

N= 204. Missing information = 1.

Page 139: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

121

Whilst there was never really an expectation that the original villagers would become business

people, they did, as we will see, develop the ambition to learn from the in-migrants and to

become capable farmers.

5.2.2.3 Livelihood Activities During the Research Period

This section describes the livelihood activities of villagers during the study period, and provides

detail regarding the uneven effects of the changes in opportunity available to villagers.

Table 5-2: Main Source of Income Reported by Household in Bey village, October 2008

Households formed before

August 2006

Households formed

August 2006-2008

All

households

Reported main income

source:

Sub-Total % Sub-total % Total %

Transporting and

Cutting79

wood

37 45.1 7 12.3 36 25.9

Agricultural labour

hire

16 19.5 29 50.9 45 32.4

Cutting wood 7 8.5 1 1.7 8 5.7

Selling own produce 5 6.1 1 1.7 6 4.3

Retail trading 4 4.9 3 5.3 7 5.0

Wages (police, NGO) 1 1.2 0 0 1 0.7

Selling desserts 1 1.2 0 0 1 0.7

Private medicine 1 1.2 1 1.7 2 1.4

Savings prior to

migration

0 0 7 12.3 7 5.0

Motorcycle taxi 0 0 1 1.7 1 0.7

Left village 4 4.9 0 0 4 2.9

Missing 6 7.3 5 8.8 11 7.9

Never existed80

1 1.2 0 0 1 0.7

Not yet moved in 0 3 5.3 3 2.2

Totals 82 99.8 57 100.0 139 99.7

Source: Field Data, Land and Livelihood Survey (2), October 2008.

79

Of the 36 responses, 29 mentioned only transporting wood while 7 mentioned either cutting on its own or cutting

and transporting wood. 80

One household was in the process of moving in August 2006 and thus had two houses. As a result we recorded it

twice, as household 47 and then as household 75. This error was identified and rectified in the census update in

October 2008.

Page 140: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

122

Before considering the specific activities, it is worth noting that while many of the villagers come

from further afield, once they are settled in the village their livelihoods have become

overwhelmingly local. The „village census‟ information which we gathered in early August 2006

served to illustrate this. Only 2% of Bey adults were out of the province at the time of the village

census, and fully 92% were in or near the village at the time the census interviews took place.

5.2.2.3.1 Timber-related Livelihood Activities

The cutting and transporting of wood was the major source of income for most households in the

village of Bey during the period of our research, as was evidenced, at least during 2006-8, by

regular traffic of oxcarts laden with planks. Our hosts in the village, the deputy village chief and

his wife, were amongst the leading timber traders. When we first met them they flatly denied any

involvement in logging. However, their house is on the main road through the village, with an

open front with a shop and a little wooden platform where women might chat and joke, or men

might smoke and drink and joke. In the course of our first week, men involved in transporting

timber either employed by or in partnership with our hosts often popped into the house to discuss

deals on their way through81

(Interview 100). The pretence of non-involvement quickly, and

without comment, evaporated (Interview 96).

Involvement in the timber trade took various forms, with varying degrees of economic reward. At

the top of the village timber business hierarchy were traders, who either bought timber, or hired

other villagers to cut and transport wood for them, and then sold, often to order, to other traders

located in the villages by the Mekong (Interviews 153, 154). One step down from these wood

traders were chainsaw operators either cutting wood and selling it themselves, or, more often,

working as day labour for traders. A further step down from that were people with oxcarts who

earned money transporting wood from the forest through the village and down to the villages on

eastern bank of the Mekong (see Photo at Figure 5-3). Finally, at the humblest level were people

without any capital equipment. They could either work as an assistant to a chainsaw operator (and

were wholly dependent on somebody calling them to come and work with them), or could work

transporting wood, by borrowing somebody else‟s oxen and oxcart and splitting the money fifty

percent with them (Interviews 15, 120).

As already noted, informal regulation of the informal timber trade was significant in shaping the

opportunities for villagers. Business skills and some financial capital were not sufficient to

guarantee business success, as the following case illustrates:

Kone Kmeich was born in Bey village in 1984. He is the son-in-law of Kim Nary in one of our

case study households. He is the main income earner for the household, mainly through his work

transporting wood which he does with his own oxcart. He is also a capable chainsaw operator. In

late 2006 he bought a chainsaw, for 240 USD.

81

„Interview‟ 100 was my short notes on observing one such conversation, and not an interview as such.

Page 141: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

123

Figure 5-3: Villager with an oxcart load of wood in Bey, January 2008 (Photo: Robin Biddulph).

In order to make a business of operating the chainsaw he needed to hire other people to work with

him both cutting and transporting, to provide them with food and cigarettes and also to pay for

the fuel for the chainsaw. He could cut about 0.6 cubic meters per day, which meant that he could

make a profit of approximately 52,800 riels (or 13 US dollars) per day (see Table 5-3).

Table 5-3: Calculations of Profitability for a Chainsaw Owner-Operator in Bey 2007

Costs per cubic meter (riels) Income per cubic meter (riels)

Machine operators 60,000

Transportation 60,000

Fuel 42,000

Food, drink, cigarettes

etc

50,000

Total 212,000 Sale price 300,000

Source: Field Data, Interview 24

Page 142: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

124

However, after he began operating the chainsaw for a time he had it confiscated twice in a short

period of time. On the first occasion, it was the police who took it and he had to pay 400 000 riels

(100 USD) to recover it. On the second occasion, in early April 2007, the military took it and he

had to pay them 300 000 riels (75 USD) to recover it. After these experiences he decided that it

was not worth the risk and the insecurity so he sold the chainsaw and reverted to the less

profitable business of transporting wood or working as a chainsaw operator for others (Interview

24).

Table 5-4: Timber Incomes in 8 Case Study Households, Bey village 2006-7

HH Household background and description % from

timber

2006-7

Other key

income

sources

4 Moved to village 2006 from Kampong Cham in order to

farm cleared forest. One of a group of related households.

Comfortably off. Intending to farm.

0% Profit on

move (71%)

16 Married couple moved to village in 1998 following

defection from Khmer Rouge.

0% Medical

practices

(66%)

28 Young couple with three children moved to village 2006

from Kampong Cham in order to farm cleared forest.

Relatively poor.

0% Profit on

move (62%)

31 She is single woman from neighbouring province. Main

earner is her son-in-law who was born in the village and

cuts and transports wood.

70%

43 Both in their forties. Were born in the village and have

always lived there. He uses their oxen and cart to transport

wood.

68%

56 She was born in the village but her husband, who she met

in western Cambodia, was born in Siem Reap and moved

into the village in 1986.

38% Agric labour

22%

Resin 23%

65 A young couple with two small children. They both came

to the village as young children, their parents are business

oriented (her father is deputy village chief).

83%

74 He is born in the village whilst she is from a timber-

trading village on the Mekong.

78%

Source: Field Data, Income and Expenditure Survey of 8 Case Study Households

Page 143: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

125

The importance of timber livelihoods during the early part of our research can be seen from the

proportions of household income reported from this source by the eight case study households in

early 2007 (see Table 5-4 below). Of these eight households, the four who have adult male

members who were born or brought up in the village are the four households where the majority

of reported income in 2006-7 came from cutting and transporting wood. In the hybrid household

where it is the woman who is native to the village and her husband comes from outside they

reported only 38% of their income coming from timber. The three other households, where no

adult household members had been born in the village, reported no income from timber.

The trend of new-arrivals not being involved in timber trading continued throughout the study

period. In January 2008, fifty-two (62%) of the 84 households who were interviewed, reported

incomes from cutting or transporting wood. By this time, however, the in-migrants from

Kampong Cham who had arrived by 2006 had had a further 18 months in the village. Now,

almost half of them (7 out of 15) reported incomes from cutting or transporting wood82

.

When the results of the land and livelihoods questionnaire that we administered in October 2008

were disaggregated according to when households were formed in the village (before or after

2006), and whether they contained adults born in the village, the same pattern was confirmed. As

Table 5-5indicates, households that were new to the village were not immediately participating in

the timber trade; households who had been established in the village for two years or more or

contained a native villager were far more likely to be engaged in timber trade activities.

Table 5-5: Households reporting Timber as Main Income Source in Bey village, Cambodia, 2008

#HH reporting timber as

main income

Total # HH

responding83

Households formed before 2006 37 (51%) 72

Post-2006 households containing existing

villagers

6 (60%) 10

Post-2006 households containing only

migrants

1 (3%) 39

Total 44 (36%) 121

Source: Field Data, Land and Livelihood Survey (2), October 2008

There were fluctuations in activity from visit to visit. Our penultimate trip in late 2008 seemed to

coincide with a major timber order suddenly chainsaws were in open view and there was sawing

going on throughout the village. On our last trip, however, in early 2009 we barely saw any wood

being transported. While extenuating circumstances may have played a part - the financial crisis

82

Households 6, 10, 28, 50, 59, 93, 94 reported incomes from timber. Households 3, 4, 11, 13, 22, 23, 49, 91

reported no incomes from timber. 83

121 out of a possible 135 households (90%) responded to this question.

Page 144: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

126

globally and a case of foot and mouth affecting oxen in the village locally - however it seemed

possible that the long-predicted exhaustion of local timber was now taking hold and that a

permanent decline in timber activities was finally beginning to occur.

5.2.2.3.2 Farming own land

The village has rice paddy fields in its immediate vicinity and also to the east of the immediate

village area. These have gradually been expanding with the village population, and are farmed

every year. The soil is good but the rice farming is rain fed and therefore vulnerable to the

exigencies of the weather: when the rains are suitable for the paddy in the centre of the village,

they are too much for the paddy in the east; when the harvest in the east is good, there is too little

rain for the fields in the centre of the village. Crop land which does not flood is known as

chamcar in Khmer. The villagers used to farm chamcar on a shifting basis in the forests to the

east of the village. After a lull during the 1980s when there was little farming outside the

immediate village area (Interview 108), agriculture began to resume with more clearing of

permanent plots. Increasingly, with interest in land and farming going hand in hand with the

degradation of the forest, households in the village have claimed larger tracts of chamcar

especially along the roads to the east of the village. It is rare now to find a household in Bey

where the members do not regard their future as tied up with their ability to acquire and farm

agricultural land.

As we have seen, though, this is a relatively recent break with the previous ways of earning a

living in the village where agriculture was basically a complement to forest-based activities. This

was certainly the case during the study period, with the majority of households owning rice land,

chamcar or both (see Table 5-6 below).

Table 5-6: Reported agricultural land holdings in Bey village, January 2008.

Reported agricultural land holding by type # Households %

Rice and Chamcar land 37 42%

Rice only 19 23%

Chamcar only 20 25%

No agric land reported 5 6%

Total responses 81 100%

Source: Field Data, Land and Livelihood Survey (1), January 2008.

In our October 1998 Land and Livelihood Survey (2), representatives of all available households

were asked about the main livelihood activity for their household. Only 6 of the 120 respondents

gave agriculture as their response. In 2009, however, when households were asked about their

hopes and expectations for a livelihood in the future, all respondents said that agriculture was

their key hope/expectation.

Page 145: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

127

One household‟s experiences have been particularly influential in stimulating people‟s ambitions

in relation to agriculture. They came to the village in 2005 with labour and capital to spare and an

intention to farm. In 2007 they planted 1.8 hectares of cassava, and made a profit of 1,800 USD.

Prior to this the idea of growing cash crops had been there, and some of the new households had

made a start with soya beans and other crops. However, there had been concerns that even if a

decent crop was produced it might not be possible to get it to market. The experience of that

household in 2007 demonstrated that large profits were possible. Suddenly, the vast majority of

villages, both newcomers from farming backgrounds in Kampong Cham, and long-term residents

with little or no experience of farming, were stating their intention to grow cassava.

Figure 5-4: Cassava ready for planting in Bey, 2008 (Photograph: Robin Biddulph).

Transforming forest, or degraded forest, to farm land does not happen overnight. Even cassava,

which can be grown without completely clearing the existing vegetation and without ploughing

the fields, requires significant labour. And families can only labour on their chamcar land if they

have another source of income or food to ensure that they can feed themselves and send their

children to school. This was illustrated by the responses to our questions about how much

chamcar land each household owned, and how much it had under crop. The average landholding

claimed after the 2007 harvest was 2.0 hectares, while the average area reported to be under crop

was 0.21 hectares; at the time of the 2008 harvest, for the same 81 households the respective

averages were 2.16 and 0.54 hectares. In other words, households had increased the proportion

that they farmed from about a tenth to about a quarter of their reported holdings. So clearing of

agricultural land had increased but most of the land in villagers‟ (informal) possession still had

not been cleared.

Page 146: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

128

The relationship between smallholder agriculture and farming in the village is reflected in the

experiences of the eight case study households. Buying agricultural land was usually part of the

entry of new households into the village. In this sense it was easier to access this form of

livelihood than to become engaged in timber related activities (where social networks and

knowledge of remote areas were key). For households such as HH04, who came with capital,

they were able to start clearing land and farming quite quickly; for poorer in-migrants such as

HH28 it was necessary to engage in other activities to solve day to day cash flow and food needs

so the progress in starting to farm was somewhat slower.

The increased focus on agriculture within the case study households is clear from the changes

through the year (see Table 5-7). Six of the eight households increased the amount of land under

cultivation between the end of 2007 and the end of 2008. The two households who did not

increase land under cultivation, did nevertheless buy more agricultural land in the course of that

year: these were both small households relying, for lifecycle reasons (i.e. mothers were at home

with small children), on the labour of one man involved in the timber industry.

Table 5-7: Case Study Households in Bey Village Land holding and farming, 2007 and 2008.

Origins of adult HH

members

HH

number

Rice land

owned

Chamcar owned:

chamcar farmed

2007 (ha)

Chamcar owned:

chamcar farmed

2008 (ha)

All adults born in

village

HH43 1 0.5 : 0 1.5 : 0.5

Some adults born in

village

HH56 0 3:0 3 : 0.2

HH74 1 0:0 1 : 0

HH31 1.5 6 : 0 6 : 2

No adults born in

village but local

HH65 0.3 0.8 : 0 2 : 0

HH16 0 1 : 0.5 2 : 1

No adults born in

village

HH04 1 3: 1.8 5.5 : 1.8

HH28 0 4 : 0 4 : 1.5

Source: Field Data, Land and Livelihood Survey (1) January 2008, Land and Livelihood Survey (2) October

2008

A central element of smallholder agriculture as a livelihood strategy is the inherent risk in an

activity where there is a gap of several months between the investment of effort and the return on

that investment. Following the success of the cassava crop in 2007 there was a rush to cassava in

2008 as villagers attempted to benefit from the 1000 USD per hectares that seemed to be

available. Unfortunately for them, and countless others throughout the region, the price of

cassava fell (Interview 92, 161). In Bey it fell from around 550 riels in 2007 to around 210 riels in

Page 147: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

129

2008. At this level a profit was still possible, but far from the sorts of levels that had been

anticipated and according to some it was not even possible to get 100 riels per kg at market

(Interview 140). Furthermore, because the price was low, and because it is possible to leave

cassava in the field after it is ripe, many did not harvest their crop until quite late in the hope that

the prices would rise again. However, this meant the risk that the harvest would be damaged if

there were early rains, and that was precisely what was happening during our final visit in

February 2009.

The risks intrinsic to smallholder agriculture are not confined to the unpredictable vagaries of

markets and weather. We were with Kim Nary when she went to her chamcar for the first time for

six weeks. Her daughter had been giving birth to Nary‟s second grandchild and Nary had been at

home looking after her. On the way to the chamcar Nary was telling us about the excellent

pumpkin crop she had that year, and how it would be ready for harvest: when we got there all of

the pumpkins had been stolen (Interview 27). In addition these uncertainties, which are more or

less inherent to smallholder farming, are the uncertainties related to the competition for land in a

situation where all farming activity is strictly speaking illegal. This will be discussed more in the

section on the “Competition for Land” which follows.

Overall, then, we found that while smallholder farming was not yet an important source of

income for many households, and was a difficult and risky endeavour, it was here that people saw

their futures. Deforestation and forest degradation had meant that there was little future in timber

related activities. Villagers hoped, therefore, that they might be able to establish themselves as

smallholder farmers producing cash crops in a transformed landscape. Our visit to one household,

which had arrived at the village from Kampong Cham in 2002, so three or four years earlier than

the other newcomers, showed that for a household with capital, and with agricultural experience,

and with land with a stream running through it, that this might be a viable option. Whether such a

prospect would have been realistic for households without farming experience, and whether it

would be realistic on land not endowed with a reliable water source is uncertain.

5.2.2.3.3 Hiring Out Agricultural Labour

While smallholder farming figured high in villagers‟ aspirations and expectations, but low in

terms of actual incomes for most households, the opposite was true of agricultural labouring.

Villagers did not consider themselves to be agricultural labourers, nor was it the future that they

envisaged for themselves. It was, however, an important source of income for many households.

This was demonstrated both in January 2008 when 72% of households reported income from

hiring out agricultural labour, and by the survey in November 2008 where 45 out of 120

respondents (38%) said that agricultural labour had been the most important livelihood activity

for their household during the previous six months.

As with other livelihood activities, there was considerable variation according to the background

of the household. New in-migrants to the village were more likely (59%) to report agricultural

labour as their main household income, than households that were already formed when the

research began in 2006 (22%).

The experiences of another case study household husband Panny and wife Panna illustrate some

of the changes in agricultural labour during the study period (Interviews 15-22). They moved to

Bey in July 2006, just two weeks before our first visit to the village. During their first six months

Page 148: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

130

in the village, they reported that their main source of income (62%) had been the money they had

got from selling assets when they moved. However, agricultural labouring (29%) was their only

reported earned income (with the remaining 9% of their reported income being money given to

them by friends when their children were sick)84

. During the first year or so in the village, they

mainly worked on land near the village that belonged to outsiders who were clearing forest and

planting there. In early 2008 wife Panna had begun to work for the head-teacher who had claimed

a large area between Bey and the neighbouring village and was working it, or so he claimed, on

behalf of one of the Prime Minister‟s daughters and two of her high-ranking friends. Panna said

that the head-teacher had threatened villagers, saying that only his land was legally owned, and

that if people tried to work on their own land that he would report them to the police and the

soldiers for working on State land, so they must only work on his land. At this time, Panna was

actually acting as an intermediary for the head-teacher, collecting wages from him and

distributing them to everyone who worked on his land. By the end of the year the head-teacher

was using external labour – young men trucked direct out to the plantation in the middle of the

night – and Panny and Panna had become less reliant on agricultural labour because husband

Panny had accepted an offer of work – returning to his former role as a policeman in Kampong

Cham province, which meant that he was away for about half of the time, but that he brought in

most of the household‟s income through earnings related to that job. While agricultural labouring

dominated their income at first, the family seemed to be succeeding in its ambition to establish a

smallholding. Initially growing soya beans on their house land, they also bought and planted an

area of chamcar opposite their house, growing soya beans on it in 2007 and then cassava in 2008.

They intended to interplant rubber with these crops and gradually become smallholder rubber

farmers. For this household, then, with the benefit of their farming experience, as well as a new,

non-local income stream, agricultural labour had indeed seemed to serve the temporary purpose

of enabling the household to cope until they could fully establish as smallholder farmers.

At the beginning of the research, agricultural labour was something that was carried out beyond

the immediate confines of the village. People (like Panny and Panna above) would work on land

that was being cleared mainly by Cham settlers who were converting forest nearby. Within the

village, most households who were embarking on chamcar farming did so using their own family

labour, and mutual assistance – i.e. a group of households pooled their labour and took it in turns

working on each other‟s land (e.g. Interviews 3, 16, 19).

As increasingly large areas were cleared during 2008 the price of agricultural labour rose quite

dramatically – doubling from about 7000 riels to 15000 riels per day. With labour being scarce,

the head-teacher introduced two other solutions which may give some clues as to the future in the

terms of households‟ engagement in agricultural labour as a livelihood activity: first the use of

threats of violence (under the cloak of a claim of legality) to force people to work on a certain

plantation; second the use of temporary imported labour at cheaper prices (Interview 17).

While no household saw its future as largely dependent on agricultural labouring during the

research period, this could change. Smallholder farming, wood trading and various other

livelihoods are all aspired to, whilst agricultural labouring was seen as a short-term fix, resorted

84

These figures do not include the husband‟s occasional income from working as a chainsaw assistant (fetching and

carrying for a chainsaw operator in a team in the forest). This happened very rarely, and at that time, new to the

village and uncertain about admitting to illegal activities he preferred not to tell us about it.

Page 149: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

131

to in order to solve food and cash-flow shortages while waiting for the harvest or other work.

However, many households gave agricultural labour as their primary source of income, and one

possibility is that this ends up having more long-term significance. However, during the study

period conditions have been favourable for agricultural labour: there has been quite a large

demand with new land being cleared, and the area is still considered somewhat wild and poor and

therefore has not attracted so many migrant labourers. These factors are likely to change.

5.2.2.3.4 Gathering and Trading Non-Timber Forest Products

Traditionally, non-timber forest products (NTFP) have been an important source of income for

villagers in Bey. While there had always been some logging, and also some agriculture in the

village, it was the gathering and trading of non-timber forest products that were reported as

traditionally comprising the main source of food and incomes for villagers.

First and foremost amongst these, as we have seen, were the harvesting of rattan and tapping of

resin from hard wood trees. Villagers used to be able to collect resin all year round and to sell it

either by taking it down to the Mekong, or by selling to traders who came to the village.

The assistant village chief and her husband were both born in the village. She told us that when

she was young there had been thirty or forty households in the village, and it had been a walk of

five or six kilometres to the resin trees. Today, however, she said it took about four hours to get

to an area where some resin trees could be found. In 2006 she collected some resin, and said it

was possible to collect between 5 and 10 kg per day, and to sell them for 700 riels per

kilogramme. However, she said that it was hard work to carry 10 kilogrammes of resin back and

that 7000 riels (less than 2 US dollars) was the rate for agricultural labour at the time, and that

was much easier, as well as less risky because sometimes when she went out to collect resin she

could only get 2-3 kilogrammes in the day.

She emphasised that this was different from the situation in the past. Then the trees had been

much nearer and some men could carry as much as 20 kilogrammes home every day. In this area

there had never been any defined ownership of trees or of tapping rights to specific trees, people

just used to go out and tap the resin (Interview 80).

Likewise, a 71 year old man, also born in the village recalling even longer back:

At that time there were strict laws which were enforced. People were not allowed to go into the

forest and cut the forest. The forestry officers did not allow that. But people were allowed to cut

from the forest within about three kilometres from the village to build houses, but not to trade

timber. Villagers were allowed to look for resin and could easily get this, and rattan and leaves to

make roof material. Not like today when everything is difficult to find. As a boy he would go with

his parents to collect resin. They might get 3-5 kg in a day, sometimes even as much as 10 kg. At

that time a kilogramme was worth 3-4 riels. (Interview 109, Author‘s field notes, not

transcription)

However, the cheu teal trees that could be tapped for resin were amongst the hardwood trees that

were so attractive to the various logging interests that have been active in and beyond the village

during the past twenty-five years. It is the transformations wrought by logging which have led to

the situation where a journey to collect resin is now much longer and yields much smaller

rewards. For villagers who have grown up in Bey, resin collection has changed from being their

Page 150: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

132

primary income source to becoming a secondary resort when there is no work available cutting or

transporting timber.

To the extent that gathering of NTFPs is still an activity in the village, it is one that is

predominantly carried out by villagers who were born or grew up in the area. The one case study

household that has reported a substantial income from gathering non-timber forest products was

HH56, where the wife was a native of the village and her husband had come back to the village

with her. They reported that 31% of their income in the twelve months to spring 2007 had come

from NTFPs, comprising 23% from resin and 8% from Treang85

.

In another case study household, where both adults were born and brought up in the village, the

husband explained that he used to collect resin, but that he did not do so any more because all of

the trees had gone (Interview 30).

Members of both the two case study households who had migrated from Kampong Cham

province, had attempted to go out and collect resin. Their comparative disadvantage in this

quickly came apparent as they went out on the long trips, collected almost no resin and came

back sick with malaria. Panna, in HH 28, explained that she went with „old‟ villagers, who were

each able to collect 8-10 kilogrammes on the trip, but that she was not even able to collect 2

kilogrammes and that she was sick for three days afterwards (Interview 15).

In the village census at the beginning of August 2006 only one of the 198 adults in the village

was reported to be collecting NTFPs on the day of the interview. As mentioned above, this result

is partly biased by the fact that rice transplanting was underway and a third of adults were busy

working in the fields, nevertheless with a further third of adults at home either doing domestic

work, resting or recovering from illness, it remained the case that there were over sixty adults

who were neither in the rice fields nor at home, but only one of them was engaged in NTFP

collection.

The „livelihood matrix‟ in the Land and Livelihood Survey (1) in January 2008 gave a more

comprehensive view of how many households engage in NTFP related activities. Of the 84

households who were interviewed, only nine reported having taken any part in NTFP collection

during the previous six months. It seemed, therefore, that it was both a small and dwindling

proportion of the village who participated in collecting resin and other NTFPs.

In the Land and Livelihood Survey (2), in late 2008, only 2 of the 120 responding households

reported resin collection or NTFPs as their main livelihood activity. It was striking that while so

many of the houses in the village had been improved during the course of the research, and

motorcycles, televisions and DVD players proliferated, these were two households which still

looked extremely impoverished (insert photo HH79). They were also households that were beset

by problems of alcoholism and domestic violence (Interview 123). In follow-up interviews in

early 2009 to discover the extent of their resin incomes they doubted whether resin was in fact

quite so important and thought that they probably earned more from agricultural labouring.

Overall, then, there was a clear trend. NTFPs in general, and specifically resin and rattan had

been an important part of villagers‟ livelihoods several decades earlier. At that time food had

85

Source: Income and Expenditure Survey of 8 Case Study Households, March 2007.

Page 151: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

133

been plentiful, and resin could be traded for rice for those who did not grow it, and for cash for

other requirements. In recent times deforestation, especially during the 1990s had ensured that

there were very few resin trees left, and that it was a longer journey to get to them. Only a small

proportion of villagers now collect resin, and the households that have this as a significant source

of income are amongst the very poorest in the village.

5.2.2.3.5 Trading land

Nobody at any stage reported to us that they personally traded land in the village. On the other

hand, many people were willing to testify that many or even most of their fellow villagers had

been engaged in land trading.

However, there is at least one household, whose members having settled in the village bought a

large tract of land (stretching from opposite the school all the way to the stream at the entrance of

the village – so a front of about 700 meters along the road) extremely cheaply and has since sold

it off at a significant profit (Interview 4). There were likewise oblique references to „people‟ who

had been marking off land and selling it to outsiders and earning very large amounts of money

by doing so86

.

In order to discover more we focused a little more attention on the economies of households that

had been able to build expensive houses (see Photograph at Figure 5-5). There were 7 households

with houses either complete or under construction that were worth upwards of 5,000 USD and in

some cases clearly well over 10,000 USD), there were again denials that they personally had had

any involvement in the purchasing and selling of land. Rather they suggested that “everyone” else

in the village had been doing that, and that the only reason that they did not all have fine new

houses was that some people knew how to save and invest money, while others just knew how to

spend it (Interview 51). One senior villager (who had not, as yet, invested his money from timber

and land trading in a large new house) was terse on this subject, saying simply that anyone who

had a large house had been trading land (Interview 108).

86

It was fairly clear in many cases who was being referred to, but given the extent to which villagers chose not to use

names, it would not seem appropriate to speculate in print.

Page 152: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

134

Figure 5-5: House worth 7000 USD in Bey Village, November 2008 (Photo: Robin Biddulph)

5.2.2.4 Livelihood Activities in a Deforestation Trajectory

We can conclude this detailed account of livelihoods in Bey by returning to the idea of livelihood

trajectories or pathways raised in the introduction to this section. The changes in livelihood

activity and the demographic changes in the village can be related to the process of deforestation

that has been in progress during the years leading up to and including research project. Table 5-8

below is an attempt to show how some of the specific issues in Bey might be abstracted to

provide a more generalised theoretical model of how deforestation87

affects livelihoods. It

captures the logic and dynamics of a process whereby a market for timber attracts new actors,

transforms the role of the State, and places the local economy in a much wider context. It is no

longer characterised by its remoteness but by its centrality to an extraction process.

87

This dissertation is not the place to develop this idea further, however, it can be noted that the framework applies

particularly to deforestation that is driven by economic incentives which attract actors from beyond the local area

(i.e. the profits that can accrue from the sale of timber, or from the post-forest exploitation of land, or most likely

both). The Deforestation Trajectory that I suggest here would not have the same explanatory power in cases where a

low value, marginal forest is being consumed by local people without being directly driven by non-local market

forces and the arrival of non-local actors.

Page 153: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

135

Table 5-8: Deforestation Livelihood Trajectory suggested by experience in Bey 1960s – 2000s

Phase Structural Process Local Livelihood implications

1.Pre-

deforestation

Pre-existing dynamic

relationship between the

community and the forest

resources.

A range of possibilities, but naive

assumptions that „forest-dependent‟

communities are non-monetised and

subsistence oriented should be

avoided

2.Timber

boom/NTFP

decline

External actors begin cutting

on a larger scale. The implied

threat to the forest resource

creates a strong incentive for

villagers to deforest.

Opportunities in timber trade depend

on relations with external actors. May

be greater of less than pre-

deforestation.

NTFP decline, quite possibly to a

point where NTFPs cannot sustain a

livelihood.

3.Turn to

agriculture

As forest is degraded, first-

movers identify agricultural

possibilities and make initial

claims for land.

Locals may not have a background in

farming and may not be able to take

advantage. In-migration by

agriculturalists may shape

opportunity through both

demonstration and competition.

4. Land boom/

Competition for

Land

As agricultural potential is

proven, land prices rise

rapidly. Land speculation

accompanies the transition to

agriculture.

Outsiders with capital and a business

mindset may benefit more than locals

from land trading. Locals may

unwittingly sell cheaply.

5. Shakedown

(reterritorial-

isation)

Competition for land,

including between plantation

and smallholder interests,

works out, alongside the

process of establishing

whether farming is sustainable.

Secure livelihoods within agriculture

(as labourers or smallholders) may be

possible, but may also be threatened

by dispossession in the competition

for land or by rapid deterioration of

virgin soils.

Source: Author

The terms of incorporation might vary dramatically. We have witnessed in Bey how poor

villagers were able to participate in and (at least in the short term) profit from the timber boom.

Le Billon (2002) has suggested that the opposite happened, and I myself did field work in a

village on the opposite side of the Mekong to Chhlong district town in 1997 where rather than

being co-opted into the timber harvesting, villagers were shut out by armed security guards and

lost access not only to timber but to the NTFPs. What the trajectory suggests, though, is that the

Page 154: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

136

defining feature for local livelihoods is less the timber boom than the competition for land that

follows88

. We complete the discussion of the immanent development context of Bey village by

looking in more detail at the competition for land in and around Bey, and how that affects the

future prospects of the villagers who live there.

5.2.3 Prospects Explained: The Competition for Land

5.2.3.1 Introduction

The competition for land in Bey began long before the research for this project started, and was

far from complete by the time it finished. However, notwithstanding the element of smoke and

mirrors that inevitably attends such „shadow‟ market activity, we did manage to gain some

insights into the ways that some of the actors operate, and how tenure insecurity was created and

experienced. I (eventually) was able to interview members of the provincial authorities, district

forest administration and the local concession company representative which gave me access to

information that would have been far beyond the reach of most villagers. On the other hand, I

assume that this understanding only scrapes at the surface of this competition, and that –

especially amongst the more entrepreneurial and well-connected villagers – there will have been

issues that were common knowledge which nevertheless eluded us.

For local people, the competition for land was one that they participated in, but with a strong

sense that other actors or forces could quickly come into play and crush any gains that they had

made. Emblematic of this were the signs that people had put up on the road to the east of the

village to claim land. What all of these had in common was that the name of the claimant was

never legible. Villagers had to walk a narrow line. On the one hand they wanted to assert a claim,

but on the other hand there was the constant threat that a „rule of law‟ or „public good‟ argument

could be mobilised to define their particular claim as illegal leaving them open to retribution.

Such is the balancing act, for villagers, of dealing with the shadow/developmental state.

The remainder of this section first discusses some of the main actors in the competition for land,

and how they appeared (or didn‟t) on the village scene, there is then a brief discussion of an

illuminating case that we heard about just a few kilometres north of the village, before a

concluding discussion draws together some of the themes in the immanent development of Bey.

5.2.3.2 The Vietnamese Company

Following initial familiarisation visits we arrived in Bey to begin research in earnest on the 26th

July 2006. In a coincidence that would shape the whole project, and which particularly

overshadowed the first half of the project, forestry officials held a meeting in the village on our

first morning at work in the village, 27th July 2006. Having obtained permission from the village

chief to attend, I sat amongst the villagers as a Forestry Administration official presented a map

of the village. On this map all land within five hundred meters of the access roads west and south

88

It has become commonplace to argue that deforestation is not driven by demand for timber, but by demand for the

post-forest land-use (e.g. Grainger, 2008). This may be true where there is a particularly lucrative post-forest land use

and/or the prospect of good governance of the forest resource. However, as McKenney et al. (2004) have

convincingly argued, in conditions of poor governance, the timber resource itself is more than sufficient to explain

the incentives to „cut and run‟.

Page 155: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

137

of the village had been shaded. The official explained that this was forestry land and that all

families resident on this land (about thirty of the village‟s 82 households at the time) were illegal

occupiers. They would be required to leave it in order that the forest could grow back. This, they

explained, was simply them implementing the Forestry Law on behalf of the nation and its

people.

Chan, the former Khmer Rouge commander who is the head of the village‟s community forestry

group asked questions during the meeting. The forestry official, Mr Muntrei Cheu tried to object

to one person asking all of the questions. However, the other villagers, previously silent,

responded firmly that they liked Chan‟s questions and wanted him to continue with them. Chan

asked why the Forestry Administration was just concentrating its efforts on the poor people who

live along the road, but was not doing anything about the big people in the forests who had

sawmills and who destroyed a lot of trees. Mr Muntrei Cheu promised that he would be

systematic and that in time he would also go after people further from the road. Chan asked what

rights the Casotim company had in the area. Cheu responded that he had only been in his job for

two months so was unable to answer the question.

Meanwhile, even while informing the villagers that they were to be evicted from their land, Mr

Muntrei Cheu repeatedly maintained that „the State‟ cared for them and wanted to look after

them. He held up a government document on land redistribution as evidence that the State cared

for them (see Photography at Figure 5-6). The Sub-Decree on Social Land Concessions is a legal

document subsidiary to the 2001 land law which enables the state to divest itself of certain

categories of land and redistribute them to poor people. The villagers‟ inevitably asked if there

was land available for them to move to, and his answer, (equally inevitably) was no. But he

argued that they should not be without hope, because the sub-decree should give them hope as it

showed that the State cared89

.

This eviction threat can be interpreted as being the local manifestation of an initiative from the

Prime Minister in May 2006. In May 2006 the Prime Minister had issued an edict and made

speeches (Sen, 2006, p. e.g.) to the effect that he wanted to make sure that powerful people would

not be able to exploit the nation‟s forests. He was fed up of hearing that his officials had been

targeting poor people and he now wanted them to go after the big people involved in encroaching

on State forests. The forestry official cited and distributed the Prime Minister‟s edict, but, as

Chan pointed out in the meeting, its logic had been reversed. The action being taken was one that

targeted the poor (villagers living along the road) and ignored the wealthy (business men running

sawmills in the forests).

One could read this sympathetically as the Prime Minister being frustrated in attempts to lead a

fight against corruption in the state apparatus. Or one could read it more cynically as the Prime

Minister making political capital of appearing to defend the poor, while in fact maintaining his

89

The irony of this situation was not lost on me. Working both through Oxfam GB and through the German advisory

team at the Ministry of Land Management Urban Planning and Construction I had been involved in the preparation

of the Social Land Concessions Sub-Decree. Social Land Concessions had been envisaged as a means by which poor

people, who had missed out during the grabbing of former state land both by government officials following the

transition from communism and by military following the arrival of peace, might yet be able to claim back some

small part of this land. It had certainly not been intended by any of its international supporters that it should be used

to placate people who were being dispossessed by the State as it sought to reassert its claims.

Page 156: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

138

own position through the very practices of enabling the rich to dispossess the poor. What was

indisputable, however, was that the formal intentions outlined at national level became

transformed in the course of their journey to the village. So Social Land Concessions, being

officially an instrument by which to distribute land to poor people, became an instrument to

placate them when they were to be made landless. Meanwhile, the Prime Minister‟s edict to target

wealthy encroachers became an instrument to target the poor.

Figure 5-6: Forestry Official holds up the Social Land Concession Sub-decree at the 27th

July 2006 meeting in

Bey village. (Photopgraph: Robin Biddulph)

In early 2007 villagers reported that a Vietnamese company was seeking to obtain an economic

concession to establish a plantation in the area. Company staff were reported to have been in the

village for the first time on 22 January 2007, and to have made several subsequent visits in order

to conduct soil testing (Interview 57). This gave rise to much anxious speculation in the village.

Community Forestry activist Long Chan reported that they had promised that only land six

kilometers from the village would be taken by the company, (though he saw them carrying out

tests within 200 meters of the village). Rumours began to swirl. Another villager had heard that

they would be granted an initial 1000 hectares which would potentially be expanded to 40 000

hectares, and furthermore that the plan had been that they would pay a rent to the government of

1000 USD per hectare per year. However, he also reported that their soil tests had only identified

300 of the 1000 hectares as suitable for rubber (Interview 8).

In time it became apparent that the two stories – the one of the Forest Administration seeking to

allow the forest to grow back for the good of the nation, and the other of the Vietnamese

Page 157: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

139

company looking for a site to establish a plantation – were in fact one story. During interviews at

the Forestry Administration office in the provincial town, I sought to find out about progress in

relation to the proposed evictions. Villagers had protested and these protests were to be

investigated. In February 2007 I was told that similar processes had occurred in over 100 villages

in 21 communes in the province, but that no investigations had yet been completed (Interview

208). By September 2007 it was explained the investigations had now been abandoned because

the Vietnamese company was no longer coming. In other words, far from reclaiming the forest for

the nation and enabling it to grow back, as Mr Muntrei Cheu had claimed, the intention had been

to negotiate a concession with the Vietnamese company (Interview 210). The prospect that the

Vietnamese company might move in had in the meantime created a general sense of insecurity

about land holdings (e.g. Interview 1), and also in some cases caused people to not clear and plant

their land for fear they would soon lose it (e.g. Interview 30).

In summary, what this case started to show was the way in which the apparent good intentions of

national policies and legislation could easily be transformed into instruments by which the path

could be smoothed for non-local actors hoping to win control over the land upon which villagers‟

hopes were pinned.

5.2.3.3 The Casotim Company and the Okhnyaa

‖They say it is Casotim, Casotim land, but then we see big people coming in and farming that

land‖ (Interview 149)

During the years of intensive logging villagers occasionally used to see Russians in the village,

but this never happened in the course of the study. It was only the presence of Russian

representatives at occasional meetings about community forestry, and in company documents that

I saw at the Forestry Administration offices that gave evidence that there was still an international

involvement and that Casotim was not simply a front for local business interests90

.

For villagers the identity of Casotim was closely related to the identity of the man who was the

company representative in the district. He was a local man who many villagers knew: some in-

migrants from the Mekong had been to school with him before the Pol Pot times (Interviews 103,

107); others knew him from when he drove a truck through the village in the 1990s (Interview

71). Since then he had become what they referred to as a „big person‟ (neak thom) with the rank

of Okhnyaa. Okhnyaa is an honorary position bestowed by the Cambodian state to wealthy

benefactors who have contributed to national development. The contribution should be at least

100 000 USD and normally be in the form of infrastructure. Implicit in becoming an Okhnyaa is

the informal understanding that one‟s business interests will be protected. According to the Bey

village head-teacher, the Casotim district representative had paid 200 000 USD in order to obtain

his rank (Interview 158).

90

This was a possibility that had occurred to me, and was also suggested by a villager (Interview 13). The Active

Communities director, commenting on this text, recalled a TV broadcast in 2003 showing a Russian businessman

meeting with Cambodian officials. He said that even at that time, when other logging concessions were in the process

of producing forest management plans, there was speculation that Casotim‟s intention was to convert its logging

concession into a land concession.

Page 158: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

140

When I interviewed him in 2008, the Okhnyaa shared the company‟s plans for developing the

land within the concession area (Interview 218). CASOTIM had applied to the government in

2007, and received approval in 2008, to convert 15,000 hectares of forest to plantation over a ten

year period. The official correspondence and the attached maps and plans showed a series of ten

1,500 hectare plots, which would be developed one per year. The seventh of these was within two

kilometres of the eastern boundary of Bey village, and would effectively dispossess most of the

villagers of most of their agricultural land.

During the course of 2007-8 a number of villagers had already been driven off land that they had

claimed to the east of Bey by „Casotim soldiers‟. These soldiers had threatened villagers with

rifles and had taken their motorcycles, water containers, knives and machetes. Villagers had to

pay the soldiers in order to recover this equipment the following day (Interviews 4, 25, 26, 37,

81). One of our case study families was such a household: they had bought three hectares of land

about six kilometres east of the village, but having been driven off the land once they did not dare

to reoccupy and farm it again. Here were cases, then, which perfectly matched the narratives used

to justify programmes of systematic land titling in chapter 2: insecurity of tenure was restricting

agricultural investment and productivity. With secure tenure these households would have

invested more, produced more and been better off.

In response to questions about villagers‟ occupation of land for farming, the Okhnyaa replied that

the company was prepared for villagers to claim up to five hectares per household. Although he

was sceptical as to whether most households would be capable of farming as many as five

hectares. On the other hand, he expressed extreme disapproval of land speculation. He confirmed

a story that we had heard of the newly-elected commune chief claiming and selling off plots of

land for about 500 USD each in the area of the hamlet of Pram Toch. He declared his intention to

take the commune chief to court over this and to ensure he got sacked as a result91

.

This would seem to suggest that villagers might have some chance to acquire the smallholder

plots which they hope for. However, it is important to note that the only formal communication

with the concession company tends to go through the Forestry Administration, who are much

more hostile to the idea of forest lands being converted to smallholder agriculture. Likewise, that

(as the case of Kang Cheung below demonstrates), if the plantation development does proceed

according to plan there is likely to be a variety of actors converging on Bey in order to both claim

land and to judge the claims. The outcomes of such a process would be difficult to predict and

would not necessarily support the interests of the current villagers.

5.2.3.4 The Head-Teacher ... and The South Korean Company?

Young, educated, enthusiastic and charming, as well as being large and powerful by Cambodian

standards, the head-teacher of the 3-room village school became a controversial figure in the

competition for land. Reasonably popular when we arrived, particularly amongst the younger

men in the village with whom he used to drink and go on motorcycle trips, he gradually became

extremely unpopular, both for the way that he neglected his teaching duties (e.g. Interview 49)

and for his business dealing.

91

The court case took place during the following month but no judgement had been issued when our research

concluded in March 2009.

Page 159: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

141

He also had some experience with foreigners. He claimed to have been close friends with his

English teacher, an international volunteer called Ursula, in the provincial town, and he had also

received support from an Italian NGO to set up a handicrafts workshop in his home village on the

Mekong. He was solicitous of me and keen not only to establish a relationship, but also for the

rest of the village to see that he had established a relationship with me. Amongst his strategies to

woo me were to present me with the telephone numbers of the Casotim representative, and also of

the older brother of the Prime Minister (but on the strict instruction that I was not to use the

latter!). He had believed that he had been on his way to becoming a rich man through a logging

deal with the Prime Minister‟s brother, but that went bad and now he was restless and ambitious

for another opportunity.

In mid-2007 the head-teacher had been rumoured to have been arranging to sell land in the

village area to a high ranking woman (with the title „Excellency‟), and had spent 11-15 August

2007 surveying land with a GPS and marking it (Interview 67). By January 2008 an area

rumoured to be 2000 hectares had been marked and was being cleared. Some wealthy looking

ladies had been to visit in two expensive four wheel drive vehicles, accompanied by military

bodyguards on motorcycles. During our fourth visit, a group of angry villagers from the next

village arrived at the house of the head of the community forestry committee while one of us was

interviewing him. They represented 40 households who had been dispossessed by the head-

teacher‟s plantation, and were seeking his help to present a letter of complaint and a petition

saying that they had acquired this land three or four years before the head-teacher, and that he had

no right to steal it from them (Interviews 14, 69).

When I interviewed the head-teacher later during that visit, he claimed that the „excellencies‟

were a daughter to the Prime Minister Hun Sen called “Srey Neang”92

, a first cousin to the Prime

Minister‟s wife Bun Rany called „Nai‟ and another high ranking lady called „Toch‟. He said that

they were in the process of making an agreement with the Casotim company. Regarding

villagers‟ complaints, he argued that villagers in the area were ignorant and did not understand

that all of the land belonged to Casotim, and that anyone who cleared or traded that land was

violating the rights of the company. Furthermore, that if the „excellencies‟ came and carried out

plantation farming that this would be good for the villagers because they would build roads and

factories and therefore all of the inhabitants would benefit from development (Interview 158).

During the last days of our final field visit we heard that in the end the „Excellencies‟ had chosen

another area of land to do their plantation, and that the one that had been cleared was owned by

the head-teacher. We had no way of knowing what the truth was at this stage in a prolonged game

of smoke and mirrors. Our information was no better than that of the villagers themselves. What

was clear, though, was that the teacher, whether acting in his own interests or in the interests of

wealthy outsiders (who may or may not have been who they claimed they were), had succeeded

in occupying and farming that 2000 hectare plot, and in the process had deprived the forty

complainants from the neighbouring village of their claims to smallholder plots.

92

The Prime Minister does not have a daughter named Srey Neang, although I do not know if one of his daughters

has this as a nickname.

Page 160: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

142

5.2.3.5 Cham Settlers

Settlement of former forest by communities of Cham people is a feature of the landscape in

Chhlong district. The national road from Kampong Cham province to Chhlong is lined with

houses that have been built on land which was forested a decade ago. The tracks from the

national road out to Bey are likewise dotted with new Cham villages. At the time of the research

no Cham households had settled in the village (although one Cham woman had married a Khmer

man there), but one plot had been purchased and cleared prior to occupation in the centre of the

village (Interview 61), and nearby Pram village was said to have a large Cham population

(Interview 157).

During the research period Cham people had already established claims to large tracts of land to

the north of the village. Villagers noted that Cham people did not get driven off their land by

Casotim soldiers in the way that they did and suspected that Cham organisations had done deals

in order to secure their tenure (Interview 25). On the other hand, there were also rumours that

Casotim was going to reassert its own claim and that the Cham settlers would be forced off the

land (Interview 140). There was some conflict between Cham settlers and the villagers of Bey.

On one occasion the deputy village chief recruited the assistance of local military units to try and

address land conflicts at the northern border of the village (Interview 101), while villagers

complained that any time that their cattle – which traditionally are allowed to roam free during

the rainy season – strayed into newly-occupied Cham areas that they would be cut with knives

and sent back (Interviews 43, 51)93

. Having said that, there did not appear to be any generalised

ill will between Bey villagers and Cham people. On one occasion there had been fighting at a

festival at the pagoda and one of the village youths was injured by a young Cham. The next day

the Cham youngster turned up in the village in order to pay compensation, which everyone

seemed to think was correct and attracted no negative comments or remarks.

In addition to the already established Cham settlement, there was also a rumour circulating that a

new Cham village for about 900 households would be established about 10 kilometers east of

Bey (Interview 103, 157). In one case a household from Bey who had claimed land near there had

it taken from them on the grounds that it was for the new village (Interview 143).

As far as we could discover, the Cham who had acquired land near Bey had not settled in the area

but were still based in their home villages, mainly along the Mekong. It was unclear how they had

managed to negotiate their presence in these places, but it did seem that they often fared well both

in individual conflicts and in terms of their ability to remain on the land which they settled. The

Casotim representative was evasive regarding the Cham, not being able to give any explanation

as to why the company permitted them to settle (Interview 218). However, to have settled as

extensively as they had seemed to imply a degree of either political connectedness or economic

reach or social cohesion that would make them imposing rivals in the competition for land in the

area of Bey. Their presence was yet further evidence that the green forest on official maps should

not be seen as spaces of nature, but that they might often be staked out in privatised plots by

private agents exploiting informal links to the authorities.

93

The Active Communities director pointed out that grazing of cattle on forest land is an important element of

livelihoods in many parts of the country: while in Bey cattle‟s importance mainly related to transport of timber and

some agricultural work, in other parts of the country trading of cattle was a key income source.

Page 161: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

143

5.2.3.6 The Case of Khang Cheung

We learned of a case just a few kilometres north of Bey which reinforced our understanding of

just how difficult it would be, even with the appropriate political will, to take meaningful action

on behalf of the local poor. This concerned local people‟s attempts to resist a plantation

development by Casotim, and the way that a national intervention was undertaken94

.

When we heard about it, the case had been the subject of a preliminary investigation, but was far

from closed. It began in mid-2007 when four villagers, who were part of a small settlement that

would fall within a plantation planned by the Casotim company, succeeded in forwarding a

petition to the Prime Minister. Our informant was a former government official who had been

directly involved in the affair. He explained that the Prime Minister had responded by ordering

that villagers who had agricultural land in the area should be allowed to keep it. An

interdepartmental provincial working group under the provincial governor was then despatched to

the site in order to identify all households who had land there. At first, local people refused to

cooperate. This reluctance was unsurprising given that the Forestry Administration officials who

had drawn up the forms had headed them “Names of the people who have illegally stolen the land

of the State”. After some heated discussions within the provincial team the process was made

more settler-friendly and, using Geographic Information System and survey equipment from the

provincial land department, they proceeded to register 438 households to 281 plots (some plots

were multi-household as the provincial team did not have time to do a detailed survey).

This result, however, became a source of some controversy. When officials later examined the

438 household names they discovered that only 15 of them were on the original protest letter

submitted by the four leaders. It was argued that somebody must have been selling land illegally

on a large scale. A follow-up investigation was therefore due to investigate who had been buying

and selling the land, with a view to punishing any speculators. Our informant, meanwhile, was

sceptical about the rights of the settlers as a whole, saying that when he had driven past this site

just four years previously, there had only been two or three houses there. Clearly, then, it

remained possible that the legitimacy of any of the claims could be challenged, and that a witch-

hunt for land speculators could become the means by which other actors could overturn the

results of the provincial work-team‟s survey and ultimately dispossess the current settlers once

the Prime Minister‟s attention had moved on to other matters.

This ongoing, inconclusive case provided indications of what might be expected if villagers‟

rights to land they occupied in Bey were ever to be investigated. Firstly, of course, the hostility of

forestry officials to any activity that implied that the forest would be transformed to another use

meant that villagers were unlikely to receive support from that quarter. Secondly, the uncertainty

caused by an absence of any trustworthy, respected source of information. In such a case, it

would inevitably be the existing networks and relationships between village authorities and

higher authorities that would determine outcomes. If such a circumstance arose in Bey, it would

undoubtedly be the deputy village chief whose interpretation of history would be definitive. His

long-term allies, and those who had successfully ingratiated themselves with him through

business dealings, would have a better chance of having their possession recognised; those who

had alienated him would have little chance. Thirdly, whatever immediate effect high level

94

This section is based on material from Interview 193 with a Kracheh provincial official 29th

October 2008.

Page 162: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

144

interventions had, there was a strong likelihood that the prevailing business and political relations

would be able to reassert themselves with time. Decisions can always be modified and

renegotiated once „higher levels‟ are paying less attention. Arguably this is integral to the sort of

neo-patrimonial governance that obtains in Cambodia. Clients deliver on the major priorities of

their patrons (elections, security etc) and in return are allowed a reasonably free hand to manage

economic opportunities in the territories allocated to them.

5.2.4 Reflections: Mediating Actors and Factors in the Competition for Land and

Livelihoods

5.2.4.1 The Role of the Forest Administration

The Forestry Administration did not evict the villagers of Bey, despite the threat at the meeting

on 27th

July 2006. However, by holding that meeting they did contribute to a sense of insecurity

amongst the villagers. If nothing else was achieved, the villagers were at least reminded that

„their‟ land did not belong to them, and that they did not have the right to live in the forest.

At the same time as keeping people‟s tenure weak, the Forestry Administration also served as a

buffer between the companies who were operating (or potentially operating) concessions in the

area, and others who might criticize or resist them. Hence that first meeting was not in fact to

protect the forest, but to enable a smoother path for the Vietnamese company which was

preparing plans for a plantation. Regarding Casotim, Forestry Administration officials claimed

complete ignorance – as when Chan questioned Mr Muntrei Cheu about Casotim‟s rights in the

area, and Cheu replied that he had only been in his role for two months so could not answer the

question. Likewise, when I was at the Forestry Administration office in the provincial town I was

told that Casotim‟s operations were suspended and, at the Forestry Administration office at the

district town I was always told that the Casotim district representative was away in Phnom Penh,

or that they did know where he was.

To the extent that I did wish to build relationships with the Forestry Administration officials, my

efforts were undermined as they were rotated every two or three years. So just as I was unable to

develop the personal relationships that I would have needed to achieve my aims, villagers would

also have been frustrated if they had been similarly strategically oriented and wished to win over

the officials or in some way hold them to account.

The Forestry Administration had not been a major driver of the changes that had occurred in Bey,

but the stories of chainsaws being taken from villagers and then returned to them again for cash

the next morning were perhaps illustrative of the sort of role that institution has been able to play.

5.2.4.2 Indigenous and Forest-dependent, but not Ethnically Different

Political ecology and social movement literature is replete with examples of attempts to support

indigenous people to resist the loss of their livelihoods and ways of life (e.g. Brysk, 1996;

Colchester, 1993; du Monceau de Bergendal Labarca, 2008). The destructive effects of the

exposure to market forces are commonplace, as are the difficulties faced by indigenous people

who are not experienced in the ways of thinking associated with entrepreneurship and investment

and competition when they are suddenly exposed to competition with outsiders well-versed in the

ways of capital and markets.

Page 163: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

145

Just such differences are apparent in Bey. A way of life has already been utterly transformed, and

remains in rapid and uncertain transformation. The people least able to cope are the people who

have lived in the village since their parents‟ and grandparents‟ times. Their comparative

advantages are in finding trails in the forest, in identifying resin trees and tapping them, in killing

and capturing forest animals. These become less and less useful „advantages‟ when the hardwood

trees have been cut down, the rattan harvested and most of the animals long-since vanished.

However, there is no linguistic or ethnic marker to distinguish the people who are indigenous to

Bey from the outsiders who have come in and commoditized and traded the environment and the

social relations, so the transition/loss is less visible. Unlike the native ethnic minority areas

further north-east in Cambodia, nobody comes to Bey in order to catalyse or support a movement

to preserve the indigenous culture or relations with nature. We did not collect systematic

information on this, but certainly the three households where we chanced upon severe problems

with alcohol and domestic violence were all households containing adults who had grown up in

the village.

In Bey‟s modern history, and particularly in the experiences of the people who were born and

have lived all of their lives in the village, one can certainly recognise a transition from Rigg‟s

(2006, p. 190) „old‟ poverty (marked by isolation from the world and therefore missing many of

its benefits) to „new‟ poverty (marked by engagement with the broader world which includes a

new dependence on non-local factors and the loss of local resources and the self-reliance and

safety net that they could provide).

5.2.4.3 ‘Community’ and how it mediates change

At village level, some of the most influential villagers are in quite bitter conflict with each other.

In particular, the head teacher, the Hun-Bun household (deputy village chief and wife), and the

community forest activist Long Chan, all have considerable animosity towards each other95

.

These are the locally powerful actors whose immediate interests are relatively visible.

Each of these figures is more or less popular, but one does not get a strong sense that the

divisions between them are more widely reflected in the village population. One could quite

easily envisage a situation where blood could be spilt as a result of the conflicts between these

men/couples. On the other hand it was not the personal element of these conflicts that would

make them significant for the political economy of change in the village.

In addition to being in conflict with each other, these men/couples are also aligned with

competing outside interests. The head-teacher is looking to attach himself to large scale

plantation interests – international companies and (not unrelated) senior national politicians, and

to be part of the sort of development that would transform the local people into primarily

agricultural labourers. Because he has no family in the village and the option of returning to his

home village or to the provincial town where he was trained, he can afford high-risk liaisons with

powerful outsiders that might be locally unpopular. The deputy village chief and his wife each

have children who live in the village and it is their home. Their interests li.e. in profiting from

95

The other notably influential household, Sitha-Navy, who led the influx from Tbong Kmum district of Kampong

Cham, profited hugely from land deals and have been involved in land conflicts with other villagers, appear to have

finessed other actors such that they do not become embroiled in open conflict in the same way.

Page 164: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

146

gradual change – they broker logging deals, and now they are the first point of contact for

newcomers seeking to purchase land and move into the village. And as the trusted representative

of State and party in the village they are well-positioned to safeguard their interests and

opportunities in this respect. Proud and outspoken, the former Khmer Rouge commander Chan is

prepared to openly criticise and challenge anything which appears to destroy the forest, and

anything which he regards as corruption. He objects strongly to the business dealings of the other

men/couples. In interviews he reserves the right to keep his political views confidential, though

others associate him with opposition party activism. He has likewise been the contact point for a

series of non-governmental interventions in the area involved in malaria prevention, credit and

savings activities and (as we shall learn in Part 2) community forestry. He is unlikely ever to have

influence with the authorities but could well become a focus for, and indeed a generator of,

resistance to initiatives that dispossess villagers, as was seen in the villagers‟ enthusiastic support

of his questioning of the Forestry Administration officials during our first morning in the village.

Given that these men/couples are likely to mediate any major initiatives from outside, the shifting

politics of their relationships and the way in which they mobilise alliances in the village will be a

feature of any future change. If nothing else, it is important to understand that any initiative

supported by one of these men/couples is likely to be bitterly opposed by the other two, using

whatever resources they can muster.

5.2.5 Immanent Development and Livelihoods in Bey in Summary

Bey is a village that for most of its history would have been experienced and understood as a

village in forest. In recent decades, and especially since 1994 when peace came to the village,

external actors have initiated a process of deforestation in the village. That process of externally-

driven deforestation has been the structural factor that has shaped the livelihood trajectories of the

villagers living in Bey. It has facilitated a decade and a half of economic boom for the villagers.

This has particularly benefited newcomers to the village who are more business-oriented and

better able to reinvest profits, but even original villagers celebrate the larger population and

increased wealth saying that the village is happier than before and that they would not wish to

return it to its former state even if they do miss the large trees and the abundance of wild food.

The price to be paid for the increase in wealth has been an increase in insecurity. As the forest

landscape becomes transformed into an agricultural landscape villagers in Bey have long since

stopped having the possibility of a NTFP-based livelihood, and with logging opportunities now

also dwindling they are pinning their hopes for the future on being able to become smallholder

farmers. At the same time various companies and rent-seeking officials are jostling for position

and making claims to land, so that no villager in Bey can be sure that their current claims to

agricultural land will be respected. It was into this context that a community forestry project in

the village was first initiated in 2003.

Page 165: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

147

5.3 Intentional Development: Community Forestry in Bey

5.3.1 Introduction

As we have seen, processes of deforestation and competition for land have dominated livelihood

trajectories during the recent economic boom in the village of Bey. We began our research in the

village in July 2006. Three and a half years before that, a community forestry project was

established in the village. The remainder of this chapter is devoted to that project. We begin by

re-tracing the story of the community forestry intervention as it was experienced in the village

from early 2003 to the completion of our field research in March 2009. We then turn to the non-

local actors who have been involved in supporting or facilitating the project in various ways,

including the small Cambodian NGO which we shall call the Better Lives Organisation (BLO),

the small international NGO that we shall call Active Communities (AC), as well as the

international NGO Oxfam GB and the main donor during the research period the European

Union. Finally the implications of the case will be reviewed in relation to both community

forestry in Cambodia, and to the broader arguments about development geography in this thesis.

5.3.2 View from the Village: The Story of Community Forestry as Experienced in Bey

Community forestry was introduced to the village of Bey by two members of staff of the

Cambodian NGO BLO , an older man and a younger woman. The older man was a former

teacher, as Chan, who later became the head of the village‟s community forestry committee

recounted:

Teacher Rien came and told us about the benefits of forest products and about the disadvantages

of damaging natural resources. He came often. He came every month or once every two months

depending on the situation. Sometimes he stayed for a night, and sometimes he was busy with

other work and just came during the day96

. (Interview 71, Author‘s translation).

The BLO staff organised a group to “cultivate ideas” (pchour kumnet) and generate interest in

community forestry in early 2003. This informal group was led by the village authorities. Later in

2003 a community forestry committee was elected comprising three men and two women. Long

Chan was the head of that committee.

From the time of this NGO-facilitated election the community forestry project was somewhat

controversial and divisive. The tensions were not so much created by the community forestry but

rather represented a re-working of existing conflicts. The influential Deputy Village chief was not

present for the election and later claimed that it was not a proper election but just an appointment

by BLO (Interview 101). He asserted, furthermore, that the project could not happen because it

allowed the community forestry committee to arrest people, whereas he believed that the only

villagers entitled to arrest people were village authorities such as himself (Interview 97).

Meanwhile, Chan was resentful when the BLO staff presented the deputy village chief with a

camera to assist with project implementation.

They gave it to (deputy village chief) Hun because he was a local authority and had the role of

advisor to the community. So they gave it to him. But actually we wanted it to take pictures of

96

But compare Interview 54 in 2007 when Chan said that BLO staff never stayed in the village.

Page 166: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

148

violations, but he did not give it. To tell the truth, we never got to touch it at all (Interview 71,

Author‘s translation).

During the following two years, there was relatively little project activity in the village. In early

2006, however, funding was obtained from the international NGO Community Forestry

International for the marking and mapping of the boundaries of the community forest. On 17th

April 2006 Chan mapped the boundary using a handheld Global Positioning System device, but

was not accompanied by either BLO staff or by officials from the Forestry Administration

(Interview 71). The readings that Chan took were submitted to Community Forestry International

in Phnom Penh who in turn produced computerised maps and sent them back to BLO and the

village. These maps provided the inputs to subsequent discussions about the community forestry

project in Bey.

The community forestry project site marked by Chan was to be a shared responsibility of Bey and

Pram villages. The site was six kilometres to the southeast of the village. It was 1145 hectares,

and the boundary over 12 kilometres long. In the wet season it took over an hour to get to the

community forestry site by motorcycle. In the dry season, just to walk to and from the site took

two to three hours, and to patrol the boundary was a full day‟s walk. Villagers‟ own agricultural

fields and logging activities were mainly to the east of the village, whilst their work as

agricultural labourers took them mainly to the north and to the west of the village. In other words,

the community forest was not on any of their regular routes and was not, therefore, an area with

which villagers were familiar or which they could easily monitor. Asked about this location over

two years later in 2008, Chan, the head of the Community Forestry committee in the village

explained:

About this, I am not disappointed with myself because at the beginning I never had any training in

this question. What I did was according to the ideas that came from the local authorities. They

said it should be a good distance from the village so that it didn't overlap with villagers' land. We

didn't want people's rice and chamcar to be in the forest. We wanted them separate. And I went

along with that. And it is a good idea, but I did not think about the fact that an area a long way

from the village would be difficult to defend, which means that we can lose that area now

(Interview 71. Author‘s translation)97

.

Our research in the village began in mid-July 2006. At that point, shortly after the mapping of the

site, there was a sense of expectation around the project in the village. In August, Chan reported

expecting a meeting on 2nd

November to give official approval to the project (Interview 64).

When we returned for a brief visit on 5th November 2006 it had not occurred, but villagers were

then expecting a meeting the following day to approve the project (Interview 21), and were

already talking about the details of patrolling routines that this would involve, with themselves

and the neighbouring village sharing the duties, and everyone being required to carry out one

patrol per week.

97

The Active Communities director provided the following written comment on this quote: “This gets at a contentious issue. FA wants to say communities shouldn’t get large areas because they can’t manage them. Nowadays, since anything outside a CF is fair game for concessions, people try to get as large an area as possible. Not that the CF area in Bey was well selected, just that it would be unfortunate to conclude that the FA is right and CFs should be small and near the village”.

Page 167: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

149

In practice, these expectations were not to be realised. The November meetings never happened,

and on 9th

January 2007 there was a meeting attended by members of the Forestry

Administration, representatives of Oxfam and of BLO. Chan was present. He reported that the

Forestry Administration officials had recommended that only proposals for community forests

not located within commercial concessions be submitted. They argued that it would be better this

way, because there were too many complications involved in conducting negotiations with

concessionaires, so it was better to begin where this is not an issue. According to Chan, Oxfam

and the communities agreed to this advice because they did not want to risk everything getting

stopped. After four years of prevarication, his frustration was apparent.

We have done everything according to the advice of Oxfam, and especially BLO. But when we

submit it they always say that we have not got it right. Then it has been a year since we submitted

our plan and it has been silent. Forestry Administration officials say it is maybe because

provincial people don‘t really understand what community forestry is.

Whilst Chan was weighed down by the failure of the authorities to approve the community

forestry project, he also found progress in the village difficult. In the year to September 2007,

Chan reported only actually making two patrols of the boundary of the community forestry area

(Interview 65, 67). While the official membership of the Community Forestry initiative was 316

adults from 144 households in the two villages, with 177 of those members coming from Bey,

Chan said that only a few of the members in Krouch were active in the beginning (Interview 71),

and that ultimately he was the only one who was absolutely committed. He related this to a lack

of understanding on the part of other villagers regarding the benefits, as well as to a lack of time

on his part to disseminate information and understanding to his fellow villagers (Interview 67).

Chan interpreted the community forestry project as giving him a mandate not only over the

community forestry site, but also with regard to the implementation of forestry law anywhere in

the forest. During 2007 he reported two sawmills to the Forestry Administration, giving them the

names of both operators, who were from Kenchor village on the Mekong. He also reported

having confiscated two chainsaws from people he found using them in the forest and handed

these into the Forestry Administration. However, as far as Chan could tell, his reports and actions

never led to any action on the part of the Forestry Administration (Interview 67).

In May 2008, Chan started to hear reports that the land at the community forestry site had been

marked off into plots by the commune chief who was selling them at between 400 and 500 US

dollars per plot. In an interview in October 2008 he said that he had heard nothing from either

BLO or Oxfam for a long time, and that as far as he was concerned the project had now failed

From 2003 to now it has been five years. At the beginning, for me, I had hoped that we would

succeed, because we told people about the benefits of natural resources. Especially that there are

many things that are already growing and we do not need fertiliser for those. I am very sad. I have

worked really hard. I have neglected all of my personal interests in order to stop violations. But

the leaders, they don‘t want to have anything to do with this at all. I am very sad, but I still have

the idea that if they can start this again I would try. We can call it failure. It is failure (Interview

71. Author‘s translation).

Later in 2008 there were two meetings held at the commune office, one an annual review of

community forestry activities initiated by Oxfam and BLO, and the other a meeting hosted by the

commune chief. In both cases Chan did not receive his invitation until after the meeting had

Page 168: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

150

occurred. He was sure that this could not have been coincidence, and that they did not want him

there. At that final meeting the commune chief had proposed that the community forestry project

at Bey be cancelled and this was voted through (Interview 74). Chan questioned whether the

commune chief had the right to take such a decision, but given the lack of support he had been

able to muster in the community and the lack of interest from the NGOs he was not planning to

dispute it. He retained the hope that the NGOs or the authorities might take up their interest again,

but for the time being he regarded the project as finished.

5.3.3 Community Forestry in Bey: Meanings and Interpretation

As may be apparent from the above narrative, the story of community forestry in Bey was, at

village level, largely the story of one man‟s struggle. For most villagers „Community Forest‟ does

not mean an area of forest land protected by the community. Rather, the words are a synonym for

Chan. Whenever we asked the question “Where is the community forest?” the first response was

inevitably to be told where Chan was that day or to be told where his house was. To some degree

this was complemented by Chan‟s own self-identification98

: the first time I met him he introduced

himself with words to the effect of “Who are you? I am community here. I need to know

everyone who comes and goes”.

In early visits there was some enthusiasm expressed by other villagers for community forestry,

partly reflecting anger at the appropriation of timber and land by outsiders, and sadness at the

disappearance of the forest. In 2006 the head of one of our case study households, who also sat in

the first Community Forestry committee (2003-7) told us that the community forestry was very

important and that the forests must be protected otherwise there would be no forest left for her

children and grandchildren. In this respect she mentioned the way that „people‟ were just marking

off trees and land and selling them. However, when asked how her family and other families in

the village would be able to make a living if they were not able to cut wood, her response was

that it would be impossible (Interview 24). Hers was one of our case study households and our

knowledge of the household economy confirmed this dependence: her son-in-law worked as both

a chainsaw operator and a transporter of wood, and it was his incomes from this that were the

major source of incomes for the household. They did have agricultural crops, but, at the time of

that interview their rice crop had been destroyed by excessive rains, whilst two years later much

of their chamcar crop had been stolen whilst she took care of her daughter around the time of the

birth of her second grandchild.

To the extent that other people could say any more about community forestry the information

tended to be sketchy. In early 2008 the assistant village chief said that there were maybe four to

ten people in it, but that she did not know anything about it (Interview 81). An older man thought

there were maybe 10 members (Interview 109). One villager had never heard of it at all, though

her neighbour came along and explained by saying that she had heard of it, but that it was

something for men that was talked about at meetings and she knew no more than that (Interview

120). People did seem to know that it had not really worked: “Everyone cuts there now”

(Interview 126) and “Community forestry has gone quiet. We haven‟t heard anything for months”

(Interview 140).

98

To put this in some context, it should also be noted that he never again spoke with such brazen self-importance,

and that alcohol had clearly loosened his tongue prior to this unexpected encounter (Interview 63).

Page 169: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

151

Given that during the six years from early 2003 (when community forestry activities were

introduced to Bey) to early 2009 (when our research ended), that there was almost no activity by

any villager apart from Chan, it is unsurprising that the story of community forestry in the village

is so much one about him, and that he is almost its only narrator. He is also the one person in the

village whose livelihood has been significantly influenced by community forestry. Not because of

the community forest itself (which even he rarely visited), but because of compensation he

received for attendance of training courses and meetings over the years. While not lucrative, it

had been the main source of reported income for his household (himself, his wife and seven

children) during the first half of the research period.

While there was unanimity about the strength of Chan‟s character and commitment, his two main

enemies/rivals in the village, the deputy village chief and the head teacher, both alleged that Chan

became corrupt and started to sell off the community forest land (Interviews 101, 158). We could

not get these allegations corroborated by anybody else, but as we shall see, for Chan personally,

becoming involved in the community forestry activities also meant becoming involved in

personal conflicts.

During the research, Chan referred to his right to not discuss his personal political affiliations

when I raised these with them (Interview 71). Having a reputation as being an opposition party

activist can put somebody in a position of risk, especially if they are outspoken. It seemed to me

from my very first meeting with him in the village that Chan‟s involvement in community

forestry was giving him the platform and the confidence to be outspokenly critical of the

authorities. If any of the professional people I encountered involved in community forestry, either

with donors or NGOs, had been killed I would have been extremely surprised. Whereas I saw it

as quite possible that Chan might meet precisely such an end99

.

As the community forestry initiative stagnated, Chan moved on. For a time he got work with a

Cambodian NGO called PADEK who were establishing savings groups in the district. At the time

of our final visit he had stopped that as he found that the allowance and the petrol money

provided by the NGO barely covered his costs. He had been sick for a month so he had not been

active with any work when we last met him (Interview 74). It seemed that he was recuperating

and would be moving on to new challenges, with the community forestry being something which

had never really taken off and had died a death. On the other hand, as we will see, the community

forestry project in Bey and other villages like it have an “aid chain” behind them populated by

organisations and individuals whose endeavours depend on community forestry being a credible

and worthwhile enterprise. Chan‟s energy and engagement has effectively constituted a one-man

operation sufficient to maintain the impression of community forestry in Bey these past years,

and he may yet be called to service again. The remainder of this chapter reviews the experiences

of some of the other agencies involved in supporting community forestry in Bey.

99

Neither were such fears unrealistic. The mid-term evaluation of the “Promoting Community Forest in Cambodia”

project which provided financial and technical support the community forestry in Bey and 132 other Cambodian

villages from May 2005 gave prominence to an active community forestry leader who had been shot dead a few days

after collecting signatures from other villages for a petition to protest against a local land grab (O'Leary, 2007).

Page 170: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

152

5.3.4 Community Forestry Actors from Beyond the Village

5.3.4.1 The Cambodian NGO Based in the Provincial Town100

The direct supporter of community forestry in Bey was the Cambodian non-governmental

organization Better Lives Organisation (BLO). BLO was established in 1997 and recognized as a

national NGO by the Ministry of Interior in 1998. During the early years of its existence it

received funding from the international NGO Australian Catholic Relief. BLO had originally

been established by former staff members of Australian Catholic Relief, when the latter

organization switched from being an implementing agency to a funding partner for local NGOs.

Their original community development activities had been health and agriculture related and

included the promotion of self-help groups. It first extended these activities to Bey village in

2002.

Central to BLO‟s identity as an NGO is the idea that its staff work closely with communities. In

October 2008 we witnessed part of a training programme where the director talked with young

field workers about the importance of spending time in communities, of listening to people and of

dressing and acting in an appropriate manner when out in the villages. As we have seen, however,

the presence of BLO in Bey, even at its most intense, had never been more than one visit every

one or two months, possibly including some overnight stays. During the research period our six-

monthly visits made us a significantly more frequent visitor than the NGO, notwithstanding its

good intentions to be close to the people and to have grassroots involvement.

In September 2007 the director explained that BLO had the aim of ensuring that every village

received at least one visit every month, but that this was difficult to achieve because BLO had

only two community forestry staff members who were responsible for two districts, supporting a

total of 49 villages, formed into 28 different community forests in 9 different communes. Even if

the two workers had worked separately, and had spent every day doing field work (neither of

which was the case) they would not have been able to spend a day in every village each month. In

order to alleviate the staffing pressure BLO divided the communes into „indirect‟ communes and

„deep engagement‟ (see chomroe) communes. Damrei Pong was a „deep engagement‟ commune.

The director intended to look for ways to provide more resources so that there could be better

support for the communities but these never came. In fact, BLO staff said that they had been

unable to visit the village at all for “4-5 months” during 2008 as a result of a funding delay from

Oxfam (Interview 204).

Somewhat in contrast with our experiences in Bey, the BLO director suggested that community

forestry had been a powerful movement for villagers to protect their livelihoods during the early

years of its implementation. He gave as an example of this the fact that in the two communes

where BLO worked in Chhlong district (namely Damrei Pong where Bey is located, and

neighbouring Kampong Damrei), that the community forestry leaders had confiscated between

twenty and thirty chainsaws in the year to September 2007.

100

Where other citations are not provided, this section is based on Interview 203 with the director of BLO and the

field worker Kru Bong Rien on 21st September 2007.

Page 171: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

153

While the BLO saw the example of confiscation of chainsaws as an example of progress, it could

also be seen as instructive in other ways.

Echoing complaints that we had heard from Chan in the village, the Better Lives Organisation

(BLO) director explained that one of the problems was that the authorities only ever confiscated

chainsaws from normal villagers but that military and police who owned chainsaws never had

them confiscated. When he had made this point to the authorities they responded by saying that if

BLO made lists of everyone including police and military who had chainsaws, that they would

follow up, and that they would confiscate from the police and the military first. BLO complied

with this suggestion and collected reports from community forestry committees in the villages

where they worked of all holders of chainsaws. In other words, it seemed that rather than being an

agent to assist or empower communities, that the NGO was effectively providing surveillance of

the local community for the forestry authorities101

. This small example encapsulated some of the

tensions implicit in a project such as community forestry being regulated by the State, in a

situation where so many of the State actors were involved in predatory economic relations with

the poor people living in „communities‟. The Active Communities (AC) director, who had acted

as an advisor to BLO, explained that he had encouraged the confiscating of chainsaws by

communities as an advocacy ploy. If the community forestry groups confiscated chainsaws this

would be a way of demonstrating that they were capable forest managers, and this could be

contrasted with the inactivity of the Forest Administration. As we saw, however, the tendency for

BLO to seek accommodation and partnership with the Forestry Administration meant that this

(potentially antagonistic) approach was discarded in favour of an alternative where BLO

effectively placed itself (and by implication, the communities it represented) in a managerial

hierarchy under the forest authorities in a relationship that was quite different to that which AC

had intended. So like Craig‟s (1997) antibiotic pills, the confiscation of chainsaws travelled to the

intended location, but like the instructions for the antibiotics, the advocacy strategy was discarded

and replaced by other local ideas and concerns regarding how such a device might be most

effective.

The issue of BLO‟s presence in the village (or lack of it) and its activities are all in the context of

the organisation having a relevant strategy. As we have seen, villagers in Bey, far from being

dependent on preserving forest had, throughout the research period and for some years before

that, been dependent on incomes from cutting forest, and latterly from converting forest land to

agricultural cropping. The BLO director accepted our analysis of livelihoods in Bey, and asked to

compare it with the other 48 villages where BLO was providing support for community forestry,

he estimated that “60-70%” were characterised by situations comparable to Bey. In the other 30-

40%, however, NTFPs were more prominent in village livelihoods. He gave as an example of this

a village which BLO had treated as a „model‟ village since 2005, namely Veal Konseing in

neighbouring Kampong Damrei commune. There he said that resin tapping was a key source of

revenues and villager-logging was not a significant issue. He said that because the community

forest area was one where the villagers tapped resin every day in large numbers that they were

able to monitor their community forest without excessive extra effort and had a strong incentive

to do so. This picture, however, was counterbalanced by the Active Communities (AC) director

101

There was no reason to expect the FA to honour their promise to do this, and we have already seen the example of

the Prime Minister instructing the FA to halt forest encroachment by rich and powerful people, and them then using

this edict against poor people on behalf of company interests.

Page 172: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

154

who was familiar with both the villages in question, and with community forestry projects

throughout Cambodia, and said that while Veal Konseing was initially more receptive to forest

protection activities, that a lot of villagers there were also involved in logging (Interview 254).

The above account of BLO‟s role suggests a rather dismal experience. The apparent „community

forestry‟ in Bey was in reality one person fighting a lonely and losing battle. Community forestry

was not attuned to local circumstances and even had the area of forest been protected it would

have been completely marginal to the issues that will actually determine villagers‟ futures. To the

extent that the village was a „community‟, it consisted of three groups with different backgrounds

all competing to make the most of a highly insecure situation. Within this there were some

serious conflicts which would potentially shape the future livelihoods of the people living in the

village and future generations. There was, in other words, plenty of work for anyone committed

to community organisation. The presence of BLO clearly did not represent such a commitment. It

effectively worked through just one person in the village (one who was party to and indeed

vulnerable to intra-village conflicts) and was simply letting social and economic relations in the

village take their own course. Given the overall personnel resources of BLO devoted to

community forestry during the project period (2 people for 49 villages) and the director‟s verdict

that local economies in 60-70% of those villages were similar to Bey it is difficult not to conclude

that the organisation‟s impacts overall in its work with community forestry must have been

similarly dismal.

Table 5-9: Better Lives Organisation’s Community Forestry Funding 2004-8

Years Amount

(USD)

Donor Reason for funding.

2004-

5

Just

under

10 000

Community Forestry

International (CFI)

To support work in 28 villages in 2 communes

2003 27 000 Canada Fund

2004 20 000 Oxfam via CFI and

the Power to

Communities (AC)

Funds released against expenditure on a 3-month

rolling basis so he is not sure exactly how much

was given.

2005-

6

34 000 European Union via

Oxfam GB

As part of the EU Protecting Tropical Forests

project. For work in 9 communes.

2006-

8

70 000 European Union via

Oxfam GB

As part of the EU Protecting Tropical Forests

project. For work in 9 communes.

Total 161 000

Source: BLO Director’s Estimates (Interview 203)

Page 173: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

155

However, the general point made by Blaikie (2006) – that CBNRM tends to be more successful in

reproducing itself than it does in achieving its stated objectives – seemed to apply to BLO.

According to the BLO director, the organisation had received in the region of 161 000 US dollars

for community forestry work in up to 49 villages work during the five years 2004-8 (see Table

5-9).

s a result of the credibility that BLO built up in its work supporting community forestry in those

villages during this period, it had also received further funding in order to expand the scope of its

work, being allocated a further 80,000 USD being due from the East West Management Institute

to support work with the Prey Long protected forest in the west of the province, and a 27 000

USD from Canada Fund to support work with ethnic minority community forestry groups in

Kracheh102

.

5.3.4.2 The Cambodian NGO/donor: Footloose and Flexible

One of the prime movers behind the community forestry initiatives in Kracheh and indeed behind

the community forestry movement in Cambodia in general was Active Communities (AC), a

small non-government organization (NGO) focusing on empowerment and community

organization103

. Being funded by private donations from the United States, the organization was

somewhat more flexible and less burdened by the nature of the „partnerships‟ with donors than

either BLO or the other organizations involved in supporting community forestry in Bey.

AC had become interested in forest action as a response to the impacts on rural livelihoods of the

activities of companies holding logging concessions. It saw a particular opportunity in

documenting the livelihoods of resin tapping households in Cambodian forests, and using these as

the basis for advocacy work which would challenge the activities of companies which routinely

(and illegally) cut resin trees in their concession areas.

As a result, AC sent field workers to forested areas throughout Cambodia in order to identify

communities that were highly dependent on resin tapping in order to support them in protecting

their livelihoods. In 2002 the AC director had visited Damrei Pong commune, where Bey is

located, and may even have visited Bey. He judged that it was not a promising area in which to

pursue community forestry because the resin trees in the area had already been logged and as a

result the villagers were now more interested in cutting down trees than in preventing the cutting

of trees. In the course of their investigations, AC had, through its field workers, also come into

contact with BLO and had been particularly impressed with the engagement and abilities of

Samnang, who was the BLO director during the research period, but had at that time been a field

worker. As a result, AC supported BLO to become more involved in community organization

around forestry issues in areas where resin tapping was still an important part of people‟s

livelihoods.

102

AC director (and BLO board member) comments: “Probably no one was ever impressed with BLO’s work in Chhlong, and it has been their work in Sambor and other areas that has allowed them to get funding. Plus the fact that there aren’t any other decent NGOs in Kratie doing any better on land and livelihoods rights”.

103 This section is informed principally by interviews 253 and 254 with the AC director in January and October 2008

respectively. Interview 254 was recorded digitally.

Page 174: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

156

There were a number of ironies and contradictions involved in the AC support to BLO and the

way in which events played out. One was that the fact that Samnang became the director of BLO.

The BLO Board of Directors104

, who did not have the same confidence in other staff members at

that time, sought to ensure that he remained engaged in the field, and supported the appointment

of an older, more administratively oriented staff member as director. This did not, however, work

out, so that the original reason for AC confidence in BLO as a community organisation, namely

Samnang‟s talent and commitment as a field worker, was lost quite early. Another irony was that

as BLO got more funds they expanded to include Damrei Pong in their target areas despite the

original AC judgement that the area was not promising.

The largest irony, however, was that AC assisted BLO and several other organizations to work

with Oxfam GB and secure EU funding for a major project which came to be called Promoting

Community Forestry in Cambodia. At around the time that funding was successfully secured,

though, the AC director came to the conclusion that community forestry was not an effective tool

for promoting community interests. This conclusion related to the way in which community

forestry had become an officially sanctioned movement, with government approval and legal

recognition becoming the key milestones for everyone involved in community forestry105

.

For the AC director, this orientation towards official recognition meant that instead of responding

to community priorities and community needs, that community forestry actors were instead

responding to Forestry Administration priorities and waiting for their approval (FA):

Then the FA started to get involved and to say that CF was a good thing. Then these maps started

to come out which showed CF areas and concession areas. These were official maps from the FA

and everything that wasn‘t CF was the company. Since that time I have been saying ‗stop doing

community forestry‘. There came a point when I thought that community forestry was not the thing

to do. So I said to Samnang that CF is not good, and he listened and said OK but continued to do

it. I had been involved in designing the project106

in late 2004 but by the time the project had come

on line in mid 2005 I had concluded that CF was not the thing to do. I switched from thinking that

CF was a strategy for communities to get forests from the companies to thinking it was a

government strategy to get forests for the companies (Interview 254).

And,

The more you do community forestry the more it is implicitly recognising it is a state forest. I think

CBNRM has got to start with the idea of intrinsic rights and that this is your forest, and CF starts

with the opposite, this is not yours you‘ve got to ask us for it (Interview 254).

104

The BLO Board included the director of AC 105

The AC critique was to some extent confirmed by an interview with a forestry academic working with one of the

donor agencies in Phnom Penh notwithstanding the fact that he saw developments in a more positive light. When

asked if there was any evidence that community forestry had succeeded in either its goals of improving livelihoods or

of protecting forests, he replied not. On the other hand, he compared it to community fisheries and other CBNRM

initiatives and said that it was relatively successful in having achieved legal recognition, with a law having passed

and a sub-decree and guidelines to enable the implementation of the law, and with a number of the community

forestry sites well on the way towards being formally recognized by the government (Interview 174).

106

The reference here is to the EU/Oxfam GB “Protecting Tropical Forests” project.

Page 175: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

157

This dissonance between the apparent objectives of community forestry and what it actually

achieves in terms of normalisation, pacification and extension of government reach, is a theme

which calls to mind the conclusions of Ferguson (1994) and Foucault (1979) mentioned in the

introduction of this thesis and to which we will return at the conclusion107

.

As the relatively nimble AC turned its attention away from providing formal support for

community forestry, other organisations, with a far greater weight of bureaucratic relations to

bear and much more limited ability to change course arrived on the scene. These were Oxfam GB

with its head office in Oxford and the European Commission with its headquarters in Brussels

and regional office in Bangkok. The EU became the key funding source for BLO and the

community forestry in Bey during the research period by means of the 5-year (2005-10)

European Union project “Promoting Community Forestry in Cambodia” implemented by Oxfam

GB.

5.3.4.3 The International NGO Sub-contracting and Co-financing 2005-9

Oxfam GB had been present in Cambodia throughout the 1980s and, through the publication of

the book Punishing the Poor (Mysliwiec, 1988a), had been instrumental in highlighting the

poverty impacts of the international isolation of Cambodia. Through the 1980s then, Oxfam had

close relations with the government and carried out project activities that might normally be

associated with major bilateral donors, such as the improvement of clean water infrastructure in

the capital. In the early 1990s Oxfam moved to a more traditional NGO role, which at first

included direct implementation of its own projects, but rapidly moved to a role as an organisation

which on the one hand supported the development activities of Cambodian NGOs (dubbed in the

recent lingua franca of the development industry “partners”) and on the other hand engaged in

policy advocacy activities.

In May 2005 the 5-year European Union project “Promoting Community Forestry in Cambodia”

was initiated, with Oxfam GB as the executing agency providing support to seven Cambodian

local NGOs involved in providing direct support to community forestry projects (EC, 2005). This

support was complemented by the international NGO, Voluntary Service Overseas (VSO) which

provided volunteers mainly to support the identification and marketing of commercial non-timber

forest products from the community forestry sites. The project budget was 1,623,529 Euros, co-

financed by the European Union (77%), Oxfam GB (20%) and VSO (3%) (Interview 138; Oxfam

GB, 2005).

During the research period and the years preceding it, there was continuity in the main actors

involved in community forestry in BLO (where both the field worker-teacher and the director

were constant), and AC (whose director likewise remained in place). The same continuity of

personnel did not obtain further back in the chain. During the course of the field research

(between July 2006 and March 2009) there was an almost complete turnover of relevant staff at

Oxfam GB, as well as an in-country reorganisation. The country director changed, and so did the

programme manager and the programme officer with overall responsibility for the European

Union community forestry programme. Meanwhile, responsibility for providing support to BLO

107

Precisely these same Foucauldian/anti-politics dynamics have been discussed in relation to NGO interventions in

similar contexts by Bryant (2002)

Page 176: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

158

was decentralised from the Phnom Penh office to a new provincial office which opened in May

2007 with new programme officers and assistants. In early January 2009 a new programme

officer who would be responsible for providing support to BLO was employed. As researchers,

then, we were no longer tracing the experiences and learning of individuals following a process

(as we had been in the village and with the smaller organisations), but instead were meeting a

series of people who were each beginning a process of getting to know the people above and

below them in their own organisation‟s hierarchy, as well as the organisations and communities

that they were to be working with. In the absence of continuity of personnel, and especially of

leadership, the project document was of necessity of central importance.

Of interest for this thesis, and especially in the light of our research in Bey, is the central

assumption of the EU/Oxfam project document that community forestry constitutes a win-win

solution that is both good for the people and good for the forests. It allows for no possibility that

what is best for local people‟s livelihoods and what is best for sustainable forest management

might in some circumstances be in conflict with each other. Because there is no

acknowledgement of this possible conflict of interests, there is no need to identify a priority.

Accordingly the project documentation simply alternates between them. The EU implicitly

prioritises forests locating the project within a “Program on Tropical Forests and other Forests in

Developing Countries”. The project summary on the other hand gives more weight to the “target

group” of “poor forest-dependent men and women and communities, including indigenous

groups”, who are described in the following somewhat caricatured terms:

Forest-dependent people in Cambodia are among the poorest of all sections of society in one of

the world‘s poorest countries. Although they are resilient and resourceful, their capacity to forge

their own livelihoods has been eroded by the insidious loss of control they once had over

resources traditionally managed by them. This project will support the processes of knowledge-

and skill-gaining, and empowerment that are needed to promote management of forested areas by

communities under a newly-enacted framework of law (Oxfam GB, 2005, p. 4)

The project objective by contrast switches primacy back to the forests:

The overall project objective is ―Sustainable management of forests in Cambodia, based on full

community participation‖ (Oxfam GB, 2005, p. 4)

But this switches back to an apparent people-first orientation under the „specific objective‟:

The specific objective is ―Improved livelihoods for forest-dependent women and men based on

sustainable and productive use of forest resources‖ (Oxfam GB, 2005, p. 4)

The project approach to both forests and people is thus fundamentally instrumental. The forests

are not just a natural or social or cultural „resource‟ in their own right, but must also provide

sustainable livelihoods for people living in them. Meanwhile, „the people‟ are not just people who

are to realise goals in their own terms, but they are framed as “forest-dependent” people who will

“sustainably manage” the forests.

Not only are „the beneficiaries‟ framed up as locked in a mutually beneficial relationship with

forests, but their livelihoods are also framed as being of a particular type:

Many of the people targeted by this project live within forestry concessions. All depend on forest

products. Some depend on forest products as their main livelihood option; for many the resources

are second in importance only to farming. The most important product is liquid resin, which

Page 177: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

159

community members tap from huge resin trees. Other important products include hard resin

(dammar), wild fruits, mushrooms, palm leaves, honey, vines, rattan, and bamboo. Most of these

products are collected in a way that is sustainable and does not damage the forest. Forests are

also important to the local culture and as habitat for wildlife (Oxfam GB, 2005, pp. 6-7).

People are thus not only “forest-dependent”, but their livelihoods are underpinned by activities

which do not harm the forests. Such a framing of the people clearly fits well with the problem

formulated above, namely “the insidious loss of control they once had over resources traditionally

managed by them”. However, as we have clearly seen, this framing excludes the villagers of Bey,

not to mention the 30-35 more villages (out of 49) where BLO worked where the “resources

traditionally managed” in the form of resin trees had long since been harvested, leaving villagers

with short-term livelihoods based on logging and longer-term possibilities dependent on the

agricultural opportunities in a post-deforestation landscape. As such, this misrepresentation of

forest communities as overwhelmingly NTFP-dependent provided no guidance to development

workers further down the chain in terms of how to react when meeting forest-dwelling

communities whose livelihoods were not, and could not be, be based on NTFPs.108

The corrosive effects of this misrepresentation were apparent in the interview responses. When

Oxfam programme officers were presented with the situation in Bey and asked what they thought

their response should be in a situation where villagers‟ livelihoods would not be improved by

community forestry their responses were somewhat similar. One said that he did not know what

the alternative would be and he would have to discuss with other members of the team, but on

further reflection said that many villagers were short-sighted and that “If we tell them how

valuable forest is, they understand and want to protect the forest” (Interview 185). Likewise, the

programme officer newly responsible for cooperation with BLO who said that if people reported

a lack of potential for NTFPs from the forest that Oxfam people might be able to look more

carefully and find that actually there was potential (Interview 186). In other words, if the realities

of the people did not fit with the reality of the project document, then the response of the

development workers was that the people‟s realities must be altered. It is perhaps not irrelevant to

point out that the new programme officer had been working since the beginning of January 2009

and she was not due to make her first visit to a community forestry village until some time in

March. So even relatively „low‟ in the aid chain, at a decentralised provincial office,

administrative and bureaucratic workloads seemed to take priority. Interviews with the first

Programme Officer to have responsibility for the EU project, and with other Oxfam staff who had

been present during the debrief of the first EU monitoring mission indicated that much of the

Oxfam workload for supporting community forestry actually involved managing the

administrative and financial reporting of the local partners (Interviews 181, 184).

5.3.4.4 The Donor: Control Orientation Revisited

The European Union staff member in Phnom Penh responsible for the Promoting Community

Forestry project stressed that he was not a technical officer and that the EU was not a technical

agency, so that they relied on periodic monitoring visits in order to get technical inputs.

108

Comment from AC director: ”It might be interesting to look at how this misrepresentation came about since I was

part of that. We were looking for resin tapping, and found it and learned about it. We didn‘t ever try to learn about

the situation in communities‖.

Page 178: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

160

First EU monitoring mission occurred in 2008 and looked at progress in relation to three sets of

outputs: training; legal approval; livelihood improvement. It reported that there had been

abundant training, that legal recognition had not been achieved to the degree expected and that

targets should be revised, and that there had been no livelihood outputs. It also found that much

of the reporting required had not been carried out, and that there was a lack of clarity regarding

the division of responsibilities between Oxfam and the European Union for uploading of reports

(Interview 184).

Both of the Oxfam programme managers who successively had responsibility for the

management of the EU co-financed programme spoke of the difficulties in cooperating with the

European Union, and specifically of the fact that authority was not delegated to Phnom Penh, but

that almost all decisions had to be referred back to Bangkok or even Brussels (Interviews 181,

182).

Printed on the inside cover of the successful application for EU funding for the “Promoting

Community Forestry in Cambodia” project is a message from the EU to potential applicants

Omissions cannot be rectified; if any information or document is missing, your application will be

rejected (Oxfam GB, 2005, p. 2).

This seemed to provide a vivid illustration of just how little flexibility the European Union

allowed itself for responding to situations which differed from those set out in the project

document109

. The aid chain may be seen as a hierarchical arrangement with the donor at the top

exercising control and authority via the conditional release of funds. The control from the top

may be more or less personalised. In other words, the project document may be used to adjudicate

each decision. Alternatively a degree of personal discretion may be allowed to enable response to

unexpected factors. It is the latter which was called for by Porter et al. (1991) in their critique of

“control orientation” of project management in 1970s and 1980s development projects. In this

case it appeared that a control orientation was, of necessity, the default setting. Having neither

technical expertise, nor an in-depth knowledge of conditions on the ground, the EU donor was

only in a position to process financial reports and output reports that corresponded to the

assumptions and logic of the project document. We did not find any indications that either Oxfam

or BLO had registered the dissonance between the livelihoods and relationships depicted in the

project document and those found on the ground, much less sought to respond to them. However,

it is worth noting that even if they had seen a problem and attempted to take initiative that the EU

office in Phnom Penh would, for organisational reasons, have had the greatest difficulty in

responding to requests to amend the approaches in the project document. This was, in other words

a vivid illustration of the sort of dynamic pointed out in our brief sampling of institutional

economics perspectives in chapter 2. With both supply and demand originating in the donor

countries, incentive structures tend to be oriented in that direction, exacerbating the inherent

problem of feedback loops between „beneficiaries‟ in places like Bey and the citizens of EU

countries who ultimately demand and pay for the interventions.

109

The AC director recalled that the first Oxfam staff member responsible for the project always said ‖We have to do

exactly what is in the project document. The EU won‘t let us change. The EU is notorious this way‖.

Page 179: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

161

5.3.4.5 Encountering the Concessionaire – Or Not

Whilst the aid chain for the community forestry initiative in Bey stretches back from the village

to Brussels via the BLO office in Kracheh provincial town, the Oxfam office in Kracheh, the

Oxfam office in Phnom Penh, the EU office in Phnom Penh and the EU office in Bangkok, a key

actor determining whether or not a community forestry project in Bey is feasible or not is the

Casotim company. Without company agreement, a community forestry project would not be

implementable.

In 2008, Oxfam staff supported a Cambodian partner NGO in Stung Treng province to negotiate

an agreement with a concessionaire to allow 4000 hectares within his company‟s concession to be

allocated as a community forest. The Oxfam programme officer reporting this saw it as an

appropriate way for Oxfam to engage (Interview 184). This did not, however, reflect the general

experience presented by Oxfam staff, who depicted a set of relationships which placed

themselves, and indeed the communities, at several steps removed from the companies in general,

and Casotim in particular.

According to one of the Kracheh programme officers “We don‟t have any contact with the

company because this is the responsibility of the Forestry Administration” (Interview 185),

adding that the relationship between the Forestry Administration and the NGOs was the

responsibility of the RECOFTC110

office established within the provincial Forestry

Administration office. This sense that negotiating with the concessionaire was someone else‟s

responsibility was familiar from other interviews. Chan in the village had never attempted to

contact Casotim because he said that was BLO‟s responsibility (Interview 71). BLO meanwhile

explained that they had had limited contact with Casotim because that was a Forestry

Administration responsibility (Interview 203). Somehow, then, the community deferred to the

local NGO, the local NGO deferred to the international NGO, RECOFTC, situated in the Forestry

Administration office, RECOFTC deferred to the Forestry Administration. In this constellation

there was no clear role for Oxfam to engage directly, although programme officers regarded

themselves as supporting and cooperating with BLO and RECOFT (Interview 185). One of the

Oxfam programme managers expressed some frustration that in some cases the Forestry

Administration seemed to be aligned with the concessionaires and to be trying to keep the

community forestry actors at a distance (Interview 181).

In 2007 there had been some dialogue with Casotim. Meetings had been arranged and documents

submitted in May 2007. According to the BLO director there was a “90% chance” that Casotim

would approve the community forestry sites approved in the concession area. Time passed,

however, and no reply was forthcoming. Without the network of relations which encumbered the

actors in the aid chain I could potentially approach Casotim directly for interviews.

The Casotim company‟s head office in Phnom Penh was Monivong #100. This placed it in a very

prominent and affluent area, south of the Wat Phnom monument that gives the capital its name

and north of the Independence monument. Located opposite the office of the World Bank, the

110

Regional Community Forestry Training Center for Asian and the Pacific (RECOFTC) is an international NGO

which received a contract to support the legalization of community forestry. RECOFTC have an office in Phnom

Penh in the national Forestry Administration, and during the course of the research they established their Kracheh

provincial office (Interview 131).

Page 180: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

162

Casotim office was also the former Czechoslovakian embassy. Whenever I went there it appeared

deserted and I was not able to contact anyone. I managed to make one mobile phone call to a

Casotim employee who gave me an email address, but I never received a reply to the mails. In

this sense, then the company was not readily accessible.

Having failed to either engage substantially with Casotim nationally, or to gain a proper

introduction at district, however, I finally decided to take a chance on meeting the Casotim

representative at home. It is worth noting that it was difficult to find a motorcycle taxi who would

take me to his house. The first ones I approached were afraid of the reaction from his security

guards if they took me there. An experienced Cambodian researcher in Phnom Penh also

expressed concern for my safety if my research started to incorporate the business interests of

concessionaires and timber traders. For me, of course, there was no particular danger associated

with such an interview. However, it is important to note that for people living and working

locally there would have been a more tangible calculation of risk when attempting any form of

engagement with a forest concession company.

Having approached him in the street between his home and the Casotim compound and secured

an interview I asked him whether Casotim would be agreeing to the community forestry in Bey.

His answer was a flat no. Casotim would not permit the establishment of a community forestry

site in the area of the village, and did not recognize the one that had been proposed (Interview

218). There was therefore a very stark contrast in the research results between that which was

reported by various NGO and FA interviewees, namely that Casotim were very difficult to

contact, that the answer was uncertain, but that it would probably be yes, and the findings when

the Casotim representative was interviewed, namely that he was rather easy to access, that the

answer was not at all uncertain, and that it was no. There was likewise a stark contrast between

the way that the community forestry actors and Casotim represented the state of communication:

the NGOs waiting for a reply whilst the Casotim representative said that it had already been

given. The practical consequence of this difference was that it remained possible to rationalise

continued support for community forestry activities in Bey and other villages in the company

concession area.

5.4 Conclusions and Implications

5.4.1 Bey and Cambodian Community Forestry

During the research, two lines of argument were identifiable amongst community forestry

practitioners. One might be said to come from an „activist faction‟ who believed that rights to

forest should be grounded in established use and practice, and that communities should assert

these rights with the support of NGOs and without waiting to be guided by government. To some

extent these practitioners saw community forestry as a means of resistance, which in the short

term might slow or disrupt the destruction of forests by predatory non-local interests, and in the

longer term might build a sense of entitlement and increase people‟s capacity more generally to

organize resistance against powerful outsiders. A more technically oriented „diplomatic faction‟

were looking at partnerships with government, and seeking to safeguard community forestry by

recruiting the government as the ultimate supporter and regulator of community forestry. Their

assumption tended to be that there was little hope for them to influence the management of high

value forests in Cambodia, that the decline of the forest resource would continue, but that

Page 181: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

163

community forestry presented an opportunity to create some enclaves of exception where the

mobilisation of local resources and incentives could create the long-term potential for pockets of

community managed forest on currently degraded forest land.

In Bey, community forestry had been introduced by followers of the activist approach, but by the

time our research commenced, the project had been incorporated into the EU project managed by

Oxfam, and a diplomatic approach characterised the support offered. While Bey is far from being

a flagship case for either approach it may be noted that an „activist‟ rejected it as a community

forestry site from the start, whilst „diplomats‟ then nurtured it, and notwithstanding the

information from the Casotim representative and Chan suggesting that the project had neither a

present nor a future, it remained on the list of projects that was being prepared for approval by the

community forestry section of the Forestry Administration in Phnom Penh.

In some respects, Bey would seem to be a representative case, but in other respects it seems likely

to prove less representative. As we saw in chapter 4, the location of the community forestry site

in low value, degraded forest which cannot currently contribute greatly to livelihoods is likely to

be rather typical. The observation from the BLO director that most of the villages which BLO

support are similar – in terms of villagers relying on logging more than NTFPs – also suggests

that Bey is not untypical in that respect, although it should be noted that he thought there were a

large minority of villages which were more NTFP oriented in their use of forest.

That there was so very little meaningful support for community forestry in the village may well

be an exception. Interviews with the AC director, the experiences of community forestry

documented elsewhere in Cambodia (Bradley, 2009), and the feedback I received when I

presented to a gathering of community forestry activists and researchers in Phnom Penh in March

2009 suggested that even in the absence of a strong short term livelihood motivation,

communities do sometimes mobilise around forest protection and management. Oxfam

programme officers had likewise been able to give examples which sounded far more relevant

and successful than that in Bey, although the sense was that these were somewhat exceptional.

The new programme manager had seen a project in Kampong Thom province where there was

regular patrolling, but this was the only such example he had seen (Interview 182), and one of the

new programme officers had been in a village where villagers could collect 30-45 litres of resin

per day, worth 6-9 USD, but again that there were very few villages where such opportunities

existed (Interview 185). Overall, the new project manager believed that the benefits of

community forestry would not come for the current generation, but that villagers expected

community forestry to benefit their children (Interview 184).

However, the fact that a community forestry project could be sustained as a „live‟ project for six

years when only one person in the „community‟ was engaged does raise the question as to

whether some of the other 300 community forestry initiatives in Cambodia are of a similar nature.

Notwithstanding the apparent „cancellation‟ of the project by the commune chief111

, the project

remained on the list of those being forwarded for approval at national level (Interview 172)

indicating the potential for local flimsiness to be counterpointed by national level durability.

111

Who, we must recall, was facing a court case where he would be accused of selling this land, so seemed to have a

personal stake in the cancellation of the project.

Page 182: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

164

A final reflection relates back to the literature. As we saw, there is little debate about the validity

of assertions that common property regimes and community based natural resource management

arrangements are feasible in certain circumstances. The key, according to the literature, is to

identify where those circumstances might exist, and how they might be nurtured. Major themes in

development literature suggest that close attention to livelihoods is now a cornerstone of

development practice (Scoones, 1998). Despite this, what we found was a development

organisation reproducing precisely the same „forest caricatures‟ criticised by Walker (2004) and

Murray Li (2002) elsewhere in the region, and which, echoing the 1990s case studies (Ferguson,

1994; T. Mitchell, 1995; Porter et al., 1991) in the introduction involved a complete and

fundamental misrepresentation of the livelihoods of the people. It seemed that the incentives to

produce the sort of policy simplifications which Ostrom found so abhorrent were simply too

great. These were exacerbated in a system whereby a lack of personal accountability (with staff

turnover in the EU and Oxfam meaning that nobody in place at the beginning of the project was

left at the end) was replaced with an attempt to make all accountable to the very project document

that exemplified and embodied the misrepresentations. Mosse‟s more cynical suggestion that

policy is not implemented but reproduced was much in evidence, however, his more optimistic

corollary, that new spaces for unexpected effects and local appropriations would be opened up

was absent. Rather, there was the frustration and disappointment felt by Chan in the village, and

the futile assertions of young field workers that their response to the mismatch between the

livelihoods of the villagers and the livelihoods inscribed in the project document would be to

„educate‟ the villagers about valuing their environment.

5.4.2 Bey and Geographies of Evasiveness

In chapter 4 we saw how there is a tendency for „solutions‟ in the form of tenure rights

interventions to avoid „problems‟ such as tenure insecurity. The broad argument was that the

political economy of Cambodia ensures that interventions that might challenge the status quo are

carefully diverted and/or diluted. Diverted such that they only travel to places without ready

opportunities for elites to extract significant rents, and diluted meaning that if they are allowed to

travel to places where elite rent-seeking takes place, that they will travel in diluted form, free of

any potentially transformative content.

In Bey, then, we focused on a case in the forests. These being a renowned provider of opportunity

for elite moneymaking interests, the national case suggested that we would find diversion and

dilution here in order to ensure that those interests were not opposed. That proved to be the case.

Community forestry had been stripped of its potentially radical content. This was the frustration

of the AC director who found that government regulation of community forestry as well as

enabling the state to replace the communities as the prime movers, undermined the possibilities of

villagers opposing elite interests.

Integral to this was the way in which the community forestry sites functioned as spatial

containers. Effectively, by focusing on community forests within boundaries, the authorities were

able to delegitimize community concerns over the rest of the forest. Rather than working towards

a conceptualisation of forest resources as public resources for everyone‟s good, community

forestry created a sense that people‟s rights over forest were only exercised within the boundaries

of the community forest, and that the Forestry Administration as the agent of the state had all the

rights over the remaining forest.

Page 183: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

165

A second, more everyday issue, was that the detailed work required to fulfil the community

forestry criteria effectively absorbed the energies of those people who were potentially political

active and might have galvanised opposition to elite economic interests in forest areas. At

meetings, Chan did not spend his time discussing how the „community‟ could gain control of

sufficient forest and land to make a substantial and sustainable contribution to their livelihoods.

Rather, he and the NGO staff spent their time learning to fulfil steps one, two, three, four, five,

six, seven and eight in the community forestry guidelines. The mid-term evaluation of the

Promoting Community Forestry in Cambodia project was critical of the way that the government

complemented the 2003 Community Forestry Sub-Decree with the 2006 Community Forestry

Prakas and then refused to recognize measures taken towards achieving legal recognition from

prior to 2006, thereby requiring all communities to start the process again (O'Leary, 2007). This

form of bureaucracy might not have assisted the intended goals of improved livelihoods and

sustainable forest management, but it certainly achieved the sort of unintended goals that

Ferguson (1994) argued were served by development discourse, namely the extension of

bureaucratic state power. The business of energies being poured into the measuring and planning

of the detailed movements of every day life resonates perfectly with the logic of Foucault‟s

(1979) prison which inspired Ferguson. The sorts of detail that would be required after legal

approval, in the form of forest inventories and management plans suggest that community

forestry would continue to contribute to the bureaucratisation and de-politicization of everyday

life.

5.5 Summary

Fifty years ago the village of Bey was principally inhabited by people born and brought up in the

area, and whose livelihoods were largely sustained by non-timber forest products (NTFPs), which

were both traded and consumed. The logging of the 1990s transformed local livelihoods. NTFPs

were no longer abundant, and villagers instead became dependent on labouring in the timber

industry. There was some trading of timber in the village too, but it was principally people

migrating into the village from trading villages on the Mekong who took advantage of trading

opportunities. Overall, the years since peace came to Bey in 1994 have been a period of economic

boom. Villagers were pleased about the changes. They regretted the disappearance of the

beautiful tall hardwood trees and the abundance of food and wildlife, but none of them would

turn the clock back from today‟s „happier‟ times to those more impoverished, isolated ones.

However, the increased wealth has come at the price of insecurity, and villagers in Bey are

generally extremely uncertain about their future prospects. Recently, opportunities for logging

have declined as the forest resource is depleted. Attention has now turned to exploiting the forest

as agricultural land. Since 2004 the population of the village has more than doubled as a result of

households from agricultural areas of Kampong Cham province moving in to buy or claim farm

land. At the same time, outside companies have established links with various local actors to try

and establish claims to agricultural land. If successful they may extinguish villagers‟ claims to

land. The company holding a concession in the district while making deals with other companies

has expressed its interest in principle in allowing villagers to have 5 hectares of agricultural land

per household. Other experiences nearby suggest that any such allocation process will be

uncertain and heavily mediated by the conflicting agendas of outsiders.

Page 184: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

166

A community forestry project was launched in the village in 2003 by a local NGO which

facilitated the election of a community forestry committee. The NGO, despite a commitment in

principle to community development, has never been more than an occasional visitor to the

village. One villager, Chan, was elected head of the community forestry committee. He has

advocated community forestry, and attended meetings and trainings outside the village from 2003

to 2009 to support him in that role. He never succeeded in mobilising other villagers. A proposed

community forest site was marked in April 2006. It was 6 kilometres remote from the village in

an area not visited by villagers in their everyday lives. Chan never succeeded in establishing

regular visits of patrols of the site. The NGOs supporting and financing community forestry and

the Forestry Administration reported asking the local concession company to approve the

community forest site. During the research they reported that they were waiting for a response.

The representative of the company reported that it would definitely not approve the site. During

May 2008 the commune chief was reportedly selling off parcels of land in the community forest

site for up to 500 USD each. Chan began to report that the project had failed. At the end of the

year the commune chief, at a meeting to which Chan did not receive an invitation, secured a

decision from the commune council to end the project. Chan judged the project a failure, even

saying that he himself had failed to win a single supporter to it.

An international NGO has supported the community forestry project since 2005 as part of a

programme supporting 133 villages in 7 provinces. The multilateral donor supporting the project

has no technical staff in-country and relies on monitoring visits for technical support in

overseeing the project. The community forestry project is grounded on a conception of the

community more or less as it was fifty years ago before the forest resource was depleted and the

local political economy transformed by the activities of non-local actors. NGO worker

explanations as to how they can respond to this mismatch centre on the idea of teaching villagers

to value their environment. Activists responsible for promoting community forestry have become

disenchanted with its lack of effect. At the conclusion of this research in early 2009 the project at

Bey remained on the list of projects being submitted for approval at the national Forestry

Administration, and actors involved in community forestry measure current progress in terms of

legal recognition of projects and anticipate that livelihood benefits from community forestry will

follow much later. Interviews suggest that within the donor project there are many villages with

situations that broadly resemble Bey in terms of non-NTFP livelihood and the identification of

poor quality forest remote from the village; some villages however have livelihoods that are more

NTFP-oriented and have functioning community forestry activities.

The promotion of community forestry in a form that is regulated by the government at every step

tends to weaken its potential to enhance villagers‟ tenure rights at the expense of elite outsiders.

By contrast, it absorbs the energies of villagers who might potentially have provided resistance,

and implicitly extends the reach and legitimacy of the bureaucratic state. These processes

correspond with the concept of dilution introduced in chapter 4. The location of the community

forestry site likewise provides a local example of the diversion that was seen at national level.

Page 185: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

167

6. Systematic Land Titling in Buon Village

6.1 Introduction

The fourth chapter of this thesis showed how tenure security interventions have been diverted and

diluted in Cambodia. Systematic land titling was diverted away from areas prone to tenure

insecurity, and into smallholder rice farming landscapes where tenure was already secure.

Community forestry was admitted into the generally insecure forested landscapes, but only

approved in diluted form (minimal rights awarded and minimal approval), and also, as we saw in

chapter 5, diverted away from places where powerful interests might be engaged. The current

chapter will take a closer look at a village where systematic land titling has been administered. By

examining changes in the context of local livelihoods, it will be possible to critically reflect on

the conclusions in chapter 4. Is it really villagers‟ lived experience that tenure insecurity is

elsewhere, and that the benefits that titling is intended to generate were already available de facto

before titling? Or does formal titling actually generate more effects and possibilities locally than

is expected after the national analysis in chapter 4. Following the approach outlined in chapter 3,

I will first present the livelihoods of people in the village, and set those in the broader political

and economic context which shapes them (immanent development), before then describing the

villagers‟ encounter with the systematic land titling intervention (intentional development) and its

consequences.

Underpinning the argument of chapter 4 was the idea that a resource rich area creates a landscape

where powerful actors and interests compete. To the extent that those same powerful actors also

have the opportunity to influence development interventions, they will make sure that any

intervention which might challenge or disrupt their interests will be either diverted away from the

resource rich area, or re-worked such that it serves rather than opposes their interests. Chapter 5

gave us insights into the livelihoods of poor people in such an area. On the one hand they faced

the dangers of dealing with raw power. On the other hand, they faced the uncertainty of not

knowing which actor would appear on the scene next, and of working out the truth behind the

claims and connections of that actor.

According to our findings in chapter 4, a village in rice fields is not resource rich. One would not

expect it to attract outside actors who create a sense of danger and uncertainty for local

inhabitants. Instead, one would expect something that comes nearer to mimicking the supposedly

timeless tranquillity of the peasant village. In many ways this is exactly what we encountered in

Buon. While rumours in Bey would revolve around new plans to redraw the map of the village

and exclude people from the land, in Buon, the few rumours that circulated tended to be about

marital infidelity or behaviour at the pagoda at festival times. In the context of Cambodia

scholarship this is in itself of interest. Many accounts of recent Cambodian history reflect refugee

experience which was dominated by displacement and trauma prior to escape to a third country.

Other accounts have, on the basis of quite limited evidence, tried to construct arguments about the

nature of „community‟ or social relations in Cambodian villages (Ovesen, Trankell, & Öjendal,

Page 186: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

168

1996). Presented with the relatively tranquil political and economic landscape of Buon, I will

therefore take the opportunity to spend a few pages setting the scene in Buon. This may provide a

little more background than is strictly necessary to contextualise and support the arguments of

this thesis but may make a modest contribution to empirical understandings of life in a

Cambodian rice field village in the 20th

and early 21st century.

The chapter thus begins by describing the village of Buon, it then describes the livelihoods of the

villagers and the factors which affect those livelihoods, and finally it describes the villagers‟

encounter with the systematic land titling programme which was implemented in the village in

late 2005 and early 2006.

6.2 Immanent Development: Lives and Livelihoods in Buon

6.2.1 Setting the Scene

6.2.1.1 Modern History of Buon

For as long as anyone can remember, Buon has stood in its current location, with the pagoda to

the north of the two ponds, Trapeang Toch to the southeast and Boeung Buon further to the south.

The oldest people in the village, who were born in the 1920s and 1930s, know that their parents

were born in the village and that there was „always‟ a pagoda there. At that time there were not

more than thirty houses in the village, and according to one account only about ten (Interview

369). These houses were in two clusters around each of the ponds. Much of the land in the village

area was forested, and the area between Trapeang Toch and the pagoda was particularly thick

with bamboo. Unlike many other parts of the country, people did not recall fearing elephants and

tigers at that time. However, packs of wild dogs were a danger to people caught on their own –

one older man recalled being having to seek refuge up a tree whilst waiting for assistance

(Interview 383), while an older woman explained that children used to be afraid of the spirits in

the forest (Interview 271).

The village was by no means isolated. The market at Chambok, which today is a 15-minute

motorcycle ride away could be reached in a couple of hours on foot, so whilst it was a journey

that had to be planned it was by no means beyond the reach of the villagers who used to both buy

and sell there (Interview 357). Today a journey to the national capital of Phnom Penh can be

achieved in little more than an hour on a fast motorbike or a couple of hours by minibus, whereas

then it took a day and a night travelling by oxcart (Interview 314). There were likewise trips to

pagodas and other sights located mainly on the hills dotted about the otherwise flat landscape.

Often these were trips by elephant. It was possible to hire elephants that were kept a few

kilometres from the village at Phnom Sroung for excursions. Each elephant had a wooden

platform and parasols, and eight or ten people could sit on one of these. The village chief‟s

mother, recalled one such trip when one of the elephants shied in fear, causing the girls on top of

it to fall off; her brother-in-law, born in the village in 1927 remembers the processions of

elephants and being scared of the creatures even though they were chained together; another

woman, born in 1938, remembered going on trips with twenty or thirty elephants to the pagoda at

Phnom Chiseav and staying there for two or three days to work with the monks (Interviews 314;

369; 357).

Page 187: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

169

When the older people were young, the abundance of nearby forest meant plenty of readily

available food: fish and frogs that could be collected from ponds and from the water in the rice

fields and abundant vegetables and fruit (Interviews 357; 369). Families had sufficient rice land,

and if a newly married couple needed more it was simply a question of clearing more from the

forest.

The forest also provided a place of refuge. Older villagers described tax officials coming to the

village to collect taxes and the villagers, on hearing of their arrival running away into the forest in

order to avoid paying any tax (Interview 383). Other tales of taking refuge had a harsher danger

associated with them, as one old woman recalled French colonial troops and Cambodian

resistance fighters going through the village looking for each other, and her sister hiding in a well

every time the resistance fighters came because of her fear of being raped (Interview 314). On the

other hand, we did not learn of any particular instances of violence by soldiers during those

earlier phases of low level war in the 1940s, and another older woman interviewed said that the

soldiers of both sides past through without event (Interview 357).

If the decades of the early and middle part of the twentieth century seem to carry somewhat of a

romantic flavour, with stories of elephant trips and tax evasion and wild dogs all told with a glint

in the eye, this changes when the events of the 1970s and 1980s are recalled. First came the

bombing of the Cambodian countryside by the Americans and by the Phnom Penh government

which they supported112

. One of our case study households have a pond in their garden which was

created by an air-dropped bomb. Another bomb at that time landed in the pagoda killing a monk

and a novice and destroying one of the buildings (Interview 290). Even this, though, pales in

comparison with what was to follow during the 1975-79 period of the Khmer Rouge rule. Shortly

after Phnom Penh was captured and evacuated in 1975, Khmer Rouge cadres, mainly boys and

young men in black uniforms, were despatched to Buon and began sorting the population into

„true‟ peasants, and “17th

April people”, the latter being people who had not supported the

revolution before its victory on 17th

April 1975. Most villagers fell into the latter category and

were sent away to a work camp called „55‟, which was in the eastern part of the province in Prei

Kabas and Angkor Borei districts. During that time of sorting the population, villagers were also

taken away quietly in the evening, three or four at a time and executed just north of the village

(Interview 290). Those who remained in the village were joined by 17th

April people from

elsewhere and worked alongside them on irrigation canals. According to one villager, there

cannot have been any point to these except to keep people busy, because they were never

connected to any water source and have never been used for irrigation either then or since.

Husband and wife in that interview recalled the weddings that the Khmer Rouge used to organise

with twenty or thirty people married in the same ceremony, forced to accept the partner given to

them by the revolution. She said that as a dark-skinned woman she was glad to have married a

lighter skinned man who would not have been a match for her otherwise, and they both smiled at

the fact that they had remained together for thirty years. But she also said that she felt sad every

time she heard wedding music and regretted that she had never had a traditional wedding herself

(Interview 365).

112

The definitive account of the United States‟ illegal bombing of Cambodia is given by William Shawcross (1979) .

The early chapters of Francois Ponchaud‟s (1978) contemporary account of the Khmer Rouge regime also contain

survivor accounts of the bombings.

Page 188: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

170

It seemed that it was not uncommon for villagers sent to „55‟ to try escape and return to the

village (Interview 290, 325). The Khmer Rouge running Buon were mainly people they knew

from other nearby villages so they were not killed, but allowed to visit briefly before being sent

away to join other work camps. Villagers‟ overall experience then, was of a mixture of rigid

control, occasional humanity as well as unpredictable brutality. One woman recalled cases of

Khmer Rouge cadre killing pregnant women and eating their foetuses, as well as eating their

victims‟ livers. When the Khmer Rouge were driven out in January 1979 there were no violent

retributions by villagers against the local Khmer Rouge. One explanation for this was that most of

them fled to the north-west of the country (Interview 383), but another interviewee said that one

of the „people who ate people‟ still lived in the area (Interview 290).

These defining experiences are remembered by a declining proportion of the population. Only

26% of the village population were born before 1970 and would therefore have had much

memory of the Khmer Rouge times113

. After 1979, peace came to Buon and the surrounding area.

So, very much in contrast with the situation in Bey where villagers were part of Khmer Rouge

raiding parties into the early 1990s, and where as late as 1994 a villager was killed by a mine in

the village area, Buon has been safe and secure for thirty years. This does not, of course, mean

that the village escaped the influences of the guerrilla war that was sustained by the Khmer

Rouge and its international supporters during the 1980s. Many of the men in the village were

conscripted into the army or to build defences in malaria forests on the Thai border. The assistant

village chief recalled how her husband returned from this work with such bad malaria that he was

unable to work for three years and she was left with the entire work of taking care of their young

children and supporting the household alone (Interview 340). Much worse was the story of the

woman, now in her seventies, whose anger and grief were still apparent as she recounted how the

partially decomposed body of the last of her four sons, (all of whom died young) was brought

back to the village, and how other villagers kept it at the pagoda for several days without telling

her because they found it so horrific (Interview 395).

According to villagers, the past ten years have seen significant changes in the appearance of the

village. Houses are larger and better constructed, there are more businesses with more goods for

sale, and people have more and newer, better motorcycles and bicycles (Interview 303).

6.2.1.2 Location

Buon is located in Bati district, Takeo province. The village is approximately half way between

the national capital Phnom Penh and Takeo provincial town. It is located between national roads

2 and 3 which both run from the capital to Takeo provincial town, and is just west of the national

railway line which transports goods from Phnom Penh to the coastal ports of Kampot and

Kampong Som. The market town of Chambok and the district offices are on National road 2, only

about 7 km from the village, and therefore accessible from the village by either cycle or

motorcycle. The commune office and the local health centre are both located a couple of

kilometres away on the road from the village to the district/market town and are therefore also

relatively accessible.

113

Village census 28 October-1 November 2006.

Page 189: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

171

6.2.1.3 Site

The village site is extremely flat. There are some trees grown on people‟s house land, and there

are small scrubby patches which are privately owned and used as sources of firewood, but

generally the landscape, within the village area and beyond, is one of flat, rice fields interrupted

only by dykes, roads and the houses built alongside them.

The main access road to the village runs from west to east. The pagoda and school are to the

north of the road, while virtually all of the houses and agricultural land in the village are found to

the south of the road. At the west of the village is a road that runs from the pagoda south towards

the next village. All of the members of the local authorities in the village (one commune council

member114

, the village chief, his deputy and their assistant) live along this north-south road at the

west of the village. Also located along this road are two restaurants, one run by the deputy village

chief and the other by another older man: both of these men had earlier experience of working at

the district headquarters and have established their businesses in recent years. At the junction of

the two roads are a couple of small shops, a generator which charges all of the village‟s batteries

and a motorcycle repair shop. Additionally, just south of the junction is the village chief‟s house,

which hosts both a motorcycle repair shop and an ice retailing outlet. Thus, to the extent that the

village has a visible economic life beyond the traditional local activities of farming and

manufacturing string, it is wholly concentrated along the main access roads, and particularly

along the road running from the entrance to the pagoda south.

Two features not common in rural Khmer villages, but present in Buon are a church and a village

community centre115

. According to the commune chief, the community centre was donated by a

national representative of the Cambodian People‟s Party, who has given the same sort of building

to every village in the commune (Interview 237). The village chief, by contrast reported that he

had to raise all the money for this construction and had not received anything for it (Interview

325). Construction of the community hall continued gradually throughout the three years that we

followed the village. Sometimes we saw painters painting Buddhist murals inside it (each with

the name of the person who donated 30 USD painted on to it). In late 2007 we met a group of

people who were in a truck who had travelled to the pagoda as part of the Bun Khaten

celebrations and also stopped off at the hall.

The village chief is a Christian and took a leading role in cooperating with Christian NGO

Assemblies of God in order to build the church (Interview 325). This is a white brick building

next to a pond which was dug when the church was built. We did not see the church in any kind

of use on any of our visits, although the household who live in front of it reported that they take

114

At the 2007 commune election he was one place too low on the party list to be able to retain his set as a councilor.

Nevertheless, he continues to go to the commune office and work every day precisely as before, but is now known as

a „commune assistant‟ rather than a commune councilor. 115

This is in contrast to the native ethnic minority villages in the northeast of the country which are typically

congregated around a central communal hall which is used for meetings, celebrations and to host guests. A Japanese-

led international development programme which I evaluated in early 2000 was implemented in parts of Takeo and

neighbouring Kampong Speu provinces. Part of their approach included the construction of „village halls‟. The

expatriate advisors had anticipated this project leading to the adoption of such constructions as rural development

policy nationwide. Whether this initiative had a role in the adoption of the idea of village community centres in

Trapeang Krasaing commune was not clear.

Page 190: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

172

care of it and that there are services for children every Saturday and for adults every Sunday

(Interview 321).

6.2.1.4 Population

At the outset of the research, Bey consisted of 64 households, which by its conclusion had

expanded to 66 households. In no cases had any household either left or joined the village.

The personal tragedies, violence and displacements that characterised much of Buon‟s modern

history are only partially reflected in the village‟s demography in the early 21st century. The

gender balance has been skewed by the disproportionate effects of conscription to military service

and the building of national defences on the male population. Only 46% of the village population

are male, with only 41% of the population over 18 in 2006 being men. On the other hand,

however, the displacements and upheavals of the late 1970s have left no lasting trace as people

seem to have returned home at the end of the Khmer Rouge period, so that the village population

retains the overwhelmingly local flavour that villagers remember from before the civil war and

genocide:

Today I live with my daughter and my nephew as my neighbours. All the families here are related.

It was the same when I was young. It was all my relatives here (Interview 357).

As of late 2006, 89% of adult villagers were born in the village. Of the 11% who were not born in

the village, the majority (7% of the total adult population) were born in nearby villages and had

married into the village. Only three households did not contain adults born in Buon.

This picture of geographical localisation could easily imply an insular or isolated rural

community, evoking the sorts of (mis-) representation of rural life that we saw characterised

development industry imaginations and descriptions in the introduction to this thesis. However,

when we come to analyse the livelihoods of the villagers, and to see where people are when they

are earning their livings, the image of unchanging isolation rapidly dissolves.

6.2.1.4 Social Organisation

Three forms of community organisation were notable in the village and are touched upon here,

namely activities centring on the pagoda, organisation by political parties and the operation of a

form of savings group called Tong Tin.

The village has gradually shifted, with houses concentrated along the roads instead of around the

ponds. With the two main roads intersecting at the pagoda gate, the pagoda has moved, more by

accident than design, from being somewhat remote from the village to being close to its centre.

On the other hand, while in the past it had often had a hundred and sometimes even up to two

hundred monks in residence (Interview 369), during the research period there were only about a

dozen monks and we rarely saw them outside the confines of the pagoda grounds.

On festival days (once every eight days) older people, mainly women dressed in immaculate

black skirts and white blouses, could be seen carrying silver containers of rice and food to the

pagoda. Other than this we observed little evidence of the pagoda‟s influence on the village.

However, villagers did report that the monks did visit the houses in the village in order to invite

them to join them on trips to other pagodas. One of our poorer case study households, for

Page 191: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

173

example, reported that they went on three or four such trips each year, when they could afford to

(Interview 303).

The pagoda was by no means a religious oasis cut off from the worldly concerns and interests of

the village. In common with our experiences in Bey, and with the reports from our team

members‟ home villages, inter-village violence had become common at festivals and religious

events at the pagoda (Interview 369). One of the land conflicts reported in the village area

involved a husband and wife in conflict with the school authorities. According to the village chief

(Interview 328), the wife was the daughter of the former chief monk at the pagoda. Her father had

given them land to build a house when he was the chief monk. Since then, the new chief monk

had come to an agreement with the education authorities that a new school could be built using

land that previously belonged to the pagoda. The couple were attempting to resist this by

claiming the land was their privately owned land, which put them in conflict with the school

principal.

Regarding political organisation, there was no visible sign of political activity by other parties

than the ruling CPP in the village. There was a FUNCINPEC activist who was known as a

member of that party and whose house was just south of that of the commune councillor on the

main north-south road in the village. As far as we could ascertain, there was no Sam Rainsy Party

activity in the village. Nevertheless, there was an awareness on the part of the authorities that the

Sam Rainsy Party constituted a threat electorally. The commune councillor reported that of the

500 people who voted in Buon and the neighouring village at the previous election, 144 votes had

been cast for the Sam Rainsy Party (Interview 374).

The CPP‟s organisation at village level appeared rather thorough and impressive. According to

the party organiser in the village (Interview 289), he had taken over the local organising since the

village chief had been ill. He had organised the CPP members in the village into 16 teams or

groups. Each group had a book where there was a passport photograph of the group leader and

each member as well as their personal details. One of the party organiser‟s responsibilities was to

check the details of all of the members against the copy of the electoral role for the 2008 election.

It was essential, he said, that the details be in perfect agreement otherwise people would not be

able to cast their votes. Given the number and the size of the groups, it seemed that virtually all of

the villagers must have been registered as CPP members116

. This would also imply that a

substantial number of registered CPP members voted for the Sam Rainsy Party on election day.

There is therefore a certain form of political competition, including particular sorts of

campaigning and resistance. Efforts are made to ensure that voters registered with CPP do not

encounter bureaucratic problems when the electoral roll is finalised. Meanwhile, opposition

supporters continue to proclaim allegiance to CPP while continuing to vote against them.

Many villagers reported that they „play‟ Tong Tin in the village. Tong Tin is a revolving savings

and credit association (ROSCA), and therefore an example of the sort of indigenous savings

group that has been brought to international attention by scholars such as Stuart Rutherford.

According to his classification, Tong Tin is a form of auction ROSCA (Rutherford, 2000, p. 37).

Tong Tin requires a leader, who guarantees all of the obligations of all members of the group. A

116

If all 16 groups had had 17 members that would have made 272 people, when the village population is only 244. I

could not check all of the books, but I infer that a large proportion of the adults were registered as party voters.

Page 192: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

174

stake is agreed, and then every month every member pays the stake to one member in the group.

So if there are thirty members, one round of Tong Tin will last thirty months. If the stake is 10

dollars, then each month one member will receive a maximum of three hundred dollars. However,

the process to decide who the recipient will be each month is an auction. The person who bids the

lowest sum of money is the recipient. Thus, if somebody is willing to accept 150 USD, each

member then only has to contribute 5 USD that month. During the first month, it is the Tong Tin

leader who is the recipient and receives the full stake. In this sense, therefore, the Tong Tin leader

always „wins‟ because she always receives the first payment and it is a full payment. However, if

any of the members fail to fulfil their obligation to make the monthly payment, the leader is

responsible for covering that and therefore risks making a significant loss.

There were several opportunities for villagers in Buon to participate in Tong Tin. One of our case

study households, the main string traders in the village, was responsible for four rounds of Tong

Tin at the beginning of 2008, whilst two of the other case study households also participated in

Tong Tin groups in other villages. In one case the group had 60 participants and therefore

represented a 5-year commitment on behalf of the leader and members (Interviews 281, 295,

298). Villagers spoke approvingly of Tong Tin as it meant that they could make a profit, and also

that they could access larger sums of money in times of need (Interviews 290, 303). While profit

levels were calibrated according to the desperation of the circumstances of people in need of

ready cash, those people were also net beneficiaries because they were obtaining money at a

better rate than if they went to a private moneylender117

. The trust that is relied upon or

institutionalised within Tong Tin is very heavily focused on the leader: it is not necessary to trust

any of the other participants provided one fully trusts the leader.

6.2.1.5 Credit

The availability of credit, and the terms on which it is available, can provide insight into the states

of both economic development and social safety nets in a community. Seventeen of the 20

Table 6-1: Outstanding debts in Buon by type of creditor (November 2006)

Type of Creditor Frequency

(n=31)

Family friends (interest-free) 16

Family & friends (charging interest) 1

Non-relatives (interest-free) 1

Non-relatives (charging interest) 10

Formal lenders (ACLEDA Rural Development Bank) 2

Private medical practitioner (interest-free) 1

Source: Field Data, Livelihood Survey, Buon Village, October 2006

117

I am grateful to Stuart Rutherford for his assistance in both referring me to the relevant parts of his own work and

explaining the benefits of the Tong Tin bidding ROSCA to me.

Page 193: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

175

households sampled during our October 2006 Livelihood Survey reported current debts. The 17

households had average total debts of 1,221,176 riels (305 USD) with the most indebted

household reporting owing 5,000,000 riels (1,250 USD) and the least indebted household

reporting a 50,000 riels (12.50 USD) debt. Just under half of the debts were to fellow residents of

Buon (see Table 6-1). Creditors for the 31 outstanding loans were reported as follows:

Thus there was both formal and informal credit available and, despite the fact that almost all of

the informal credit was reported at monthly rates of 10% or more, and formal credit at reported

monthly rates of 3% and 4% far more people had accessed informal credit. The fact that such a

large proportion of the loans were interest-free loans from friends and relatives indicates the

extent to which informal social (or at least kinship) safety nets operated in the village.

Furthermore, it is not certain that the 10% interest rates should be judged in isolation from default

rates. Certainly, in one case one of the wealthier households in the village had loaned money to

one of the poorer households, but when they had failed to repay the debt had been written off

rather than enforced (Interview 336)

The reasons given for indebtedness and their frequency are set out in Table 6-2 below:

Table 6-2: Reasons given for indebtedness in Buon (November 2006)

Reason given for acquiring debt Frequency (n=31)

Illness 19

Buy food 3

House construction 2

Motorcycle purchase 2

Buy land 1

„Investment and festivals‟ 1

Repay other debts 1

Agricultural investment 1

Cycle repair 1

Source: Field Data, Livelihood Survey 2006

6.2.1.6 Village leadership and safety nets for the poorest

The village chief and his two deputies were all related to the elderly couple who lived in the

centre of the village. Most people in the west and centre of the village were related to this pair.

However, in the east of the village, the families who traditionally lived around the second

reservoir in the village formed a separate network. The members of the kinship network of the

village chief and his relatives were generally wealthier. It seemed that the local authorities used

their position in order to ensure that poorer households gained access to supplementary incomes.

According to the Deputy Village Chief (Interview 286), there were five households who received

Page 194: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

176

extra food from the „government‟ and another four who received extra food every month from an

NGO that helps people who were living with HIV AIDS. There seemed to be general agreement

in the village about who the very poorest households in the village were, and general knowledge

and approval of the village chief‟s (mis-) appropriation of HIV AIDS funding to assist them

(Interviews 305; 306; 336)118

.

6.2.2 How villagers from Buon make a living

6.2.2.1 Overview

One of the most striking findings from the Village Census conducted at the outset of our research

was that 69 people, or 35%, of the adult population of the village were living away from their

homes in Phnom Penh. Principally these were young, mainly single women working in garment

factories (typically returning for one night a month after they are paid) young, single men

working on construction sites (who are more flexibly employed and may come home more or less

frequently but usually for longer periods), as well as older men working as motorcycle taxi

drivers in the city119

.

Table 6-3: Main Reported Source of Income in Buon, 2007

Activity (PNP = located in Phnom Penh) Number of households

Garment Factory remittances (PNP) 20

String production and trading 10

Retail trading 8

Construction remittances (PNP) 7

Motorcycle taxi (PNP) 6

Other (PNP) 4

Pig Raising 3

Hiring out labour locally 2

Milling and Trading Rice 2

Motorcycle repair 1

Handicrafts 1

Total 64

Source: Field Data, Livelihood Survey, January 2008

118

There is undoubtedly more to this story. It is difficult to believe that any organization is giving out support on the

basis of word of mouth reports by local authorities that villagers are living with HIV, though one could imagine field

workers taking license to use funds to help poorer families. However, we did not follow this up, and for our purposes

the interesting point to note was the authorities sympathetic use of resources (compared to many other places I have

stayed where there has been bad feeling about local authorities channeling resources away from the poorest and

towards their own relatives and friends). 119

The way in which men‟s engagements with the broader economy gave them more freedom, whilst women were

often engaged in employment in ways which involved their time and their movements being extremely restricted was

a theme throughout our research in Buon.

Page 195: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

177

As explained in Chapter 2, obtaining reliable economic data on household incomes and

expenditures was a challenge throughout, however, in the course of the project we built up a clear

picture of overall participation in different economic activities, their relative importance, and to

some extent the incomes that they generated. In September 2007 we found that there were just 17

out of the village‟s 64 households who did not have any members working in Phnom Penh and

sending money home to the village. As we will see, this was often explained by either households

being unusually wealthy, or by them not having available labour.

In our Livelihood Survey, conducted at the beginning of 2008, 37 of the 64 households reported

remittances from Phnom Penh as their major source of income (see Table 6-3). Small businesses

of different sorts were the main income source for 11 households (mainly retail outlets in the

village but also rice milling and motorcycle repairs), whilst 10 households reported string as their

main income source. To the extent that agriculture was a major source of income for households,

this was as a result of either pig raising and trading (3 households) or milling and trading of rice

(2 households). Arable farming was not the major income for any household in the village.

The most thorough information we obtained on income sources was from the Incomes and

Expenditure Questionnaire (though still of limited reliability, see Appendix 4) administered to our

eight case study households in the village in March 2007 (see Table 6-4). This again showed the

importance of incomes from Phnom Penh and the insignificance of incomes from arable

farming120

, although it did indicate that small livestock (pigs and chickens) were an income

stream for all households.

Table 6-4: Breakdown of Buon Case Study Household (HH) incomes April 2006-March 2007

HH

*121

Reported

income

(riels)

PNP

remittances

Own

business

String Arable

farming

Livestock Loans

and

gifts

Other122

16** 4,425,000 49% 4% 46%

21*** 4,300,000 70% 7% 23%

07** 3,650,000 99% 1%

09*** 3,476,000 83% 17%

46** 3,441,000 17% 70% 2%

52* 2,130,000 33% 8% 47% 12%

55* 1,940.000 31% 5% 5% 41% 18%

22** 540,000 37% 26% 18% 19%

Source: Field Data, Income and Expenditure Questionnaire, March 2007

120

Given that arable production is partly for domestic consumption, it could have an importance beyond the income

it generates, a point to which we will return later in the chapter. 121

Household number, with asterisks indicating the wealth rank ascribed to the household by the village chief and

commune councilor (Interview 289): ***= „medium‟; **‟poor‟; *= „very poor‟. On the basis of my knowledge of the

households and also their reported expenditures, I would judge that both HH21 and HH22 have underreported their

incomes by at least 50%. 122

Households 55 and 22, other = fishing; Household 52 other = daily wage labour

Page 196: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

178

The two households that were exceptions and did not have incomes from Phnom Penh were

illustrative. One was almost certainly the wealthiest in the village. The husband, who was also

deputy village chief, worked as a motorcycle taxi driver during the 1990s and used the income

from that to invest in a small soup restaurant specialising in dog meat (and euphemistically

referred to by villagers as „special soup‟). They reported that most of their customers were people

who have earned money in Phnom Penh and want to come for a drink and to relax. The husband

also hired out his services as a cook which generated as much income (though in lumpier, less

predictable sums) as the restaurant and karaoke business at home. They had adult children,

including two who had jobs in Phnom Penh, one working for a security company at the national

airport and another working for an NGO. The wife made a point of saying that they would never

take money from their children to support themselves, but rather that they would be ready to

support their children (Interview 290).

The other exception, by contrast, was one of the poorer households in the village, consisting of a

husband, wife and four school-age children. Their household economy had been constrained by a

motorcycle accident. The husband had been transporting a drunken man and a pig to a wedding

several years previously, when the pig tried to wriggle away from the passenger and their struggle

caused the motorcycle to crash. The husband broke his leg very badly. The hospital had been

unable to re-set it satisfactorily and it was only properly set after a month spent at a traditional

Khmer healer (Interview 300). However, the leg remained weak. When we met him he still could

not do hard labour, or even ride a motorcycle except for short journeys and without heavy loads.

As a result the household is very much dependent on income from string production: in the late

afternoon the whole household - parents and children - were often to be found tearing up nylon

sacks and spinning the threads into string. Had he not been injured he would have worked in

Phnom Penh on construction sites or as a motorcycle taxi. When the children are a little older, it

is anticipated that they will get factory jobs there. In fact, husband and wife said that they would

already like their oldest daughter who is in year 8 at school to get such a job. However, they said

that she had so far refused saying that she enjoyed school and wanted to complete her education

and become a teacher or a doctor (Interview 301). In other words, the one household had no

Phnom Penh incomes because they were exceptionally wealthy (by village standards) and did not

need them, and the other did not have Phnom Penh incomes because at that point in the family

lifecycle they did not have available labour for that.

The overall picture then from our field data (especially the Village Census in 2006, the

Livelihood Survey of all households in the village in 2008, and the detailed Income and

Expenditure Questionnaire to the case study households in 2007) was that for most households,

for most of the time, earnings from Phnom Penh were the most important income stream. A

number of better-off households have small businesses which are their main sources of incomes,

and in some cases obviated the need for their young adult children to work in Phnom Penh.

Meanwhile string manufacture, animal raising and rice farming were supplementary activities

whose significance varied. In order to identify overall factors influencing livelihood opportunities

for villagers (which constitute the „immanent development‟ settings that any „intentional

development‟ intervention would be required to engage with in order to make a difference) we

will pause to consider some of the economic activities in the village in a little more detail.

Page 197: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

179

6.2.2.2 Work in Phnom Penh

As recently as the late 1960s, rice farming, gathering food from the local area, and making and

trading string were the main sources of income for the village: according to the village chief, at

that time chief there were only two people in the village in those days who worked in Phnom

Penh, both as cyclo-drivers (Interview 326). This had changed in the course of the 1990s as

opportunities arose, initially it was men who went there to work as motor-taxi drivers, and in

construction, but with the growth of the garment factories, it was young women who became the

largest segment of the village‟s migrant labour force. By the time of the Village Census at the

outset of our research in late 2006 32 young women (or 13% of the village‟s adult population)

were working in a garment factory, whilst 16 men were working on construction sites and a

further 9 were working as motorcycle taxis.

Another of our case study households demonstrates how just one daughter at the right age to go

into the garment factories could support a household‟s economy. One of our case study

households in Buon consisted of a husband and wife in their late 40s, two school-aged children

and a daughter, who was born in 1982. Of their reported income in the year to March 2007, 83%

came from salary brought home from a garment factory by the daughter. Until mid-2007 she had

been working nights and earning as much as 120 USD per month. At that point, however, she

decided that the work was too much and took a new job where she worked days and earned about

60 USD per month. By this time, the household had a large new wooden house purchased with

her earnings, and – for example, between the team‟s visits in March and September 2007 she had

bought a fourteen inch colour television for 500 000 riels (125 US dollars), a vehicle battery for

180 000 riels (45 USD) and a new water jar for 20 000 riels (5 USD) for the household. By the

end of the research she was married and her parents were receiving about 5 US dollars per month

from her instead of the 50 – 60 US dollars that she had previously sent home, although they still

seemed able to count on her for support as she had paid part of the costs of the latrine they were

building and had also bought an ox123

. Whilst her earnings had been exceptionally high (twice the

normal when she was working nights), she was only one person. During the Livelihood Survey at

the beginning of 2008 (see Table 6-5), 97 adults were reported to have worked in Phnom Penh in

the previous year, with one household having as many as 7 of its members having worked there.

Table 6-5: Number of Buon Household (HH) Members Working in Phnom Penh in 2007

#HH members in PNP 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Total

#HH in that category 17 17 24 4 2 1 0 1 64

# individuals in PNP 0 17 48 12 8 5 0 7 97

Source: Field Data, Livelihood Survey, Buon village, January 2008.

123

Around the time his daughter got married, her father had started selling ice cream. He would set out on his

bicycle early in the morning, with ice cream in a cool box cooled with ice. The stock would only last the day, so if he

did not sell enough during the day he would lose money. On days when he sold out he could earn the equivalent of 4

USD in a day. But there were days when he did not sell out, and he had stopped selling for a time because he kept

failing to sell out. The household income was therefore considerably less secure than it had been the previous years.

Page 198: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

180

At the individual level, the structure of opportunity for men and women is quite different.

Amongst the younger generation, most of the young women who work in Phnom Penh have jobs

in factories. Here they have an extremely regimented lifestyle, with long working hours and little

or no choice as to when they come home to the village. Meanwhile, the rhythms of the factory are

beginning to pulse into the rhythms of the supposedly rural village. The girls usually get paid on

the tenth day of each month returning en masse to the village to visit their homes for a day and to

pass on money to their families. This triggers the repayment of debt to the rice surplus

households (mainly the two households owning rice milling machines) by the households with a

rice deficit (Interview 342). There is an element of choice for the young women with regard to

where they work, but the choice is between different factories which each provide the same

overall pattern of work-dominated lifestyle.

Young men, meanwhile, are generally employed in the construction industry. Work is far more

irregular. Clearly, this provides opportunity them to exercise the freedom to behave in the way

that they wish. A vicious circle was therefore operating in terms of the gender differentiation in

lifestyle and work: the same social conditioning that reserves work in garment factories for

diligent, obedient young women, also allows the less reliable and trustworthy young men to live a

far more self-indulgent lifestyle away from the village.

Generally, although interviewees tended to say that it was „difficult‟ to get jobs in Phnom Penh,

the evidence seemed to contradict this for the period of our research. One young woman reported

that the factory where she had worked had demanded entry fees from girls who were not

qualified. However, she simply got some private tuition in sewing for a few hours and was then

able to return to the factory and pass their tests and therefore be considered „qualified‟ without

needing to pay the fee (Interview 378). During our time in the village we did not encounter any

young women who were willing and able to work in Phnom Penh, but had not been able to so.

The same applies to men working in the construction industry or as motorcycle drivers. There

were instances of factories laying workers off temporarily, and while construction work also

includes fluctuations – if a young man is attached to a particular gang or foreman, and the

foreman takes a few weeks off to go to his home village, or if the young man is looking for a new

gang or a new project. Thus it is not the case that every person has paid work every week.

Nevertheless, the larger picture was of work being available and Buon villagers not encountering

any major entry barriers to employment. On the other hand, on our sixth and final visit in early

2009, whilst we did not collect systematic information on employment at that time, we did hear

of far more cases of factories closing and also of construction sites shutting down with projects

not completed.

Clearly then, the globalised garment industry in particular, and the terms of Cambodia‟s

acceptance into it, as well as the general world and regional economic booms have created the

employment opportunities for Buon‟s relative prosperity in the decade up to and including our

research period. The garment industry in Cambodia is under constant threat. Quota agreements

have protected the Cambodian industry from direct competition with China and Vietnam, and a

booming world economy has ensured that overall demand had been healthy. There is no certainty

that these conditions will continue. A downturn in the global and regional economies would

stiffen competition for jobs in Phnom Penh, possibly leading to the erection of the sort of entry

barriers that currently seem to be absent, and very possibly also forcing many of the Buon

villagers to either return to the village, or to attempt to survive elsewhere.

Page 199: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

181

There is a clear difference here between the changes in Bey and the changes in Buon. In Bey the

economic changes that transform the physical landscape are also transforming livelihood

opportunities. Economic change is about competition for land and land-based resources, and its

effects are inscribed on the landscape. In Buon, on the other hand, economic change has been de-

coupled from the landscape. This tallies with what has been observed in studies of livelihoods

that have found deagrarianisation elsewhere in Southeast Asia (Rigg, 2006), and is of course in

direct contradiction with the tendencies in development discourse established in the introduction

to this thesis, which stubbornly adhere to notions of rural as „traditional‟ and „isolated‟ and

„primitive‟.

6.2.2.3 Small Businesses in the Village

Notwithstanding the dominance of Phnom Penh incomes in the local economy overall, it is also

notable that almost all of the better off households in the village have their own local businesses.

These included two restaurant businesses, a wedding business (providing photography, furniture,

music), the retailing of ice, motorcycle repair, cycle workshop as well as the standard small

businesses found in just about all rural Cambodian villages, namely vehicle battery charging and

rice milling.

In some rare cases, these households have become so well off that their children have not needed

to go to Phnom Penh to work. In addition to the deputy village chief‟s household mentioned

above, the assistant village chief and her husband who have a rice mill and also trade rice and

provide credit to other villagers, were able to send their two oldest daughters away for two years

to get educated as a veterinarian and a midwife respectively. These both promise relatively secure

incomes, but required substantial fees, in the region of 1500 USD each, to be paid to middlemen

and overall was reckoned to have cost the household in the region of 6000 USD in total for the

two years of education for the two young women (Interview 346).

In both of these cases, the men in the households had spent time in the 1990s working as

motorcycle taxi drivers in Phnom Penh. It is tempting to see a link between the acquisition of

capital from Phnom Penh incomes and the establishment of small businesses in the village. This

would apply to some extent in the case of the assistant village chief‟s household, as they needed

to save money to buy the generator and most of this came from his motorcycle taxi earnings and

from her success in raising pigs at a time when the price of pork was high (Interview 343).

However, in the case of other businesses such as the restaurants the need for capital was not great,

and the decisive role played by Phnom Penh incomes was not in providing start-up capital, but in

generating demand. The deputy village chief said that most of his restaurant customers were

youngsters and that he did not know how the village would survive without Phnom Penh

incomes. He illustrated this by pointing out the poverty of families that could only rely on string

and rice farming for incomes (Interview 286).

The other factor which the households with businesses had was that they were located along one

of the two roads that go through the village. Thus, the relocation of the village over the past thirty

years from the banks of the two ponds to the roads, has mirrored its economic reorientation

towards outside markets and incomes. The elite of the village, both the business people and all of

the members of the local authorities, including all of the better off households, now have houses

along the roads.

Page 200: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

182

6.2.2.4 Making and Trading String/Rope Tethers

Buon lies in the poorer, western part of Bati district. The district chief, who grew up in the

province, explained the spatial distribution of handicrafts in explicitly geographically determinist

terms – without using that language (Interview 234). He believed that because the soils in the

eastern part of the district were better, the populations there had always been wealthier and have

therefore had more money to spend on education. As a result they had the capacity to engage in

more highly skilled and profitable work, hence the proliferation of looms and the weaving of

relatively expensive silk sarongs in the eastern part of the district. In the western part of the

district, however, the soils are poorer, and therefore over time human resources have also been

poorer and therefore the villagers work on the simpler task of spinning bark into rope and making

tethers out of it. It is in this western part of the district that the village of Buon is located.

The tradition in Buon has been to make string from either the bark or from strips of leaf from

coconut palm (Interview 295; 326). There is one older lady with failing eyesight who still uses

this method. In recent times the materials for the string have changed. From about 2003 people

started to use old damaged fertiliser bags which would be torn into strips and weaved into thin

string, which is in turn plaited into the three-ply strings that are used to make the tethers for the

animals. As recently as 2005, families have started to buy nylon string from the market to use as a

raw material instead (Interview 353). The nylon is much stronger, but this is not necessarily

regarded as an advantage: if an animal becomes very violent and determined to escape from

where it is being tied or held, it is better for the string to break than animal to damage itself in the

struggle. On the other hand, the nylon rope is easier for households where there is possibly just

one or two adults involved in the manufacture of the string (Interview 349). Where nylon bags are

used, the whole family, including small children, typically becomes involved in tearing up the

nylon bags into thin strips and then in feeding them onto the string in the evenings as pieces of

string stretching over 100 or more meters are spun on bicycle wheels in the evenings.

At any time of the year and at any time of the day wandering around the village one finds people

working at making string. While for some households this is a supplementary activity carried out

when other work has been done, for others it can be a near full-time activity (Interview 349).

Profit margins from string manufacture are however small, and at different times during the

research people had abandoned it as an activity either because the price of old fertiliser sacks had

increased (Interview 283) or because there were insufficient buyers (Interview 333). Overall, the

households who could make significant profit from string were the ones who were involved in

trading it. This applied especially to the case study household which purchased the sacks from

factories in Phnom Penh and brought them to the village, and which got 70% of its income from

string manufacture and trade in 2006 (Income and Expenditure Questionnaire, March 2007). For

other households, participation in the trading of string meant collecting string made at home or

made by other households who could not travel, and then setting off on a bicycle tour for several

days, often going to other provinces, staying at people‟s houses along the way and selling string

direct to villagers with cattle. The ten households who reported that string was their main source

of income were largely households who were able to engage in such trading. In the wealth

ranking exercise seven of these households were adjudged „very poor‟, three of them „poor‟ and

none of them in the „better off‟ category.

Page 201: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

183

Highly labour-intensive, somewhat vulnerable to market fluctuations and not particularly

profitable, the production of string is an emblem of poverty (and of the poverty of options for

many households) rather than a way out of it. We did not learn of any way in which engaging in

string manufacture and sales might be a route to a better standard of living.

6.2.2.5 Rice Farming

Rice farming is still an important part of the landscape of Buon and of the lifestyle of almost all

households. As at January 2008 there was only one household that did not report owning some

rice land. However, the landholdings are small, with most families owning less than a hectare

(see Table 6-6 and Table 6-7). Yields are likewise low, with only five to ten households a year

likely to harvest enough rice to meet their household consumption needs for the year.

Table 6-6: Land holdings by Household in Buon January 2008 (n=64)

Land holding (Ha) 0 0-0.5 0.5-1 1-1.5 1.5-2 2-2.5 0-2.5

#Households 1 17 22 13 7 4 64

Source: Field data, Land and Livelihood Questionnaire, administered 15-18 January 2008

Table 6-7: Reported Yields by Household in Buon 2007 Growing Season (n=62)

Yield (tonnes) 0 0-0.5 0.5-1 1-1.5 1.5-2 2-2.5 0-2.5

#Households 2 10 23 18 6 3 62

Source: Field data, Land and Livelihood Questionnaire, administered 15-18 January 2008

In an interview with Sann, a successful farmer and trusted informant, we elicited figures for a

„typical‟ hectare of rice land in Buon. According to his calculations a hectare might produce 1.5

tonnes of neang minh124

unmilled rice, which would sell at 500-600 riels per kilogramme, giving

a total value of 185-225 USD125

. The cost of inputs, excluding labour was estimated at 40 USD.

However, if labour costs were included for transplanting, harvesting and transporting from the

field126

, the cost of production would have increased by 100 USD (or half the value of the crop)

to 140 USD. The significance of labour costs led Sann and others to conclude that rice farming

was only profitable if the household used its own labour. This was not fully supported by his own

figures (which suggested a profit of 60 USD if labour was hired, but this does not include the

checking and weeding of the crops). Detailed information from interviews with Case Study

households suggested that Sann‟s figures were broadly representative (see Table 6-8);

124

The other rice variety popular in the village was „ka maly‘ which was more valuable, with unmilled rice selling at

800-900 riels per kg, and tasted better, but which generated lower yields and was therefore less widely grown than

neang minh (Interview 297). 125

The use of cash values is not to imply that rice is a cash crop. As we have seen, for most households, most of the

crop is consumed within the household, either by the family or by livestock. 126

There are other substantial labour inputs especially relating to weeding the crop and bringing the grass back from

the field to feed oxen. However, this is not typically something for which labour is hired. Children often make a

major contribution to this part of the household work.

Page 202: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

184

interestingly the one case where a household made a loss they ascribed it to family illness which

meant that they were forced to hire labour rather than work themselves.

Table 6-8: Rice Production in Buon village, Cambodia. 2006 and 2008.

HH Interview

number

Ha Costs (riels) Yield (riels)

(kg if

available)

Profit/Loss

(riels and USD

equivalent)

Note

7 273 1.24 400 000 650 000

(1,300kg)

250 000

62.50 USD

2008

Rice for 9 months

7 270 1.24 804 000

(500 000 labour

hire included)

780 000 - 24 000

- 8 USD

2006

Illness meant that labour

had to be hired.

9 276,

277

0.7 250 000 508 000 258 000

64.50 USD

2008

16 281 0.8 394 000 910 000

(1820 kg)

516 000

129 USD

2006

21

287 1.0 175 000 455 000 280 000

70 USD

2006

22 291 0.12 100 000 150 000 50 000

12.50 USD

Household has more

land but this the only

plot for which clear

information could be

provided on inputs.

46

295 0.8 150 000 240 000

(480 kg)

90 000

22.50 USD

2006

52

302 1.1 160 000 240 000

(480 kg)

80 000

20 USD

2006

55

309 0.5 30 000 180 000

(200 kg)

150 000

37.50 USD

2008

On rented land. Size

may not be accurate.

Source: Field Data, Interviews with Case Study Households 2006-2009

Overall then, the experiences of case study households in Buon during the study period,

suggested that, even discounting the cost of labour, rice farming only had the potential to generate

the equivalent of about 140 USD per hectare per annum. This was in the context of most

households owning less than a hectare of rice land. Set in comparison with households receiving

thirty or forty dollars per month from each young woman bringing home unspent wages from

garment factories, this is not a mainstay of the village economy.

Generally, Sann‟s own household was the only one that could confidently predict having a

tradable rice surplus every year (Interview 342), with up to about ten other households possibly

growing enough to cover their own rice consumption needs (which are of course only a portion of

household food needs, which are in turn only a portion of household expenditures). This was

supported by the Land and Livelihood Questionnaire administered in January 2008 where only 5

Page 203: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

185

households reported any income from selling rice, and of these none of them reported it as their

main source of income. It was also confirmed by interviews where villagers reported that their

crop would usually enable them to meet their household rice needs for 6-9 months of the year

(e.g.Interviews 273; 301; 303; 309; 349; 353; 292).

Our findings clearly show that Buon, despite external appearances to the contrary, is not,

economically at least, primarily a rice farming village. There is also evidence that the importance

of rice farming is gradually declining, with the culture of the village beginning to adjust to its

new economic realities. The rice fields of Buon border directly onto the rice-fields of

neighbouring villages so there is little prospect of an increase in available rice land. Neither,

given the lack of any obvious water source does there seem to be the prospect of the sort of

infrastructural development that would be required to transform the rice economy by introducing

irrigation schemes enabling farmers to move away from the high-risk, low yield limitations of

rain-fed agriculture to the relatively high-input, high yield and high profits of irrigated

production. In these circumstances, successful households no more want their children to be rice

farmers than they want them to work in garment factories. Sann‟s household eventually had to

hire some labour during transplanting because their daughters had been away studying. Now they

are both back and working in animal health and public health services respectively These two

young women who have grown up working on the farm and going to school will no longer be

farmers, and their salaries and other associated incomes will now represent a substantial portion

of the household‟s income.

But it is not only in the wealthiest households that changes could be seen. As noted previously, it

had been rare for anyone not from the local area to marry into the village. However, this was

beginning to change. Heng Sothavy met her husband in Phnom Penh when she was there selling

fruit and he, a native of Battambang in north-west Cambodia, was working as a driver for an

Australian company. Om Srei‟s son-in-law was a motor cycle driver in Phnom Penh when he met

her daughter who was then working in a garment factory. Neither man is from an agricultural

background. Sothavy and Om Srei describe these new members to their families as „not able to

plough‟ (Interviews 393; 396). This is both a cultural marker – such men have not previously

existed in the village – changing what it means to be a villager in Buon, but also a practical

obstacle to farming in those households. If they are to farm their land it will involve hiring

someone else to plough it: with timing of ploughing often crucial and rains unpredictable this can

be a time-consuming and uncertain arrangement. Many households without draft animals or adult

male labour manage to plough their lands, however, it becomes less and less self-evident that a

household will farm the land if it does not have the labour to do so (especially given the

observations of villagers about profitability depending on not requiring to hire in labour).

A technical revolution in rice farming might, of course, alter these trends, particularly if it were to

be able to treble or quadruple yields. In September 2007 the deputy village chief was enthusing

about new methods of rice farming that he has learned at an extension centre at nearby Tram

Kok. It involved less labour and less seeds as individual rice plants were transplanted rather than

several together. He reported that this was the second year that he had used this method and he

anticipated that it would become widespread. By early 2008 he was reporting that two other

households had experimented with this technology on small trial plots in their fields. In late 2008

we sat in the village and watched the Minister of Agriculture proclaim that this new way of

transplanting would indeed enable revolutionary increases in yields. However, in the village the

Page 204: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

186

initial enthusiasm gave way to a reversion to traditional methods as it became apparent that

controlling weeds was a far greater challenge with the new method. In absence of some such

technological revolution rice farming will continue to dominate the physical appearance of the

landscape, and no doubt the culture and identity of most of the villagers for some time to come,

but it will also continue to be of marginal importance in the household economies of the villagers.

6.2.3 Conclusions: Immanent Development and Livelihoods in Buon

After the relative poverty of the 1980s and early 1990s, Buon has subsequently become a village

where the most important economic activities take place elsewhere, with activities at home,

whether the manufacturing of string or rope tethers or the farming of rice, acting as supplements

to the main forms of income which tend to come directly or indirectly (in the case of the

flourishing restaurant, wedding, money lending etc businesses) from employment in Phnom

Penh. Economic change has long since been divorced from changes in the landscape in the

village. During the decade up to and including the research there had been abundant employment

opportunities available in Phnom Penh for villagers who were able and willing to take those

opportunities: the terms of incorporation were heavily biased against young women in many

respects, but the overall economic impacts for the village were positive127

. As such, the village‟s

experiences reflect the trends noted regionally towards a delocalising of livelihoods and their

decoupling of livelihoods from land and agriculture (Rigg, 2001, 2006). On the other hand, the

village has, in contrast with some of the Thai experience mentioned in chapter 2, not become part

of a „manufacturing frontier‟, but has rather retained the characteristics of a labour reserve (Rigg

et al., 2010, pp. 146-148)

The fieldwork for this thesis was completed in March 2009. By the end of that year Cambodia

had experienced its first year of negative growth since the signing of the new constitution in

1993. This has impacted upon the economic activities upon which Buon‟s economy depends:

11.4% of the jobs in Cambodian garment factories were lost in 2009, and for workers remaining

in the industry, income levels fell by 20% because of reduced overtime (IMF, 2009, p. 9). There

is little in the experiences of Buon during the study period that suggests that local resources could

be mobilised in order to provide an adequate safety net if economic opportunity in Phnom Penh

was drastically curtailed. The village might be able to re-absorb its migrant working population,

but circumstances would be extremely impoverished in comparison with the previous decade.

6.3 The Systematic Land Titling Intervention in Buon

6.2.4 Introduction

Systematic land titling, a component of Cambodia‟s Land Management and Administration

Project (LMAP) was initiated in the commune of Bati district where Buon is located with a public

meeting on 3 November 2005. Buon was one of the last villages to complete the process shortly

before the current research began. By the time we completed our research, therefore, villagers had

127

I also gathered information on the terms of incorporation into marriage amongst older households in the village,

and here again there was a bias against women. Five out of eight of the case study households had experienced cases

of marital infidelity, inevitably involving men leaving the household, often taking money with them, and leaving

their wives with more work and far fewer resources. Garment factory exploitation of female labour is therefore in

some ways a new form of exploitation, but could also be seen as reworking of pre-existing injustices against women.

Page 205: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

187

had their titles for about three years. As we have seen in chapter 4, the LMAP systematic land

titling aims to improve tenure security by providing formal legal title to all land-owners.

The project appraisal document (PAD) for the World Bank loan of 24.3 million USD to LMAP

outlined the development objectives and outcome/impact indicators (see Table 6-9) and the

outputs and indicators(see Table 6-10) which are broadly typical for such programmes (World

Bank, 2002, p. 27).

Table 6-9: LMAP Project Development Objective and Outcome/Impact Indicators

Project Development Objective Outcome/Impact Indicators

Land tenure security for urban and

agricultural land holders improved

Conflict over land falls

Land grabbing falls

Agriculture productivity rises

Access to (cheaper) credit increases

Investment in the property sector increases

Land markets operate more

efficiently

Number of land transactions increases

Taxes and Fees collected from land transactions

increase

Source: (World Bank, 2002)

The outputs and indicators for the land titling programme were as follows: This is achieved

„systematically‟ in the sense that titles are prepared and issued to a whole community at the same

time. In common with other similar programmes, the aim is to build on local knowledge in order

to formalise existing informal arrangements in order to create a fair formal system. Villages are

first surveyed with volunteers from the community being involved in that work, this initial survey

results in a provisional map where plots are assigned to owners. The map is then posted in a

public place and villagers are given thirty days to appeal the allocation. Titles are prepared and

issued for all land where there are no competing claims (on payment of a small administrative fee

which is charged per square meter according to whether land is house or agricultural land).

Where ownership is contested, the plots are then referred to a series of committees whose aim is

to settle the conflict as quickly as possible without need to refer to a higher level committee or,

ultimately, the courts.

Villagers‟ experience of titling will be reviewed in the light of these expected benefits. First, we

will consider inclusion/exclusion in/from titling, then the impacts on tenure security and

investment, credit, the land market and social costs of land conflicts will be reviewed. These

findings in Buon will then be set in the context of existing and subsequent research on the

impacts of LMAP titling elsewhere in rural Cambodia.

Page 206: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

188

Table 6-10: LMAP Systematic Land Titling Component: Outputs and Indicators.

Outputs Indicators

Titles are issued

effectively and

efficiently

Map shop is fully operational

One million titles issued under the systematic titling program

95 percent of titles collected by beneficiaries

Average cost of issuing title is less than USD 30 per title.

Issuance of titles through sporadic adjudication takes less than 2 months

from start to finish.

Land registration

system functioning

well

Provincial and district land offices are built

75 percent of land transactions are registered

Registration of land transaction in Phnom Penh is completed in one day

by year 4 of the project.

Computerized land registration database system is operational in Phnom

Penh Land Office and access to information in the registry is available

online to government, financial institutions and individuals for a charge.

Source: (World Bank, 2002, p. 27)

6.2.5 Titling in Buon: Inclusion and Exclusion from the Process

Overall, the titling process in Buon proceeded as envisaged. Two villagers accompanied the

survey teams in the initial survey of the land: the deputy village chief taking responsibility for the

northern portion and another villager the southern portion of the village (Interview 289). The map

that was produced was posted at the pagoda for thirty days. Titles were issued and the fees

charged were in accordance with the modest scales issued by the Ministry. During our interviews,

when we asked to look at people‟s land titles they were almost invariably produced from a plastic

wallet, usually from under on one of the beams just over our head as we sat under the house. The

exceptions were the rare cases where either somebody had a locked box with their documents or

where the title had been provided as collateral for a loan or surrendered when the land was

pawned. The titles were on good quality paper, were clearly printed and included a map which

showed the adjacent plots (Figure 6-1 and Figure 6-2128

). The only two concerns about the papers

which arose during the research were firstly the difficulties villagers had in identifying which title

related to which of their plots (it was difficult, though, to see how the titles could have been made

clearer), and the fact that one part of the form, which required that land be classified as either

128

These photographs have been altered in order to obscure the names of the village and the commune. The title

relates to a plot belonging to a Buon villager but located in another village.

Page 207: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

189

agricultural or housing land was left blank (see Figure 6-1) an omission which appeared to create

the possibility of mischievous challenges to the validity or completeness of the title129

.

Of the 365 plots of land in the village, there were 17 for which title had not been issued. Three of

these non-issued titles were for land titled as public land, one school and two wells. Of the

remaining 362 private plots, there were only 14 (or just under 4%) for which titles had not been

issued. Seven of these related to plots that were subject to ownership conflicts. These will be

discussed fully in the section on impact of titling on the social costs of conflict below. In the

context of the general inclusiveness of the process, however, it may be noted that the design of

LMAP, showed an improvement on earlier cases in the literature where a conflict over one plot

could delay issuance of title for landowners throughout an adjudication area130

(Hendrix &

Rockcliffe, 1998).

The cases where title had not been issued were discussed both with provincial and district

officials at the provincial land department office (Interview 232), and also with the households

who did not receive title.

Of the seven remaining plots to which title had not been issued, four related to plots for which

cadastral officials reported that all the paperwork had been complete and the titles had been ready

for collection, but that the households had not collected their titles on any of the occasions when

they had come to the village for that purpose. The four plots were owned two each by two

different couples. One of these couples did not live in the village, again raising the possibility that

the systematic titling process is unintentionally biased against non-local land owners. The other

couple were husband Sophal and wife, Navy, well-known to us as they were one of our case

study households. They reported that they did not know why they had not been issued with title.

However, we knew that Sophal was often away in Phnom Penh working on construction sites.

During those times Navy often took their small child to her mother in the next village, so it seems

fair to speculate that she may have been absent from the village on each of the occasions when

the titles had been distributed. Alternatively, as the officials mentioned, the household might have

been short of cash and decided they did not want to pay the fee at that time.

Of the other three cases of non-issued land, one related to a plot owned by the deputy village

chief and his wife: probably the most wealth and well-connected couple in the village. In this case

cadastral officials reported that he had earlier sought and received a sporadic title to his land, and

that unless he returned that title he could not receive a new one. The deputy village chief, on the

other hand, reported that he had applied for a sporadic title but never been issued one. This he

said was simply a ruse and an example of corruption:

―They want money from us. It isn‘t about anything else. They want two or three hundred dollars,

but they are not getting it from me‖ (Interview 288, Author‘s translation).

Clearly angry (at the same time as saying that he was not angry and did not care), he said that he

had lived on this land since 1979 and before that, and nobody was ever going to try and throw

him off it, so a title really did not matter. If they did not want to give him one he was not going to

129

The Deputy Provincial Land Department chief ascribed this to a lack of legal direction on how to classify urban

and non-urban land (Interview 190) 130

As noted, for example, by Hendrix and Rockcliffe (1998) in the case of Guyana.

Page 208: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

190

Figure 6-1: Land Title in Buon, Photographed 2008. Front. (Photograph: Robin Biddulph)

Page 209: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

191

Figure 6-2: Land Title in Buon,. Photographed 2008. Reverse. (Photograph: Robin Biddulph).

ask for it. He continued by explaining that he knew who they all were, and knew the person who

they rented their office from in town (Interview 289). According to the cadastral officials, the two

remaining unissued titles had been delayed because during the processing of the applications

officials had forgotten to sign relevant documents. That documentation had subsequently been

signed and the titles processed so that they were now ready for collection. In both of these cases

the villagers who had not received title were resident in other villages, and in one of the cases

they had been involved in a conflict over another plot of land in Buon.

According to officials at the Provincial Department of Land Management, the seven titles were

ready for collection. The owners would, however, need to get a letter from the commune office

confirming their identity, and would then need to travel to the provincial town to collect the title.

A small official payment at the commune office would be expected to be required, (probably

5,000 to 10,000 riels or 1.25 – 2.50 US dollars131

. Assuming that villagers know that they have a

right to go and collect their titles (and we have no evidence that they do), it is likely that they

would regard turning up at a provincial office as a highly risky venture, with the possibility of

131

This approximates roughly to what someone might earn for a day‟s labour.

Page 210: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

192

either a high payment being demanded, or of being sent away because the time was wrong or they

had the wrong paperwork etc. In other words, in the context of the prevailing relationships

between Cambodian villagers and provincial and district officials it seemed highly unlikely that

these titles would be collected unless there was some external initiative or stimulus. This was

corroborated by one case we encountered where (similar to the case of Sophal-Navy above),

where a household in the village owned land in another village. They had not been informed

when titles were issued, so had not collected the title to their land in that village. They said that

they had no plans to go and collect it, but hoped that the cadastral officials might want the fee and

therefore would come to them (Interview 321).

Overall, then, at the household level the titling had been inclusive in Buon. If there was any

pattern to be noted in the small number of households that did not receive title it seemed to be

that people not resident, or not present, in the village were more likely to miss out132

.

The other level at which exclusion from titling may be a problem is within the household. As

noted in chapter 2, one of the risks of a programme that formalises existing land tenure relations

is that it inadvertently strengthens men‟s position in relation to household assets by automatically

issuing title to a male „head of household‟. In Buon, villagers reported that where land had been

donated to either husband or wife by their respective families that they had registered the land to

that spouse, but otherwise they had jointly titled their land and had been encouraged to do this by

cadastral officials. A specific issue that arose in this respect were the cases of two single women,

one of whom reported being a widow, the other of whom had been deserted by her husband

thirteen years previously when the youngest of their six children was still a baby. The first of

these women reported that she separated from her husband 14 years previously and that he had

since died, though she was not sure when. She reported indignantly that the cadastral officials had

said that if she could not prove this that she could not title the name in her own name that it must

be jointly titled, which it was (Interview 380)133

. In the second case, the woman having occupied

her house land and brought up the six children since her husband had left, had applied to be the

sole owner of the land. Her former husband, who had been the original owner of the land,

disputed this claim – strongly supported by his mother. The woman said that the ownership of the

land had never been an issue until the titling occurred. The disputed ownership was referred up to

provincial level and they adjudicated that because she had been the sole, peaceful occupier for

over five years, and had raised the family there, that she should be the sole owner. According to

her, one of the repercussions was that from the time of the dispute, her former husband became

verbally abusive towards her, and one day chased her into her house and beat her leaving her with

a gash in her cheek that required seven stitches under her eye (281).

Notwithstanding the unintended effect of titling in the violence suffered by this woman in this

exceptional case, the process overall had been inclusive including being successful in ensuring

132

The relative wealth of the three people whose registration encountered problems and the fact that two of them had

been involved in other conflicts raises the possibility that officials might have been singling out individuals who

would be willing and able to make informal payments to facilitate their applications. This was certainly the view of

our village respondent, but it would require a systematic analysis of a larger sample to identify whether this sort of

targeting might be occurring. 133

In retrospect, I should have sought out the village facilitator who assisted with the process in the southern part of

the village and asked him about this issue. It is possible that the situation may have been a little more complicated

than she was describing.

Page 211: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

193

that women‟s property rights were protected both through joint titling and through the use of an

effective appeals process (the husband was somewhat better connected than the wife so it would

not have been a surprise had the judgement gone against her).

For the village of Buon, then, the process of land titling had been trouble-free. The sort of

speculation and shenanigans that have been encountered in some countries as people try to take

advantage of asymmetries of information (described in chapter 2) was completely absent in Buon.

The registration process led to title being issued for 96.2% of plots and of the 14 not issued, all 7

not under dispute were reported ready for collection. Both within households, where protection of

women‟s property rights in the formal system had been achieved, and at household level titling

had been an inclusive process (both compared to international standards and to the relatively high

standard of 95% which the project had set itself). We may now, therefore, turn to a consideration

of the impacts of this inclusive titling process in Buon.

6.2.6 Impact of Titling on Security and Investment

Our review of the national geography of tenure insecurity in Cambodia in Chapter 4 suggested

that Buon (being set in a lowland rice farming landscape which had escaped the ravages of the

post-1979 guerrilla war) would not be particularly prey to tenure insecurity. Our investigations of

the history of Buon and our interviews with villagers concerning their livelihoods and life

histories likewise did not suggest that tenure insecurity had been an issue. In order to confront the

issue directly we administered a simple questionnaire. This was in October 2008, three years after

the titling process began and over two years since the titles were issued. The questionnaire firstly

asked about tenure security today (after titling), secondly about tenure security before titling, and

thirdly about differences in agricultural practice. This enabled an overview of trends in tenure

security and in farming practice, and enabled us to follow up the results.

The aggregated results of this survey suggested a slight improvement in tenure security, as the

number of people who indicated that they were somewhat insecure in their tenure had decreased

by from 15 to 10 (see Table 6-11). There was likewise a small but significant minority, 7 out of

58 (12%) of respondents who reported that their farming practices had changed since titling. This

did not tell us about cause and effect, but did identify the households where titling might

potentially have made some difference to security.

Table 6-11: Tenure Security before and after Titling in Buon - Aggregate Responses

Are you worried

that someone might

take your land now?

Before titling were

you worried that

someone might take

your land?

Do you do anything

different regarding

how you farm your

land since it was

titled?

Yes 10 15 7

No 47 42 51

Don't Know 1 1 0

Total 58 58 58

Source: Field data, Impacts of Titling Questionnaire, October 2008

Page 212: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

194

However, in order to contextualize the responses it is necessary to view them in relation to each

other. The majority of respondents reported no change in tenure security after titling. Amongst

those who did report a change, a large minority reported deterioration rather than improvement

(see Table 6-12)

Table 6-12: Tenure Security after Titling in Buon Surveyed in October 2008

Reported tenure security after titling Responses (n=57) %

Improved 13 22.8

No change 36 63.2

Worsened 8 14.0

Source: Field Data, Impacts of Titling Questionnaire, October 2008

Further understanding is achieved by grouping the responses about security with the responses

about agricultural practice (see Table 6-13). By far the most common response was the “no

impact” type, with 31 of 57 (54.4%) respondents reporting that they were secure in their tenure

both before and after the titling, and that there had been no change in their agricultural practice.

On the other hand only 3 (5.2%) sets of responses correlated with project document expectations,

reporting namely that their tenure had been insecure prior to titling, was secure after titling and

that their agricultural practices had changed. This does not establish cause and effect, but it does

identify these three households as potentially having had experiences which corresponded to the

expectations established by the project document and the theories that underpin it.

In follow-up interviews, explanations sometimes pointed towards the titling as an explanatory

factor, and sometimes in other directions. Among the three households who followed the project

expectations, two of them stated that their sense of insecurity prior to titling had come from fears

that the government might appropriate their land for development projects. In cases where tenure

security was reported to have worsened, this was sometimes ascribed to being unsettled by the

titling process itself (HH66) or to the flaring up of conflicts associated with the titling (HH53),

but in other cases it was related to other factors such as the perceived threat of war with Thailand

(HH56) or that a sibling would claim back land from them (HH25). In none of the cases where

households had initially reported changing their agricultural practice were we able to substantiate

the initial report and relate it to titling.

According to the deputy village chief (Interview 286) land titling had not made any difference in

the village, either to tenure security or to agricultural practice. We only ever heard about titling

having a role in either tenure security or agricultural improvement when we asked the question

directly in those terms. In all our interviews about livelihood activities and factors that might

influence people‟s choices or activities land titling and land tenure security were never mentioned

as factors. It was thus impossible to conclude that titling had had any effect on tenure security or

on agricultural practice in the village during the three years following titling.

Page 213: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

195

Table 6-13: Impacts of Titling in Buon Surveyed in October 2008, Response by Type

Type Description134

HH numbers Total %

No impact (still

secure)

Tenure secure before and after

titling and agriculture

unchanged (NNN)

5, 7, 10, 11, 12, 14, 18,

19, 23, 26, 30, 33, 34,

35, 36, 37, 39, 41, 42,

43, 45, 46, 47, 51, 52,

58, 59, 62, 63, 64, 67

31

54.4

Intangible Improved security but no

impact on agriculture (NYN)

2, 6, 22, 28, 31, 38, 40,

48, 60, 71 10

17.5

Negative impact Tenure security deterioriated

and no agricultural

improvement (YNN)

1, 25, 44, 53, 56, 65, 66 7

12.3

Project expectation Insecure before titling, secure

after and agriculture improved

as a result (NYY)

4, 9, 20 3

5.2

Other causes Tenure secure before and after

but agriculture improved

(NNY)

13, 15, 54, 3

5.2

No impact 2 (still

insecure)

No impact 2 (still insecure) –

tenure insecure before and

after and agriculture

unchanged (YYN)

49, 50 2

3.5

Perverse impact Perverse impact – tenure

security deteriorated but

agricultural improvement

(YNY)

61 1

1.7

57 99.8%

Source: Field Data, Impacts of Titling Questionnaire, October 2008

6.2.7 Impact of Titling on Access to Credit

As we saw earlier in the chapter, most credit obtained by villagers remains on the informal

market at apparently high interest rates of 10% or so per month. If there was ever an expectation

that titling would enable a wholesale shift of credit from a rapacious informal market into a

relatively favourable (3-5% per month interest rates are typical) formal market, then Buon‟s

experiences would certainly undercut those expectations135

.

134

The three questions were: 1. Are you worried that someone might take your land? Y/N. 2. Before titling were you

worried that someone might take your land? Y/N. 3. Do you do anything different regarding how you farm your land

since it was titled? Y/N. 135

In my experience the private moneylender is often caricatured in Cambodia, especially by supporters of formal

credit. Private moneylenders encompass a wide range of different actors and relationships, and credit rates vary

hugely. Without knowing more about the sort of repayment rates and the responses to nonpayment of debts it is

Page 214: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

196

In relation to credit, villagers noted that both formal credit agencies and informal moneylenders

now took land titles as security for loans, but they did not report any change in the terms of credit

as a result of this (Interview 302). Villagers thought that people in other villages where title had

not been issued yet also got credit on the same terms. The village chief confirmed that titles were

now used as collateral for loans and named three households who had done this with formal

credit agencies (Interview 329).

The same pattern – that the title was now used as security but that there was no noticeable change

in the terms of credit – applied in the one case of a household having pawned land. Srei Phalla, a

very poor, single woman living with her young daughter had pawned her rice land with the Sann-

Heng family when the research began. When Sann and Heng wanted to raise the capital to send

their daughters away to study they called in the loan. Phalla then pawned the land with another

household instead. When she had pawned the land with Sann-Heng titles had not yet been issued;

when she pawned with the new household she had a title and handed it over as part of the

pawning agreement (Interview 306).

Overall then, during the three and a half years after titling was completed, we found that land

titles had become part of the apparatus of borrowing and lending in formal and informal markets.

However, we found no evidence of any noticeable impact on the terms on which credit was

obtained. Our research was not well-attuned to identifying changes that would not be noticed by

villagers. It may have been that there had been a slight difference in accessibility or in interest

rates, that was too small or gradual for villagers to have noticed. This is a significant point

because in order to recover the cost of the titles (about a dollar per plot to the user or about ten

dollars per plot to the state), a small but not necessarily noticeable improvement in the terms of

credit would be sufficient.

6.2.8 Impacts on the Land Market

In addition to contributing directly to increased investment and ability to raise capital through

credit, formalised land tenure is expected to facilitate a functioning land market. A functioning

land market might serve to reallocate land to the most efficient farmers, as well as determining

the most efficient level of land concentration or distribution and farm size.

As we have already seen in Chapter 4, land has been transacted in the Cambodian countryside

since the early 1980s. Transactions have either been trust-based with no official legitimation, or

have been informally witnessed by the local authorities either verbally or with a hand-written

letter (for which a small informal fee is routinely paid) in what So Sokbunthoeun (2009) has

termed a quasi-formal system. One possibility is that the new LMAP titles enable the land market

to function better, with a new formal market superseding and replacing the quasi-formal and

informal arrangements previously in place. The concept of legal plurality, on the other hand,

highlights the possibility that different systems may exist alongside each other, possibly in a

reasonably positive arrangement allowing people to „forum shop‟, but also with the risk that

adding to the different possibilities might create confusion and uncertainty.

difficult to judge the informal credit market, but the high rate of interest may indicate the extent to which

moneylenders are prepared to take a loss on a defaulter rather than enforcing repayment. Having said that, I have not

heard caricatures of formal and informal credit recycled in relation to land titling debates.

Page 215: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

197

The post-LMAP land administration system, is based on a computerised cadastral register. All

titles issued during the systematic titling are registered on the cadastral database. Transactions in

land subsequent to titling should be registered with the district land management office in order

that the ownership can be transferred on the title and in the database, and in order that the

transaction may be taxed.

So how did the land market in Buon function before titling, what difference did land registration

and titling make, and how is the land market functioning today? The Land and Livelihood

Questionnaire administered in the village in January 2008 identified all households who reported

having sold or received land. In March 2009 we conducted follow-up interviews with four of the

six households who had reported selling land (a total of 4 transactions) and 15 of the 16

households who had reported buying land (a total of 25 transactions). Of these 29 transactions136

,

seven, (one sale and six purchases) were of land located in other villages. In order to assess the

extent to which the market was enabling people to buy and be secure in their ownership we asked

representatives of households who had bought land both about any incidents that had occurred

after the transaction, and also about any feelings of anxiety they had had with regard to their

security of ownership.

Of the 25 reported purchases, twenty occurred prior to the LMAP titling and the other five

subsequent to it. Of the subsequent transfers, none was registered with the cadastral authorities.

The land title was handed over to the new owner, but the former owner‟s name remained on it. In

three cases the transactions were trust-based with no witnessing or documentation; in the other

two cases local authorities provided a cover letter to witness and (quasi-formally) authorise the

transaction (Interviews 405, 410). In four out of five of these cases the buyers reported that they

felt secure in their ownership and that there had not been any problems related to the transaction

subsequently.

In the fifth case, a Buon villager purchased land for her daughter from a relative in another

village in 2004. By 2009 her daughter had decided to move to Buon to be with her mother, so

they planned to sell the plot in the other village. However, the relative is now objecting to the sale

and saying that the 2004 transaction must be registered first and that this will cost between three

hundred and four hundred US dollars. For the Buon villager, then, the consequence of LMAP

registration is that the former owner is able to obstruct her in the market by using the fact that her

name is still on the title against her. It is not certain that such a conflict would not have occurred

even had titling not occurred, but the case does illustrate that the introduction of a formal system

which is then not used does not necessarily enable unproblematic customer choice and „forum

shopping‟, but could create obstacles in a previously functioning market137

.

136

The actual number of transactions having taken place in the village since 1979 is likely to be greater than those

reported. Transactions are subject to a 4% land transfer tax which is collected retrospectively when land is titled. As

a result there is a significant incentive for villagers to report that land which they bought as having been allocated by

the state. 137

A reader close to the LMAP project provided the following written comment: “Undocumented/unwitnessed

transaction – recipe for trouble in the pre-titling system also; raises questions of whether the land was actually sold or

whether some other arrangement was reached – though I take your point that titling clearly strengthens the claim of

the previous owner here”.

Page 216: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

198

Of the twenty purchases reported prior to the titling, none of the buyers reported any anxiety or

any challenge or conflict in relation to the transaction prior to the titling process. The introduction

of LMAP titling and registration, however, did create uncertainty and actual challenges to

ownership for six of the twenty buyers. For three of them (Interviews 273, 278, 401), this was

just a feeling of anxiety that the former owner would use the titling process to try and reclaim

their land back, but in practice in these three cases the sellers did not make trouble for them and

their anxiety proved unfounded. In a fourth case, the buyer had purchased land in 1994 (with no

witnessing by local authorities), and at the time of LMAP registration the former owner tried to

claim the land back. This dispute was resolved in their favour and now they feel secure in their

tenure again (Interview 347). The remaining two plots where a buyer of land reported feeling

insecure in her tenure following the LMAP registration related to transactions by a woman from

Buon in another village (Interview 311). The woman had decided to venture into money lending

and borrowed from a relative to finance this business idea. She loaned money to two men in a

neighbouring village. However, neither of them was able to repay and instead each gave her a

plot of land. She was not pleased with this outcome as she did not really want the land and did

not think it was worth the full value of the loan, however her husband (who was alive at the time)

encouraged her to accept the compromise. The transaction was not witnessed by the local

authorities, but the village chief in the other village had been involved in her attempts to recover

her loan from the men so he was fully aware.

When LMAP titling was implemented in that village, the two men tried to dispute her ownership

of the land that she had received. Their village chief supported her in the dispute and she was

awarded title. However, in order to secure this support she agreed to sign an agreement with the

men stating that if they, or their children as adults, repaid the full sum of the original loan (two

million riels or 500 US dollars) that they could recover the land. Having signed that agreement

she regretted it because inflation might mean that in future years these sums of money would

represent far less than the value of the land. She sought advice from cadastral officials and they

told her that the contract was not binding and did not affect her right to sell the land (Interview

311). Once again, there is no absolute guarantee that she would not have encountered problems in

relation to this land even if LMAP registration had not occurred. However, it was the registration

that initiated the challenge to her tenure, and she is now in a position where the quasi-formal

system is telling her that she has no right to sell and the formal system is saying that she does

have the right to sell. If she wishes to sell that land in the future she will be vulnerable to rent-

seeking challenges from officials both from the formal and the quasi-formal system.

Registration and titling are expected to provide the basis for clear, enforceable tenure rights

which are the basis for transferability in a well-functioning land market. This is expected to result

in related benefits, as transactions become less costly (no need to make unofficial payments in an

unofficial system, or to build fences and walls as substitutes for enforceable rights etc), and for

these benefits to become apparent in increased land prices. In Buon, the expectation was that the

formal system would attract informal payments. Titling had been a cheap and efficient system,

but people‟s expectation was that if they turned to the cadastral authorities to register subsequent

transactions that they would be likely to have to pay a fee of 300 to 500 US dollars, similar in

other words to what they would have expected to pay for a sporadic title prior to LMAP

Page 217: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

199

registration138

. In Buon people did not notice any difference in land prices as a result of LMAP

registration. It probably would be difficult to identify a small price increase related to titling in a

study such as ours in Buon where there had only been five subsequent transactions in the three

years since titling. In the one case where a woman re-pawned land which previously had been

untitled and had since acquired title, she received the same price for her land.

Overall, land titling in Buon did not appear to have had a significant impact on the land market.

The market functioned well before titling, and still appeared to function well after titling. While

none of the cases were clear cut, a couple of examples from the village suggest ways in which the

presence of a formal system which is not utilised might be detrimental to the functioning of the

market by making new owners who have acquired land via the hybrid system (formal land title

transacted quasi-formally/informally) vulnerable to claims from former owners whose names

remain on the original title. On the other hand, if such cases do become common that may, of

course, provide the incentive for accelerated uptake of the formal system, as one of our

interviewees concluded:

So now we know that we should not put off the registration of the transaction until tomorrow, and

we know that we should not trust too much (Interview 285).

Perhaps the most striking aspect of findings from Buon is the extent to which problems related to

tenure security post-titling involve transactions in other villages. One of the expectations

associated with formalisation is that, whilst an informal system might work very well locally, it

will tend to create barriers to non-local entrants to the land market. The experiences of Buon

suggest that even post-LMAP registration and titling, attempting to acquire land in a village

where one is not resident might remain more risky and expensive than purchasing in your own

village.

6.2.9 Impacts of Titling on the Social Costs of Land Conflicts

In the LMAP titling process, if there is a conflict over a plot which cannot be resolved the plot to

that title is not issued and the distribution of all other titles proceeds. A separate component of the

LMAP project is devoted to supporting dispute resolution mechanisms which aim to assist parties

to resolve their conflicts at the lowest possible administrative level and without need to turn to the

courts.

The expectation of land titling is that prior to titling there will be a level of land disputes, which

will be temporarily and possibly quite dramatically increased by the titling process itself, but that

afterwards, once ownership has been adjudicated there will then be a minimal level of disputes –

implying that, notwithstanding the temporary problem of increased disputes, the overall effect

will be reduced social costs in terms of reduced land conflicts.

Below is a short account of each of the seven conflicts which led to non-issuance of title in each

of these cases in Buon. Once the cases are described they will be analysed in terms of their

overall social and economic costs.

138

A reader close to the LMAP project commented: “Issue in all of this from a practical point of view is why people

don‟t register - fees; tax; bribes; and requirement to deal with distant/high level officials – are the usual answers

given”

Page 218: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

200

Conflict a. Burial Plot 210

Conflict was between household (HH) 49 and HH 41. HH41 had a burial plot in the middle of

HH49‟s rice field. The rice field was plot 365 and was not contested. The burial plot was marked

as a separate plot 210 and both households claimed ownership. The conflict was resolved with a

verbal agreement that HH41 had the right to have relatives buried there even though not the

owner of that land. The conflict was solved by giving the formal title to a third party, a former

commune councillor who lives near to both parties to the conflict. According to the village chief

this was the only conflict that had been resolved.

Conflict b. Scrubland Plot 332

This land had originally belonged to HH64. In 1983 HH53 had asked to borrow it. It was an

uneven piece of scrubland, „like a pig‟s snout‟ according to HH53, and they grew a small amount

of rice (ten bundles of transplanted seedlings – so very little indeed) on the lower part and

gathered fire-wood from the upper part. At the time of the titling both parties claimed ownership

of that land. This conflict has not been resolved and no title has been issued. At no time in the

previous 23 years had there been any conflict over this.

Conflict c. Pond Plot 330

This is a conflict between a member of HH64 and her daughter who now lives with a husband in

a neighbouring village. In 1983 when land was distributed the village chief had divided the pond

between mother and daughter, drawing a line half way across. Since that time the pond has silted

up, which has changed its shape, meaning that more of the pond is north of the original dividing

line than south of it. The mother is demanding that the new boundary be drawn at the half way

point of the current shape of the pond, whilst her daughter contends that the 1983 line should be

used. The disputed area is therefore a few square meters of mainly pond.

Conflict d. Plot 343 and Conflict e. Plot 344

Plots 343 and 344 are to the west of the road that runs south from the pagoda. They are now very

small plots as a result of the widening and improvement of that road. Both plots are claimed by

HH27 who have farmed them both since 1983 (although today they are so small that they are not

farmed). The disputants, HH26 for plot 343 and HH21 for plot 344, both claim that HH27 only

borrowed those plots of land, but do not own them. Again, this has not been an issue at any stage

over the past 24 years. The husband at HH21 and the wife at HH27 are the first deputy village

chief and village assistant respectively. The husbands at HH21 and HH27 are first cousins with

each other, and are also both first cousins with the village chief. The deputy and assistant village

chiefs can barely speak to each other because of this plot, which the village chief complains

makes work more difficult in the village.

Conflict f. Plot 215

Plot 215 is a small plot directly adjacent to the little access road to the village hall. Ownership is

contested by HH63 and HH45. This was another case of land being borrowed over twenty years

ago: HH63 claimed that they have used the land since 1985 and that it is therefore theirs; HH45,

however, say that they were only lending the land to HH63 and not giving it to them.

Page 219: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

201

Conflict g. Plots 360 and 364

This household is not registered as belonging to the village, but is living on the land immediately

to the west of the school and north of the pagoda. The school director claims that this land was

handed over to the state by the pagoda and belongs to the school. The couple received the land

from the former chief monk at the pagoda (who was the father of the wife) and the household is

now claiming ownership of them.

The village chief was angered by these conflicts and frustrated at the way that he felt that the

titling process had caused them. When I showed him a theoretical graph of conflict levels going

from a high level, to an even higher level around the time of titling, and then falling to a lower

level he laughed and said that the graph should show that there were no conflicts before titling,

but many afterwards and that it gave him a headache (Interview 328). He was frustrated not only

by the titling process, but by villagers who argued over land that was so small as to be worthless:

―They don‘t think properly – none of them!‖ (Interview 329. Author‘s translation).

To some degree it appeared that the village chief was exaggerating the case, probably because of

the frustration he felt at the extra workload. Certainly two of the conflicts (conflicts d. and e.) had

existed before, although they did seem to become much worse after titling. However, the seven

cases taken together tend to support the village chief‟s assertion that they did not represent land

of any particular productive value (with case f. the land at the pagoda being the exception), and

that the titling process aggravated rather than improved the overall situation regarding land

conflicts in the village.

In Buon, then, is seemed that overall the most valuable land, namely residential land and

agricultural production land, was not generally subject to conflicts. Rather, because it was in

regular use, there was little room for any ambiguity or conflict. On the other hand, some smaller

pieces of land, of marginal value, were more susceptible to conflict. In some cases this was

because they did have more complex tenure forms – i.e. one person had the right to cut wood

from a piece of land whilst another still considered themselves as owning it and having the right

to dispose of it – and simplifying it into a single title of ownership necessitated (or at least

threatened) some part of this complexity. In the case of Buon, however, these parcels were so rare

and of so little value that it would seem somewhat absurd to try and create sophisticated multi-

layered tenure systems to accommodate them. Indeed one of the hypotheses that is suggested by

the study in Buon is that land conflicts in the relatively secure smallholder areas were LMAP has

been implemented are most likely to occur on land of marginal economic value.

According to officials at the provincial cadastral office, the conflict d (and presumably the others

though only conflict d. was being explicitly discussed) had been referred to the provincial

cadastral commission for resolution. They had been unable to resolve it and had forwarded it to

the national cadastral commission. The national cadastral commission had in turn referred the

conflict to the provincial court. According to what the cadastral officials had heard, it was likely

that the unresolved conflicts would now be referred back to the provincial cadastral office. Asked

Page 220: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

202

if this was common, the provincial cadastral officials estimated that approximately 50-60

unresolved disputes per commune had been referred up to national level139

.

Overall, in Buon land conflicts did not appear to have high social costs prior to titling. If

anything, certainly in the view of the village chief, the titling had increased the social costs by

creating or restarting conflicts which could not then be resolved. He was clearly frustrated by the

difficulties his deputy and assistant (both relatives of his) being involved in such a bitter conflict,

which seemed to lead him to particularly harsh judgements regarding titling and its effects.

Overall, while conflicts clearly had been initiated or revived by titling, and not resolved, it would

be difficult to conclude that social costs of land conflicts in Buon were very significant in the

overall social and economic life of the village.

6.4 Conclusions and Implications

6.4.1 Relation of the Case of Buon to other Research on Titling Impacts in Cambodia

In order to draw implications from the case of Buon, the findings from the case study can usefully

be put in the context of other work that has been done on the impacts of systematic land titling in

Cambodia. This includes two beneficiary assessments commissioned by the German GTZ, which

surveyed villagers‟ perceptions of the impacts of titling (Deutsch, 2006; Deutsch & Makathy,

2009); a detailed case study of the impacts of titling in two communes in a rural district of the

coastal municipality of Sihanoukville (McAndrew, 2007); an independent review of LMAP

systems and procedures which judged LMAP processes against World Bank social protection

policies (O'Leary, 2005), a PhD dissertation featuring a survey of 376 households in three

communes (two of which had undergone land registration and titling) in central Kampong Speu

province (So, 2009); a field trip commissioned by the World Bank to follow up assertions made

in the World Bank‟s (2006) poverty assessment based on analysis of the 2004 Cambodia

Socioeconomic Survey (Markussen, 2006) which also led to an article in an international

academic journal (Markussen, 2008).

The inclusiveness which we found characterized the systematic land titling process in Buon is

reflected in different ways in different studies. Deutsch and Makathy (2009) have carried out the

largest scale study, surveying 485 villagers at sites in ten different provinces/municipalities as

well as consulting a further 358 people through focus group discussions and key informant

interviews. Their survey found very high levels of overall satisfaction with the titling process

(2009, p. 22) in all of the eight provinces and two municipalities where they conducted their

beneficiary assessment. Some of the elements of participation had not necessarily proceeded as

designed, with, for example, only 59% of interviewees reporting that they understood the purpose

of the public display maps posted during titling. Nevertheless, they reported high levels (“almost

100%”) of trust in the cadastral officials. On the other hand, Deutsch and Makathy (2009, p.49-

51) did find elements of exclusion relating to the process relating to demands for a 4% tax for

previous transactions on a plot of land (including sub-divisions, inheritances, and even

transactions on the plot previous to the current owner‟s).

139

One reader close to the project commented “From what we know very few of these disputes get processed once

they are forwarded to the CCs (cadastral commissions)”

Page 221: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

203

In contrast to this image of inclusiveness, however, are the circumstances of some people and

places excluded from the benefits of titling. McAndrew (2007) was required to adjust his sample

because one of the villages in the commune he was looking at was involved in a land dispute with

a businessman. As a result, land registration in that village was postponed and villagers had not

received the benefits of LMAP titling in their struggles to achieve tenure security. Meanwhile,

O‟Leary (2005, p.10), who was looking from a viewpoint of social safeguards in World Bank

supported projects, found that households who had been settled on state land for 10-15 years had

received no recognition of their tenure and no possibility of being registered as possessors with

the LMAP survey teams. These cases from the literature further confirm the findings of Chapter

4, namely that in its implementation, LMAP land registration tends to be conflict averse, and

therefore people involved in conflicts with business people or with the state are unlikely to be

assisted by the project.

The issue of single women being forced to register land jointly with a dead/absent husband was

encountered in two households in Buon, and has been reported elsewhere as a possibly significant

issue in Cambodia. Research in 5 communes identified 15 women who reported that they had

thought that land was being solely titled to them, but who then discovered it had been jointly

titled to them and their former spouse (Mehrvar, Kim Sore, & Sambath, 2008, p. 10)140

. To

follow up that qualitative work, Deutsch and Makathy sought to identify the same issue in their

larger sample. However, whilst they interviewed 70 women who all reported headed their

households and owned a total of 274 parcels of land they found no similar cases. On the contrary,

the women they interviewed reported local authorities helping them to ensure that cadastral

officials registered land to them. The case of Buon reaffirms that single women can be in a

position where they feel that joint titling works against them. However, given that this was

already established by Mehrvar et al. (2008), and that the question now is one of how widespread

this problem might be, our research has not substantially moved that debate forward.

Regarding tenure security and its effects on agricultural investment the findings in Buon seem at

first glance to be different from those of some other studies, especially the recent beneficiary

assessment. In Buon we found little or no impact on tenure security, whilst other studies reported

titles enhancing tenure security and reducing conflict (Deutsch, 2006; Deutsch & Makathy, 2009;

McAndrew, 2007). However, the point here was that all of these studies reported on perceptions

of tenure security. Our method was slightly different as we first asked about tenure security

today, and then about tenure security prior to titling, and then compared the results. If we had

simply asked about people‟s satisfaction with titles, or had in a more open ended way asked about

the effect on tenure security people would undoubtedly have responded positively. It was finding

any tangible evidence that titling might make a difference which proved elusive. McAndrew‟s

findings were similar to ours in this respect. He found that people in the villages in Sihanoukville

felt more secure in their tenure compared to the situation before titling. On the other hand, like us,

he found no evidence that farming practices or agricultural investment had been altered by the

titling. Deutsch and Makathy (2009, p36-7) did find increased investment in residences and

agriculture but could not establish links between this and titling.

140

The authors of that study make no claims to representativeness, and give no detail on either the size of the

communes or how they went about identifying interviewees for their studies. It is therefore difficult to draw any

conclusion about whether there research suggests a common problem or not.

Page 222: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

204

Deutsch and Makathy (2009 p33-4) found quite high levels of use of land titles for obtaining

credit, with about a third of their sample of beneficiaries having used their title to obtain credit.

This tallies with our finding in Buon, where it seemed that all credit suppliers, both formal and

informal, now expected to receive land titles as security for loans. Almost all of their respondents

reported that land titles improved access to credit but this, as in Buon, may not indicate an

improvement in the terms of credit, but may rather reflect the fact that since titling, a title must be

provided in order to obtain credit. Deutsch and Makathy (2009, p. 52) interviewed bank and

microfinance institution representatives who reported not needing titles for loans of less than

10,000 USD. Nobody in Buon had ever taken such a large loan. In this respect it seemed that

titling was of benefit to a richer segment of the population than the rural villagers who we were

encountering. On the other hand, the formal credit providers did report that use of titles helped to

prevent overlapping loans and often speeded the loan process. These findings strengthen the

possibility that land titling might be effecting terms of access to credit, but doing so in such

marginal ways that villagers do not notice the impact.

Regarding impact on the land market, (McAndrew, 2007) found increased buying and selling of

land, especially featuring the purchase of land by outsiders from the provincial and national

capitals from people who were selling land in response to health crises. However, these were not

perceived as being facilitated by titling, but were seen as a result of market trends which would

have occurred with or without titling.

The „finding‟ in Buon that subsequent transactions are not being registered is already well-

established in the literature, and the major reasons well-known: if the village chief can guarantee

your transaction for three USD, why would you risk spending three hundred dollars or more to

get the same task done by the cadastral authorities (So 2009, p174; Markussen 2008, p2280). In

this context the recent findings of Deutsch and Makathy (2009) that nearly 10% of transactions

are being registered is interesting and deserves detailed follow-up. It may be possible that the sort

of difficulties which our informants had disposing of land which had somebody else‟s name on it

might be an indication that a demand for subsequent registration, despite the high price, might be

starting to grow.

In this light, the finding by Deutsch and Makathy found that nearly 10% of subsequent

transactions (12 in a sample of 114) were registered with cadastral authorities is somewhat

remarkable. The authors‟ explanation was that these subsequent registrations were mainly for

higher value plots of land.

With respect to the social costs of conflict Deutsch and Makathy (2009, p31) interviewed village

and commune chiefs who reported land disputes being reduced in every adjudication area visited,

in some cases by as much as 90%. This suggests that the trials and frustrations of the village chief

in Buon may have been an exception to the general rule. Likewise the results of McAndrew

(whose scale and methods were more similar to those in this thesis) who found reduced conflicts

in the villages researched in Sihanoukville.

6.2.10 Buon and Geographies of Evasion

The case has implications for both systematic land titling in Cambodia in particular, and for the

arguments of this thesis in general.

Page 223: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

205

The case provides an example of a village in which systematic land titling provides title for lands

that are already relatively secure. In this sense the village may be quite broadly representative of

the lowland areas where LMAP has thus far been implemented, especially given that there has

been a deliberate strategy to concentrate first on areas where major obstacles are unlikely to be

encountered (World Bank, 2007b, p. 73). In such contexts, the transformative claims that are

sometimes made on behalf of land titling – that it can contribute to a revolution of agricultural

practice (World Bank 2006) and bring into play vast amounts of previously „dead‟ capital (de

Soto 2000) are clearly unfounded.

Detailed small scale studies such as that in Buon give insight into cause and effect, and enable us

to understand how processes work out on the ground. If there is a situation in a rural village

where LMAP has been implemented, where prior to titling there was insecurity, and this

insecurity was reduced by titling, and as a result of the reduced insecurity there have been

discernable differences in agricultural investment and production, then it would be invaluable to

have those experiences documented by research comparable to that which we have conducted in

Buon.

As far as we have been able to ascertain, no such cases exist. We have not been able to track

down or identify any particular case where there was a noticeable difference in agricultural

practice as a result of titling. One strategy which would capture the potential synergies between

qualitative and quantitative methods would be to use the survey results from Deutsch and

Makathy (2009) to identify places where titling has been reported as having effects on tenure

security and agricultural investment, and to see if some tangible evidence can be identified in

those places. Until there is well-documented evidence that land titles are making any difference

to tenure security, it seems misplaced to make claims for poverty reduction effects of titling based

on improved security. The case of Buon stands in stark and useful contrast to the calculations in

the 2007 World Bank Equity Report where it was assumed that issuing land titles would increase

yields by 73% on agricultural land and as a result for every million titles issued would enable

over 430 000 people to be “lifted out of poverty” and the national poverty rate to be reduced by

3.36% (World Bank, 2007b, pp. 67-68). Certainly, the experience of Buon appears to challenge

the notion that these estimates are “rather conservative”. We will return to the slipperiness and

ambiguity of these grand claims in Chapter 7.

Having concluded the empirical chapters of this thesis we will next turn to a consideration of the

findings about systematic land titling and community forestry, and how those findings enable us

to answer the main research question about the relationship between property rights interventions

in Cambodia and the livelihoods of the people they are intended to benefit, and what that case

might tells us in more broad terms about the development industry and its interventions.

6.5 Summary

Fifty years ago Buon was a small settlement, with houses gathered around two ponds, surrounded

by rice fields, with forest around the rice field, both within the village area and beyond. The

population were overwhelmingly local – born and brought up in or near the village and earning

their livings there. By the 1980s the landscape had been transformed, with only the smallest

scrubbiest patches of woodland remaining in a landscape of rice fields as far as the eye could see.

Most houses furthermore were now along the roads in the village not by the ponds. The pagoda

Page 224: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

206

had been transformed from a thriving community a distance from the village, to a sparsely

populated institution more or less at the village‟s geographical centre. During the 2000s, long

after the transformation of the landscape, came an economic transformation. The local economy

began to be dominated by incomes from work in Phnom Penh leading to visible signs of wealth

such as larger houses, more and better motorcycles and televisions along with new, western style

clothes and mobile telephones. The distance between the village and the pagoda has disappeared:

with houses and stalls directly opposite the pagoda entrance, and its grounds having been

encroached upon by the school buildings and a private house. During the study period from late

2006 to early 2009 the village population retained its local roots: 89% of adult residents were

born in Buon and only 3 of the 64 households did not contain an adult born in the village.

The people of Buon had lived through a period of relative economic boom during the decade up

to and including the study period, but one that was quite different from that experienced by those

in Bey. Whilst in the past, Buon had been characterised by local income generating and

subsistence activities, during the decade the economy has been dominated by remittance incomes

from Phnom Penh. Young women have been working in garment factories, bringing home most

of their salaries in monthly visits to the village; young men have been working on construction

sites bringing in less regular and predictable incomes; older men have been working as

motorcycle taxi drivers in the capital. Traditionally, the villagers of Buon, like other villages in

the western part of Bati district, have weaved string out of sugar palm bark and then sold it by

travelling from village to village, often in other provinces. Today this continues as a spare time

activity for most households, often absorbing children‟s spare time after school, and especially

for the households who trade the string, this can be an important source of income. Rice farming,

while the centre of traditional livelihoods and central to rural Khmer culture, has become

economically marginal. Of 66 households in the village only ten habitually produce enough rice

to cover their own rice consumption needs, and only one household consistently produced a

tradable surplus. Even if the profits from farming rice on the village‟s 44 hectares could be

doubled, the economic impact on the villagers would be marginal.

The increased prosperity of the past decade, built as it is on the construction industry and the

growth of the garment sector in Phnom Penh, had already transformed outward appearances in

the village before our research began. Houses were bigger and better, people were better clothed

and fed and had more and newer consumer goods such as televisions and motorcycles. The

increased incomes in the village had also supported a number of small businesses – two

restaurants, a wedding caterer and photographer, a motorcycle repair workshop, a cycle

workshop, two rice milling operations, and a number of small general retailers – mostly by better

off households who had accumulated capital from working in Phnom Penh. At the end of the

research, however, the effects of the economic downturn globally and nationally were beginning

to be felt. The casual work on construction sites was being characterised by longer down times,

whilst a number of garment factories had either closed or suspended production because of a

shortage of orders. The key determinant of future livelihoods in the village will be the extent to

which households will continue to be able to access paid employment in Phnom Penh. There is

little in the village‟s recent experience that would prepare the population for a more intensive

dependence on local resources and little to suggest that arable farming, string manufacture and

animal husbandry could support any more than a very impoverished way of life compared to what

the village has become accustomed to over the past decade.

Page 225: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

207

Land titles were issued in the village between late 2005 and mid-2006. The overwhelming

majority of villagers had paid the small fee, had received the titles and had them under their

houses. A small minority of villagers had not received titles to parcels as a result of conflicts,

bureaucratic mistakes or for reasons that were unclear or contested.

Increased tenure security leading to increased investment in land is the main theoretical

justification for land titling. The majority of villagers reported that they were already secure in

their tenure before the issue of land titles, that they remained secure in their tenure after the issue

of titles. This was in contrast with the LMAP project document which suggested that tenure

insecurity was to be found throughout Cambodia, but in line with our findings in Chapter 4. In

the absence of any change in tenure security, titling had had no observable impact on farming

practices, investment or ability to raise credit in the village.

Formalised tenure is also intended to contribute to the efficient operation of land markets. In

Buon the land market was found to have functioned efficiently during the twenty years prior to

titling. The introduction of a formal titling system and a cadastral register had made little impact

on existing informal practices, which were underpinned by a combination of trust between

transacting parties and informal authorisation by local authorities. In two cases, however, there

were indications that the tension between the formal system and the informal system could result

in a degree of insecurity for buyers who would be vulnerable to assertions of ownership by

people who had sold to them, especially if the buyers were not local.

Non-receipt of title where it was associated with land conflicts, was over land of minimal

productive value. To some extent the titling process awakened latent conflicts but was then

unable to resolve them. Non-issue of title for other reasons seemed to afflict non-local possessors

more than local people. There was no evidence of poor people being excluded from the process,

or of rent-seeking across the board by officials, nor was there any decisive evidence that officials

were targeting wealthier households to try and extract rents.

Women and men within households appeared to get their tenure rights recognised in equal

measure, with joint registration of ownership being the most common, and with land titled to the

husband or wife if it had been a gift from their respective parents. The exception was two women

who had divorced or been deserted, but who were required to provide legal proof of their status as

single women and owners of the land they occupied.

Land titling in Buon village was a process that villagers were satisfied with. It was also a process

that by and large had done no harm: some conflicts did arise following titling which perhaps

otherwise would not have done, but these were exceptional and there was no guarantee that many

would not have occurred anyway. However, neither our observations nor the responses of

villagers could discern any tangible benefit from titling. As a lowland village in the settled

agricultural area of central Cambodia Buon resembles most places where systematic land titling

has been introduced, and in that case might be illustrative of the actual potentials of land titling in

the current implementation areas. The case of Buon presents and implicit challenge to those who

have claimed that LMAP titling can raise hundreds of thousands of people out of poverty and

transform smallholder agriculture in Cambodia. The challenge is to find properly contextualized

evidence of anywhere in the hundreds of villages where LMAP has been implemented where

there has been any impact of titling on agricultural investment or productivity. In absence of that,

Page 226: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

208

the conclusion from Buon is that debates about the potential benefits of land titling should be

pitched at a much lower and more realistic level.

Page 227: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

209

7. Conclusions and Implications.

7.1 Thesis Aim and Research Questions Revisited

The broad area of interest motivating this study was the relationship between development

interventions and the livelihoods of poor people. This relationship was introduced in the context

of case study research from the 1990s which showed how the development industry

misrepresented the lives and livelihoods of people in rural areas. Those misrepresentations

overstated the role of agriculture and other local resource based livelihood activities and

understated the importance of labour migration. They also misrepresented rural areas by

depoliticising them, which resulted in depictions of places as unoccupied or without history.

Those earlier studies had taken place in an era when integrated rural development projects were at

the forefront of development intervention. Three decades later, when the fieldwork for this thesis

took place, institutional development set in a context of support to sectors and budgets at national

level had replaced projects as the primary modes of development assistance. Property rights were

at the fore of this institutional turn in development intervention, drawing inspiration from

theoreticians as diverse as Hernan de Soto and Elinor Ostrom.

By using the case of property rights interventions in Cambodia, this thesis has investigated the

relationship between the interventions and the livelihoods of poor rural people to ask whether,

with a new approach and three decades of experience, the development industry was still

repeating the same patterns of misrepresentation and failure. Had the lessons of past experience

and the institutional turn resulted in any change from the old pathologies? With this in mind, the

aim of the project was:

To describe and explain the relationship between property rights interventions and the

livelihoods of the rural poor in Cambodia.

This project was framed as a critical geography of development intervention, which would

incorporate: analysis of the spatial distribution of interventions (intentional development) in

relation to key features of the political economy/ecology (immanent development); the

conceptualisation of development as travel as a means of unpacking the discursive and political

factors which influence them; use of contextualised studies of place to provide an analytical lens

by which to examine the generalised claims of theory and practice. The spatial analysis was

carried out at national level. This enabled regional differences in tenure insecurity to be analysed

in combination with the geographical spread of two property rights interventions designed to

address tenure insecurity. This highlighted the question of whether the proposed solutions were in

the right place to address the problems they were supposed to address. In order to understand the

relationship between the geography of immanent development and the geography of intentional

Page 228: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

210

development it was necessary to understand the factors which shaped each. The specific

questions that structured the national case study were thus:

1. Where in rural Cambodia is tenure insecurity a problem? Why?

2. Where in Cambodia have tenure rights interventions been implemented? Why?

3. What is the relationship between the geography of tenure insecurity and the

geography of tenure security interventions?

Two village studies provided a contextualised study of place. One village, Bey, was in forest and

had hosted a community forestry project; the other village, Buon, was in a rice field landscape

where the national systematic land titling programme had been administered. The questions

which informed the village studies were:

1. How do people in the village earn a living?

2. What factors constrain and enable villagers’ livelihoods, and what is the importance

of tenure security/insecurity in those livelihoods?

3. To what extent do tenure security interventions make a difference to rural tenure

security/insecurity and rural livelihoods? Why/why not?

Synthesising the results of these three studies would yield insights into the operation of property

rights interventions in Cambodia, and might also contribute to understandings of how

development industry interventions in rural areas of the global South in the early 21st century

compare to those of earlier decades. This final chapter of the thesis reviews the findings from

research, provides a discussion of those findings and their implications in terms of both property

rights interventions in Cambodia in particular and of the operation of the development industry in

general. The implications for of the research for both policy and research are discussed, as well as

its other contributions.

7.2 Findings: Geographies of Evasion in Property Rights Interventions in Cambodia

To recap, this thesis has sought to investigate the relationship between development interventions

and the lives and livelihoods of poor people by examining the case of property rights

interventions in Cambodia, looking specifically at systematic land titling and community forestry.

The findings of the national level and the two village level studies are presented respectively

below.

At national level, tenure insecurity was found to have been a problem in almost all provinces in

rural Cambodia. In the transition from a planned to a market economy there was no initial means

of legally transferring state land into private hands. Logging concessions and economic land

concessions were authorised at national level, with various degrees of secrecy. This meant that

anyone attempting to settle on former state land was extremely insecure in their tenure, frequently

pitted in conflicts with entrepreneurs who were able to mobilise state officials and military forces

in their support. There were particular tenure security problems in the north-west of the country

where the displacement of local populations by fighting meant that military forces had often

developed a sense of ownership over land. This was also the part of the country where most

refugees from the Thai-Cambodian border had been settled, with less than the full enthusiastic

support of the local authorities, and therefore a good deal of insecurity. The majority of the

Page 229: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

211

Cambodian population, however, lived in lowland rice farming areas of central Cambodia, where

conditions were quite different and much more secure. Peace had returned to many of these areas

in the early 1980s and pre-war norms had quickly reasserted themselves in defiance of national

policies of communal farming and state ownership. These norms included locally-authorised

privatised tenure and a functioning market for land.

The programme of systematic land titling within the Land Management and Administration

Project (LMAP) implemented by the Cambodian government with technical and financial support

from the World Bank and the governments of Finland and Germany aimed to foster economic

development by improving tenure security. The project document was somewhat contradictory

regarding its orientation: on the one hand it was framed as addressing the problem of land

grabbing, including by government and military actors, but on the other hand it suggested that

registration and titling would only take place in areas that were free of dispute. In practice, it was

the conflict-averse rather than the conflict-solving tendency which defined the project‟s

geographical distribution. The programme has only been implemented in those lowland rice

farming landscapes which are characterised by security of tenure. This has mainly been a result of

a conscious strategy to avoid conflicts, justified on the grounds that the programme should have

some easy wins before it takes on more difficult challenges. This I have characterised as a

geographical diversion of the programme away from the locations of the main problem it claimed

to address. The current programme of community forestry being consolidated in Cambodia was

initiated in various places at different times by a range of national and international NGOs in

Cambodia with financial support from a range of multi-lateral and bilateral agencies and

international NGOs, and has gradually been formalised as a government sanctioned initiative

following the 2003 Community Forestry Sub-Decree and the related 2006 Community Forestry

Prakas. The main aim of the programme as expressed in the sub-decree was:

To establish procedures to enable Communities to manage, use and benefit from forest resources,

to preserve their culture, tradition and improve their livelihoods (RGC, 2003).

Only weak forms of tenure have been granted to communities, and these only over forest lands

that have already been degraded. In other words, where the tenure rights interventions have been

admitted into the forest landscapes which are characterised by tenure insecurity they have been in

diluted form.

Meanwhile, both land titling and community forestry programmes have been able to depict

success in the fight against tenure insecurity in the form of number of titles issued, and the

number of community forestry projects achieving formal recognition. These accounts of

quantitative progress provide a facade of success effectively concealing a geography of evasion,

where, unable to tackle the problems they are presented as confronting, interventions find

operational space in the places where those problems barely exist.

In the village studies, the livelihoods of villagers were first examined along with the immanent

development forces that constrained/enabled those livelihoods. The development initiatives were

examined in the context of those livelihoods. The development interventions were found to have

minimal influence on villagers‟ livelihoods, not least because those livelihoods were quite

different from the ones that the interventions claimed to address. Thus, in Bey village, people

were undergoing a process whereby the forests around them had been logged, and were then

being converted into agricultural land. As a result of the villagers‟ participation in these activities

Page 230: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

212

the decade up to and including the research period had been one of economic boom. One of the

consequences of the boom was a rapid increase in the population of the village, which doubled

during the period 2005 to 2008. The community forestry project in the village intended to secure

non-timber forest based livelihoods for villagers by enabling them to manage an area of forest

which would ensure that they could continue their „historical‟ and „traditional‟ means of earning a

living. Villagers‟ livelihoods had, however, long been dominated by logging and by agricultural

labour, and the forests in the area no longer contained the resources that would be required to

sustain an adequate NTFP-based livelihood. The villagers‟ hopes for the future revolved around

getting access to enough agricultural land to be able to make a living by farming. This reality had

no place in either the project document or in the understandings of the NGO workers at various

levels who supported the community forestry programme. In practice, the community forestry

project site was located 6 kilometers from the village on a route rarely travelled by villagers, and

was reportedly being sold off by local authorities (the commune chief acting in a private capacity)

by the end of the research.

Buon village, located in a rice field landscape in central southern Cambodia had also undergone a

decade of economic success, and this was also culminating in a period of uncertainty by the end

of the research. Unlike Bey, however, the village economy in Buon did not revolve around local

resources but around economic opportunity in the national capital Phnom Penh, particularly

through work for young women in garment factories, young men in the construction industry and

older men working as motorcycle taxi and tuk-tuk rivers. At the time of the last research visit the

global economic downturn was resulting in garment factory closures and the suspension of work

at many construction sites resulting in anxiety about future livelihoods for the villagers.

Systematic land titling had been promoted as enabling the transformation of smallholder farming

into a third engine of economic growth by giving smallholders security of tenure which would

lead to: increased investment in their land; increased ability to use the land as collateral (which

could then be used to raise capital for agriculture or other economic activities); a more efficient

land market which would put farm land in the hands of the most efficient farmers. In Buon,

however, the titling did not have any substantial effect in the village because tenure was already

secure, land was already being traded, and people were already able to secure loans against their

land at rates that were not noticeably different to those after titling. There was even a possibility

that the formal land registration system was might be making buyers of land less secure: neither

of the cases was clear cut, but we did encounter two instances where people who had bought land

were then encountering difficulties from the people they had sold to who were making it hard for

them to dispose of the land that they had bought as they wished. Rice holdings in the village were

less than a hectare per household, which is about the national average. Even if systematic land

titling had made a significant impact on rice farming in Buon it still would not have had a major

effect on the village economy given that rice production constituted such a small fraction of

villagers‟ livelihoods.

In each of the three studies, therefore, the findings were consistent in showing that the property

rights interventions were only able to proceed in places where tenure was already secure and

where there was not strong demand for land and land-based resources from non-local actors.

Meanwhile, the misrepresentation of rural people‟s livelihoods was vividly reminiscent of the

misrepresentations encountered in the works of Ferguson and Porter et al. in Chapter 1.

Households who depended overwhelmingly on remittance incomes from Phnom Penh, whose rice

production was insufficient even to put rice on their plates and whose tenure was secure, were

Page 231: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

213

characterised (or caricatured) as smallholder farmers constrained by tenure insecurity from being

the potential third engine of economic growth for the country. Households whose incomes were

dominated by logging and by agricultural labour, and whose future aspirations revolved around

their ability to secure agricultural land for their households, were portrayed as „forest-dependent‟

and needing to secure „historical‟ and „traditional‟ livelihoods that had in fact long since been

extinguished from their everyday realities and their aspirations by deforestation.

The remainder of this chapter analyses the findings of this thesis, firstly in relation to the specific

case of property rights interventions in Cambodia, and then in relation to how this case might

contribute to research agendas and debates on the Western development industry as a whole.

7.3 Explaining Geographies of Evasion in Property Rights Interventions in Cambodia

The discussions on the findings of this thesis in relation to livelihoods and property rights

interventions in Cambodia will be structured around three issues: firstly, how and why have

„geographies of evasion‟ occurred? Secondly, why have livelihoods been misrepresented?

Thirdly, to what extent have these interventions created opportunities for agency: for other

objectives – possibly humbler ones, or possibly quite different unanticipated ones – to be

fulfilled.

7.3.1 Development Industry Overreach and Geographies of Evasion

The ingredients of the „geography of evasion‟ described in the findings above are: a landscape

broadly dichotomised into secure and insecure areas; a process of diversion, whereby some

interventions that would bestow security are channelled away from insecure areas; a process of

dilution whereby some interventions that would bestow security are diluted such that the

„security‟ bestowed in insecure areas is not substantive; a facade whereby indicators supported by

simplified and exaggerated narratives are used to portray programmes as successfully enabling

development by providing enhanced security of tenure.

The proposition made in this thesis is that this geography of evasion is triggered by the attempt

by the development industry to support policies which the Cambodian political elite do not

support. Specifically, that the geography of evasion is a result of development agencies

attempting to support the Cambodian state to extend rights to people that the political elite does

not want to extend and would not be willing to support. Here, of course, context is king. In

certain places and at certain times, the political elite is happy to grant such rights.

This proposition links back to the theories of shadow states and developmental states,

encountered in chapter 2, which suggest that the political elite will always be engaged in a

political project (whether one of self-enrichment or of national improvement or a combination of

the two). My proposition is that one of the fundamental reasons that some people in Cambodia

are insecure in their tenure over land is that the political elite have an interest in them being

insecure. Any attempt to extend security to them will risk undermining other political projects

and will therefore be resisted.

Within the case studies in this thesis, the land which is insecurely held is found in the forest

village of Bey. And as we also saw, from the very first day of the research, the State was not

Page 232: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

214

offering protection to informal settlers. On the contrary, it was instead threatening them with

dispossession. Neither was the meeting on 26th

July 2006 in Bey when the Forestry

Administration officials informed many of the villagers that they had no right to live there, and

that the forest must be allowed to grow back a one-off. In Kracheh province alone it was

replicated in over a hundred other villages in 21 different communes (Interview 168). Villagers in

Bey also recalled that similar meetings had occurred in previous years. The authorities, then, were

deliberately allowing a form of tenure which was both temporary and insecure. Populations were

allowed to stay, but they were not allowed the right to stay. They could use the land, but on the

understanding that they might be moved on in the future.

The situation of authorities allowing people to settle, but reminding them that they do not have

the right to settle is, of course, reminiscent of the informal urban settlements that I mentioned at

the end of Chapter 4. Allowing temporary but insecure settlement of land can be seen as a way

for shadow/development state authorities to effectively occupy that land until a suitable

opportunity for disposing of it profitably arises. This has clear advantages for the officials

controlling the land. They are able to establish occupation of the land without needing to hire

guards or to defend themselves against accusations of warehousing land or holding it for

speculative purposes. Rather, by maintaining or renewing their own authority to evict the

temporary settlers (through occasional reminders such as the eviction meeting in Bey), and by

keeping the settlers on the land, they are able to exclude potential competitors from it.

Furthermore, they also have the opportunity to extract informal rents from these informally

settled populations. In this setting, De Soto-style arguments claiming that titling is enabling

formerly „dead‟ assets to become „live‟ by enabling them to be used to secure loans, appear naive.

The poor here are not sitting on their own dead property; rather they are sitting on the land that

the elite have earmarked as their own. They are not sitting on their own dead capital, but rather

are sitting on the live capital of the elite, keeping it warm until the right business deal comes

along. To formalise poor people‟s property rights here would, from that viewpoint, not be a

formalisation, but rather a redistribution of land from the very powerful to the least powerful.

My point here is not to engage in a discussion about the rights and wrongs of how the political

elite govern Cambodia. My point is rather that this is the way that Cambodia is currently

governed and that the development industry as currently constituted has little leverage over that.

To some extent this was being quietly acknowledged in the implementation of LMAP. The

village being removed from the titling process in McAndrew‟s study area provided an example of

how the titling process avoided exactly those situations where people‟s tenure was not secure.

When the Forestry Administration official sat in the schoolroom in front of the villagers in Bey,

and in very calm and reasonable tones explained to them that they were to be evicted, he did so

not as a rogue element, but as an agent of the shadow/developmental state. He held up a copy of

the Social Concession Sub-decree (Royal Government of Cambodia, 2003) which had been

drafted with international assistance with the aim of redistributing land and by doing so providing

safety nets for the poor.

Highlighting the phenomenon of geographies of evasion, then, is not a challenge to the

development industry to stop avoiding insecurity and instead to try and force the

shadow/development state to enforce poor people‟s rights against its own interests. There is

nothing in this research that suggests that such a move would in any way be successful. Rather,

Page 233: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

215

the point here is that, given that interventions will only be allowed to operate in certain places (in

the case of land titling) and to extend certain limited rights (in the case of community forestry),

that those limitations be acknowledged.

7.3.2 Bigging Up and Dumbing Down: Are Misrepresentation and Simplification

Necessary?

The EU/Oxfam Protecting Tropical Forest project document invested heavily in what I have

termed the „forest caricature‟ of resourceful forest-dependent, forest-dwelling people waiting for

the opportunity to restore their livelihoods by having the forests on which they traditionally

depend returned to them. Meanwhile, the „rural caricature‟ of rural people as smallholder farmers

whose economic potential is ready to be unlocked by integration into wider economies were

deployed in the claims made for LMAP, most notably in the World Bank‟s (2006) poverty

assessment for Cambodia.

These caricatures patently misrepresent and (at best) simplify the livelihoods of rural

Cambodians. The circulation of such misrepresentations would not surprise Mosse (2005), who in

Cultivating Development, a detailed decade-long study of a project in India on which Mosse

himself worked, argued that project documents are the means by which support is recruited from

a range of actors for projects. In order to bring together quite diverse agendas and positions it is

necessary and to be expected that project documents are ambiguous and (in relation to what is

possible to implement) over-ambitious. Policy, according to Mosse‟s conclusions does not direct

implementation. Rather it is the contrary – policy follows implementation, finding ways to

rationalise situations and decisions such that policies (and the coalitions of actors that they

enable) can be maintained.

This two-step interpretation of policy – that it firstly uses ambitious claims and ambiguity in

order to recruit broad-based support for an intervention, and secondly that it deploys

rationalisations from the experiences of implementation in order to reproduce itself whilst always

in fact following rather than leading events – in some respects matches well with experience in

Cambodia.

Many of the documents relating to LMAP contained great ambiguity. As I have shown, the

project document itself refers both to the tenure insecurity caused by people with military and

political connections, at the same time as plotting a course for itself that will avoid disputes. The

2007 Equity Report incorporated, side-by-side, the most overblown exaggerated claims for land

titling (based on the assumption that issuing title to a piece of agricultural land would result in a

73% improvement in yield over the same piece of land without title), at the same time as making

points about the difficulties of implementing the project in places where it might make a

difference which were entirely in line with the findings presented in this thesis. This surely is

precisely the sort of ambiguity that Mosse had in mind. The theoretical potential of titling to

facilitate land markets would appeal to neo-liberal tastes; the vision of smallholder farmers

strengthened and secured in their tenure would appeal to those whose vision of development

stresses risk aversion and the provision of social welfare; the framing of Cambodian tenure

insecurity in terms of neo-patrimonial relations and differentiated geography appeals to those

who know the country and the challenges it presents.

Page 234: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

216

The major critique of community forestry coming out of this thesis is that it harnesses two

agendas – one of forest preservation and another of livelihood improvement, which, certainly in

the case of Bey, are directly contradictory, but are presented as though they were a harmonious

unity. In Mosse‟s understanding, of course, this is exactly what policy formulations are expected

to do at the outset of a programme. By this means it is possible to recruit the enthusiastic support

of individuals and institutions committed to forest conservation and biodiversity, as well as

recruiting the support of individuals and institutions committed to poverty reduction and the

rights of forest-dwelling people.

Likewise, once implementation is underway, policies can then be reframed in accordance with

operational experience. Arguably we were seeing this in the arguments of community forestry

advocates who explained that there were many reasons for supporting community forestry, that it

might eventually prove beneficial for livelihoods in ten or fifteen years, but that communities

might well value forests for other reasons – as burial sites or habitats for local spirits or deities.

This could also be seen in the beginnings of a shift in the rationalisations for land titling which

seemed to be taking an unexpected turn away from market orientations. During the final research

trip for this thesis, technical advisors at the Ministry of Land Management, Urban Planning and

Construction were beginning to discuss the possibilities of more state-led interventions that might

be facilitated by land registration – specifically the possibility that some form of reorganisation

and rationalisation of smallholdings at village level might be achieved141

. For Mosse, the fact that

subsequent registration of land transactions was never realistic in the context of existing

Cambodian administrative norms, is not the point so much as that the promise of subsequent

registration and a functioning land market was necessary in order to recruit support for land

administration policies.

While Mosse‟s account is a convincing one, it remains profoundly dissatisfying. It replaces the

thinly-disguised outrage of Porter et al. (1991, pp. 197-198) at the misrepresentations of the

Magarini project document (see chapter 1) with a rationalised acceptance. The policy documents

supporting the activities in Bey and Buon in this thesis deployed win-win scenarios and policy

simplifications which implied that, with just a small amount of institutional engineering, latent

capacities inherent in rural Cambodians (whether in forest or rice field landscapes) could

transform their lives and livelihoods. Community forestry might enable villagers‟ to achieve the

„historic‟ and „traditional‟ control they once had over their environment and its resources;

systematic land titling might prevent land-grabbing and expropriation. The cases in this study

have demonstrated how outrageous these claims were. They have also demonstrated how the

maintenance of these claims has created a facade behind which the inability of programmes to

make a difference was concealed, at least for one project cycle or two. It would seem mistaken to

lose the sense of outrage here. More to the point, it is necessary to ask the question again, why?

Why do development projects need to be oversold in order to get funded? The answers are to

some degree well-known, and the brief sampling of the institutional economics literature on

development interventions in Chapter 2 highlighted them: the need to compete for funds (and

141

The five or six plots a rural household typically owns are usually rather small and placed in different locations in

the village. This has the advantage of enabling households to spread risk by having land at different heights, and

therefore no household is unduly vulnerable to the inevitable floods and droughts afflicting an extremely flat, rain-

fed landscape. Consolidation of land into larger plots would potentially enable economies of scale and efficiency

savings if it could be done in ways that did not undermine the security/insurance of multiple sites.

Page 235: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

217

therefore to portray interventions as low-risk, high-return), and the need to demonstrate success

(and therefore to find indicators that link to the bold – oversold – claims made during the fund-

raising required to get the intervention off the ground).

This thesis provides an example of the way that the need to make unrealistic claims for

interventions shapes discussions of those interventions at an unrealistic level. During the writing

of this thesis, the World Bank continued to add lustre to the claims made for its interventions –

press releases and newsletters were issued with ladies sitting in villages telling the world about

the huge difference that land titles had made to their lives (e.g. World Bank, 2007a). One answer

I received to written questions (which were sent not only to the World Bank but also to the

Ministry of Land Management and to advisors supported by German and Finnish assistance),

tended to substantiate the sort of analysis provided by Mosse:

On the other hand perhaps it was the understood gap between what emerges in project documents

and what people expect to do under a project that allowed LMAP to proceed at all. That is to say

the project document created a vision of a project for a particular audience - not one that was

ever going to be implemented as described (A source close to the LMAP Project,19th March

2010).

Is there a scenario where interventions could be presented without being oversold in this way?

Where expectations could be pitched at a realistic level, and a degree of failure or compromise

could be built into those expectations? Must developing country contexts be simplified and

caricatured and development industry interventions overhyped in order to satisfy donor agency

desk officers, donor country politicians and the donor public? As a member of that public today,

and remembering my first awareness of being a member of that public thirty years ago in England

I know one answer to that question. Otherwise, it remains beyond the scope of this thesis to

discuss the nature of the Western demand for development industry services.

If there is such a gap between the world as described in the policy simplifications (including the

rural caricatures and forest caricatures deployed by agencies in this thesis), and if the

implementation of policy involves re-working and reproducing these simplifications, what are the

consequences of this for agency? How do development workers negotiate the tension between

the world of the project document, which structures their incentives, and the real world whose

influences permeate their everyday lives through newspapers and through everyday conversations

and observations? And does the space opened up by interventions, even if they cannot

realistically make real their claims, nevertheless open up possibilities for intended beneficiaries to

shape unintended benefits or opportunities for themselves?

7.3.3 Unintended Effects and Space for Creative Agency?

Mosse‟s view of policy as catching up with implementation rather than shaping it, and being

about recruiting assemblies of actors with divergent agendas rather than describing in realistic

terms what is likely to occur was not unremittingly pessimistic. He saw potential for interventions

to be redeemed by the opportunities taken by people in the spaces created by interventions.

Is it possible that the answer to the question posed by this thesis about the relationship between

interventions and the livelihoods of rural people is that the relationship is healthy and positive,

although not in ways that were anticipated in the project documents? Were development workers

able to see the project documents for what they were, see reality for what it was, and find ways to

Page 236: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

218

be of service in the large gap between the two? My questions to development professionals (see

Appendix 9) failed to shed light on these questions from the viewpoint of development

professionals and government officials working on LMAP.

Otherwise, in the case studied the answers to this varied, and were partly related to the argument

of overreach. Overreach in this thesis as well as having a more general meaning of development

industry attempts to achieve goals that are beyond its capacities and resources, is used specifically

to refer to cases where development industry interventions try to go beyond what the host country

political elite is comfortable with. Systematic land titling in Buon in particular (and in the sorts of

places where it is implemented in Cambodia) is not in overreach in either sense. While there is

clearly overreach in terms of the sort of expectations that have been manufactured regarding

transformation of tenure security and lifting hundreds of thousands of people out of poverty, these

expectations have not filtered out to the villages where the titling is implemented and do not

define the expectations that govern the daily work lives of the registration teams.

The titles are popular with government and with beneficiaries, who see them as worth paying for.

The programme is well-resourced and well-managed, with experiences from earlier programmes

in other countries factored in to its design and new developments, particularly relating to

computerisation and related cost-benefit improvements successfully integrated. The working lives

of the registration teams and the expectations of the villagers fit well with the output orientation

of the project so there were no particular reasons for resistance or for creative initiatives beyond

the scope of the programme. As far as we learned the agency of the registration teams was

exercised very much in line with what would have been expected in the project document.

The development workers involved in community forest field work were in a quite different

situation. Their project was poorly designed, poorly resourced and helplessly ill-fitted to the

situations of the people in the village. To the extent that it raised expectations – and these were

quite high in mid-late 2006, when official recognition was expected and villagers‟ forest patrol

schedules were beginning to be worked out - it utterly failed to meet them. Here, then, was a less

ordered set of circumstances where one might look for initiative and agency to reach out in

unanticipated directions.

As we have seen, however, field level development workers certainly did not become streetwise

opportunists searching for opportunities on behalf of their clients amid the confusion and

dysfunction. The community development worker was so rarely in the village it was unsurprising

that no particular relationships or initiatives were discernable there. Meanwhile, the young Oxfam

field workers, as we have seen, whilst they had never been to Bey, when confronted in interviews

with the scenario of livelihoods which did not match the forest caricature, their response was

characterised by anything but creativity or resistance. They would, they said, try and educate

villages to value their environment. In other words, if the ideas and behaviour of the people did

not fit the project document then the ideas and the behaviour should be changed. A more

sustained exposure to villagers and village realities might well have changed these attitudes, but

this was not an intervention that promised much exposure of even the lowliest field workers to

village realities.

We did not either find much indication of villager agency or new spaces for villager agency

opened up by the interventions. It is possible to speculate on what such „spaces‟ for agency and

Page 237: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

219

new initiative might look like, especially in terms of new networks and relationships created by

the interventions, however it is important to note that we did not find any evidence of these

functioning.

The head of the community forestry committee in Bey had travelled to other provinces and had

met people from a wide range of NGOs in the national capital and in those provinces, as well as

having had some contact with Forestry Administration officials. This potentially gave the village

an extra source of connections and patronage in addition to the deputy village chief‟s

embeddedness in the structures of party and administration, and the rather more haphazard and

illegible connections of the teacher to the alleged relations of the Prime Minister in his business

dealings.

The situation with systematic land titling is comparable. One can imagine that exposure to the

registration teams may give villagers some potential connections or confidence that may lead

them to approach cadastral authorities in a different way in future; the satisfied expectations of

the titling process may lead to a stronger sense of entitlements and an increased likelihood of

villagers taking initiatives to obtain services from land administration offices at a reasonable

price. However, again, in our research we found little evidence of such developments. On the

contrary, even after the positive experience of titling, villagers expectations of paying high and

unpredictable fees if they ever approached district or provincial cadastral offices remained

unchanged. The one villager who regarded himself as having been the victim of injustice had

simply given up despite the fact that he was relatively well-connected and much wealthier than

most villagers.

The idea of resourceful local actors – whether development workers or villagers – finding ways to

appropriate the resources of cumbersome, poorly adapted programmes to better ends is of course

appealing. We did not, however, find any evidence of this occurring in these interventions. That

is possibly in the nature of the intervention. If rather than distributing or redistributing tangible

resources, interventions are „only‟ seeking to change the rules of the game (i.e. to achieve

institutional reform) this may limit the resources and the sorts of opportunities that can be

captured.

Before turning to the possible relevance of the case of property rights interventions in Cambodia

for the development industry – the broader interest that inspired this research – some of the key

implications for systematic land titling and community forestry are drawn out. These do not

necessarily contribute directly to the main arguments of the thesis, but it is hoped that they might

in some way repay the engagement I have received from people working on these activities.

These implications are not framed as detailed, implementable policy or operational

recommendations, but it is hoped nevertheless that they may provide food for thought.

7.3.4 Implications for Systematic Land Titling

The broad argument emerging from this thesis with regard to systematic land titling is that it has

been greatly oversold. This particularly by the World Bank which has suggested that land titling

can improve output per hectare of agricultural land by 73% (World Bank, 2007b, p. 67), and that

titling would be the vital step required to liberate smallholder agriculture from the binding

constraint of tenure insecurity and enable it to become the third engine of economic growth in

Cambodia‟s economy (World Bank, 2006, p. 55 & 74). These claims do not have basis in the

Page 238: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

220

lived reality of Cambodian villagers and they do a disservice to anybody working on land titling

and trying to make a serious evaluation of their efforts.

For debates about land titling to better correspond to reality the experience of Buon suggests that

calculations of the impact/benefits of land titling in rural areas of Cambodia should start with the

assumptions that (1) titling does not impact on tenure security and agricultural productivity, and

(2) transactions of land subsequent to initial registration will not be registered with the cadastral

authorities for the foreseeable future. On the basis of this assumption, calculations of costs and

benefits would then revolve around finding ways to calculate the impact of titling on the terms of

access to credit, and also on the revenues generated by titling. What we are talking about here is

a programme that may make a marginal difference to the terms of access to credit. While this

difference may not even be substantial enough to be noticed by villages, it might nevertheless be

sufficient to cover the minor costs to villages of paying for the titles. Similarly, revenues to

government might demonstrate that land titling comfortably pays for itself.

One general expectation of land titling programmes is that they will facilitate the participation of

non-local purchasers in land markets (Deininger, 2003, p. 33; Markussen, 2006, p. 25) Of

possible interest, and contrary to general expectations regarding land registration programmes

that seek to formalise existing tenure arrangements, is the way in which titling in Buon did not

seem to make it easier for non-locals to participate in the land market. According to our findings,

people who lived in a different village from where they owned land were far more likely to not

receive their title. Furthermore, the cases where people did run into problems because the former

owners‟ names were still on the title were all cases where the owner was resident in a different

village to the location of the plot of land.

This may indicate that LMAP titling in the Cambodian context is not equipped to protect the

interests of non-local land-owners. An alternative proposition, though, partly suggested by the

findings of Deutsch and Makathy is that titling might provide protection to non-local owners, but

only to those non-local owners who belong to the wealthier classes who are able to pay the fees

for subsequent registration. In this sense, the most suitable place to look for impacts of land

titling is not a general comparison between the quasi-formal, locally enforced practices of the

majority of the rural population before and after titling (because they have by and large remained

in the quasi-formal system), but rather to focus particularly on improvements in the system

comparing the segment of the population who used the formal system (via „sporadic‟ land titles)

before titling, and continue to use the formal system by trading their technically superior titles.

This segment of the population are the people who are willing and able to pay taxes or fees of

several hundred dollars to obtain some sort of official authorisation of their land transactions.

Their experiences do not tell us anything about the experiences of the majority of rural people,

who are not willing or able to pay such fees. Nevertheless, if titling has created improvements for

this relatively wealthy section of the population this is nevertheless worth identifying and

documenting and building from, rather than investing efforts in spurious publicity claiming that

land titles are transforming the situations of poor rural people (World Bank, 2007a)

A final specific concern relating to findings from this research has to do with village size. In

Buon, the village was very small and everybody knew each other, and had overwhelmingly lived

there all of their lives. There was a high degree of social cohesion in the village. Most

households were related to the family of the village chief, and wherever you were in the village

Page 239: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

221

you were never more than a five minute walk from any other given house in the village. Villages

of 300 households are not uncommon in Cambodia, and I can think of one village I know well

where the population is stretched along 5 kilometers of road. Villages of 900 households also

exist – these are exceptional, but, for example, Dina in our research team came from one such

village. It is possible that in such villages the ability of the village chief to have sufficient

oversight to enforce security of tenure is more limited than in Buon. It may be that the risk of

appropriations of one villager‟s land by another are more common in such villages, or at least that

it is a more significant concern there. Disaggregating data on land conflicts and insecurity by

village size, as well as conducting qualitative research in much larger villages would be possible

ways to pursue this line of inquiry.

7.3.5 Implications for Community Forestry

A general point which the experiences of Bey suggest when set against the framings of the

EU/Oxfam project document, is the degree to which the effects of deforestation on livelihoods are

both transforming and non-reversible. The idea that „historical‟ or „traditional‟ livelihoods, those

that obtained in Bey sixty years ago for example, are in some way relevant or recoverable

grounds the whole project in a narrative which has no basis in contemporary reality. I hope that

the Deforestation Livelihood Trajectory (see Table 5-8) developed in Chapter 5 of this thesis,

might provide a contribution to ensuring that the implications of deforestations for livelihoods are

less easy to overlook in future livelihoods-oriented forestry interventions.

Three particular challenges for community forestry practice are derived from this thesis. These

relate to prioritising of development agendas, resourcing programmes adequately and engaging

private sector actors.

What we found in this thesis was that people working in community forestry were locked into a

way of thinking and interpreting reality that required livelihoods and forest management to be

mutually supporting objectives. Any other reality did not fit. By being locked into this way of

viewing people and their livelihoods agencies were failing to give themselves any flexibility of

possibility to respond to changing or unexpected situations. This is precisely the phenomenon that

Walker (2004) has documented in Thailand. An agency devoted to improving people‟s

livelihoods, on finding that managing small patches of degraded forest is not a promising strategy

for improving those livelihoods, will look for a better solution. An agency seeking to improve

forest management, discovering that local communities are dedicated to clearing forests for

agricultural use, will look for a different forest management strategy. Agencies, that do not know

what their priorities are beyond reproducing community forestry, will be immobilised by

situations where one or both of the forest/people equation is not well-served by trying to

implement a community forestry project. So one provocation from this research is that all

agencies involved in community forestry should know what their bottom-line commitment is –

either to forests or to livelihoods. Obviously it works much better and easier when these two are

in harmony, but organisations need to be able to respond when they are not.

The second very basic point regards adequate resourcing of interventions. Community

development in Bey was a one-person operation. And the one person was not a development

worker. There may be sites in Cambodia such as those identified by Poffenburger (2006) in

Chapter 4 where communities are already managing their own resource, and therefore an

Page 240: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

222

intervening agency does not need to do much. In a place like Bey where there is no such

community management already in operation, where there are conflicting interests within the

village, where powerful interests outside the village also engaged and where a resource has not

yet even been clearly identified, then a serious attempt to achieve change must surely require full-

time or near full-time engagement of at least one member of staff for a number of months. It

seems unlikely that however it was resourced that community forestry would have succeeded in

making a tangible difference to livelihoods in Bey. Other forms of community organisation,

however, might have some potential. Projects that assign responsibility for community

organisation in 28 villages to two development workers are surely doomed to fail?

Finally, and this may not be easy to operationalise given existing trajectories, is the sense from

experience in Bey that the private company with the concession agreement is a far more

promising development partner than the Forestry Administration. The Okhnyaa representing the

company in Chhlong grew up in the district and was a childhood friend of people in the area

including some of the Bey villagers. Forestry Administration officials, meanwhile, are rotated on

two year postings: the official who threatened villagers in Bey with eviction had only been in post

for two months and within two years he had been moved to another province. The Okhnyaa is a

rich man whose future is assured and who can afford to be generous. The Forestry Administration

officials are mid-ranking bureaucrats anxious to secure a future for themselves and dependent on

the patronage of their Forestry Administration seniors. In contrast to the Forestry Administration,

private companies with concessions to carry out logging or agricultural operations in state forests

do not have an institutional link to the concept of forests and to land being classified as forest. If

organisations are wishing to help poor people to achieve more secure tenure over agricultural

land in concessions it may be easier and more realistic to do so within the mini-fiefdom of a

concession than within the dysfunctional bureaucracy of Forestry Administration „managed‟

forest. Certainly in the case of the Casotim representative, he was prepared to approve households

being allocated 5 hectares of agricultural land each for agricultural plots. It is inconceivable that

any Forestry Administration official would ever write off state forest in that way, or that anyone

below the rank of minister would imagine they had the right to. These are all arguments to

suggest that rather than demonising concessionaires (and with some justification too – it was

soldiers paid by the Okhnyaa who were throwing villagers off their land and demanding

payments to return their motorcycles and equipment), and approaching them at arm‟s length via

the Forestry Administration, that it might be worthwhile to try and find ways to seek direct

working relationship with powerful figures within these private companies who have gained

control of state forest land.

After that brief digression, we now turn to the question of whether the research aim in this thesis

has indeed proved relevant for generating lessons with respect to the broader research interest.

7.4 Broader Relevance of this Thesis for the Development Industry

The aim of this project was to explore the relationship between property rights interventions and

the livelihoods of rural Cambodians. The broader interest motivating that was in the relationship

between development industry interventions in rural areas in general and the livelihoods of

people are intended to benefit. The purpose of this section is to discuss whether the case of

property rights interventions in Cambodia as presented in this research is relevant and significant

for the broader development industry. By relevant, I mean (as outlined in chapter 3), might the

Page 241: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

223

case of property rights interventions in Cambodia „represent‟ dynamics in the broader

development industry? And by significant I mean are the findings non-obvious and non-trivial?

Property rights interventions in Cambodia were found to either be located away from sites of

tenure insecurity, or only be allowed into them in diluted and precarious forms. This I have

termed a geography of evasion, and theorised it as a form of (shadow/developmental) state

resistance which is triggered by development industry attempts to initiate policies which go

beyond what the political elite is comfortable with. In the case of property rights interventions in

Cambodia this is proposed to be significant because the facades of success associated with these

geographies of evasion mean that the development industry inadvertently supports interventions

which have little impact on the livelihoods of the poor. Energy that might be spent on better

serving the needs of the poor is instead directed towards maintaining and defending the facade.

Is this a model that might have broader relevance? Might it explain and predict situations outside

Cambodia? Might it furthermore be applicable not only to property rights interventions but to

interventions in other sectors? My contention is that if the geographies of evasion thesis is

convincing for the case of Cambodia that it is also likely to be applicable to some degree in many

of the other countries that host development interventions.

The idea of a shadow/developmental state in Cambodia is derived from experiences of States in

Africa and (East and Southeast) Asia respectively. More generally, faced by foreign projects

which combine financial infusions with propositions for how they should run their countries

surely many of the world‟s political elites would react by accepting the money but then quietly

ensuring that the policy propositions are selectively applied such that they do not challenge elite

projects.

A dichotomised landscape with a settled smallholder lowland and an unsettled, insecure upland

with commercial concessions, deforestation and migration is characteristic not only of Cambodia

but much of the rest of Southeast Asia (2001). In Africa, Ferguson (2005) also portrayed a

dichotomised landscape which featured resource rich hotspots and hopped over areas in-between.

It would certainly be feasible to expect that initiatives allowed in the hopped over would be

shepherded away from the resource rich areas. Yet more broadly, the whole theory of Uneven

Development (Harvey, 2006; Smith, 2008) suggests a landscape where zones of accumulation are

carefully protected by political elites who will seek to protect the interests of capital in those

zones.

The only remaining ingredient is a development industry which is first prepared to push the

policy envelope (to initiate the resistance which provokes the geography of evasion) and second

which is susceptible to reporting success on the basis of quantitative outputs without spatial

modification (thereby creating the facade of success which enables the geography of evasion to

be sustained).

In other words, the key components of the geographies of evasion thesis are ones that are

commonly found throughout the parts of the world where the development industry intervenes.

The geography of evasion thesis therefore provides a relevant framework for discussion of what

happens when the development industry goes into overreach, and provides a working hypothesis

for that case.

Page 242: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

224

We easily think of land and forest rights interventions in spatial terms. However, all activities

occur in space and the geographies of evasion thesis could be applied to other sectors and at other

scales. In a health district, for example, donors might try and advocate a rights-based approach to

health services. In that same district the government counterparts might also be health service

managers who are profiting from informal fees in the sector. The geographies of evasion thesis

suggests that attempts at introducing public health services and vaccination campaigns in rural

villages might prove successful (there being little profit to be made by elites from these activities

in these territories). In treatment hospitals, however, attempts to introduce predictable and

affordable fees, or even free treatment, might well be subject to diversion and dilution. The final

ingredient, an insistent donor pushing the envelope and deploying generalising theories and

policy simplifications to provide a facade that conceals spatial differences and the political

economy of „development partner‟ engagements might also be present, although it might, one

hopes, be more or less prevalent in different sectors.

7.5 Implications of Geographies of Evasion for Development Industry Policies

Tania Murray Li draw a distinct line between the role of critic and that of programmer, and in the

context of The Will to Improve refused to cross the line to becoming a programmer for fear of

diluting her contributions as a critic. If I could recommend a programmatic solution to

operationalise the policy implications of this thesis I would have no qualms about doing so.

Unfortunately, the policy implications will be difficult to swallow, and it seems to be getting

ahead of myself to suggest solutions following on from a problem analysis that many in the

development industry would contest.

Like Li, I conclude that the development industry is poorly equipped to engage in political

struggles which involve opposing the projects of a host nation political elite. The difference is

possibly one of emphasis. She emphasises that this space is rightly occupied by other actors, and

named opposition political parties and social movements in that regard. My emphasis is more that

development industry attempts to engage in this space are – regardless of the moral judgements

involved – wasteful. Attempting to introduce rights into countries where the political elite does

not have a genuine project to enforce those rights is to invite a series of far-fetched

misrepresentations of the actors involved, and to generate a quite predictable scenario where the

resources invested are devoted to maintaining the credibility of the scenario rather than delivering

any substantive change.

The key word, however, is genuine. While it is easy in theory to talk about a political elite having

a fixed position and its own projects, it is much more difficult in practice to work out what the

substantive relationships and deals in the shadow political economy might be. Governments and

administrations comprise of many different people and interests. Donor representatives and

technical advisors will not experience such sharp dividing lines. They will have counterparts,

possibly educated, ambitious and energetic, who seem to potentially be part of a constituency for

reform. Development industry workers may even have ambitions to win the ear of Ministers and

other senior figures and convince them of the value and wisdom of the development industry

agenda.

Page 243: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

225

In the context of room for interpretation and ambiguity regarding constituencies for reform within

many states, this thesis will not, in isolation, persuade many development industry actors that the

industry is in overreach. Each individual situation is fraught with the sort of ambiguity that I have

just tried to illustrate, and therefore provides plenty of room for interpretation. This room for

interpretation can allow development industry actors to rationalise continuation of their strategies.

Meanwhile, as noted in chapter 2, a movement to retrench would be to reverse the trends over the

decades which have been to broaden the mandate over time: from needs to rights; from growth to

institutions, governance and democracy, from projects to programmes to policies to whole-of-

budget comprehensive frameworks and plans. The impulse to control what is beyond its control

runs deep in the industry. Each successive paradigm casts its net wider. To suggest that the

industry should find a completely new way to respond to its failures, by narrowing rather than

broadening the agenda, is to demand a fundamental change.

However, that is the policy implication that I think should be drawn from this thesis. The

development industry should take far more seriously the implications of trying to go beyond

where a host national government is comfortable. In general, if it is seeking to be effective it

should be looking not to constantly push host governments to go further (with its normal

repertoire of ventriloquism and ambiguously broad policy agendas) but should rather look to

retrench. It should be far less insistent in its promotion of its own agendas. This is not necessarily

because they are bad agendas, but rather because it is not plausible for the Western development

industry to achieve things against the wishes of the political elites of the countries that host its

interventions. Development industry representatives should, this research suggests, be far more

prepared to sit down and listen to the formal and informal positions of host country leaders142

.

The preference for the development industry is for being guided by internationally defined rights

agendas, rather than host government defined needs agendas. In this context, for anyone

convinced by the arguments of this thesis, a second legitimate response involves taking more

seriously what is required if a development intervention is to go beyond the comfort zone of the

host government. This is not an area where agendas can be advanced by short-term, output-

oriented, technical projects (the case of the EU/Oxfam community forestry project in Bey being a

small but vivid case in point). In countries where political opponents and union leaders get

attacked and sometimes killed, where key players maintain alliances through gifts and business

opportunities worth tens of millions of dollars, and where alliances are secured through marriage

between the families of key potential allies and opponents, the pronouncements and the

investments of the development industry will, for the most part, be peripheral. Nevertheless, if the

industry is going to try and have influence in this environment there are ways that it can increase

its chances. Twenty-five year projects with plenty of flexibility built in, would give a far better

chance of engagement than five year projects locked into a rigid output schedule. Employing

people who might stay in post for much of the twenty-five year project, or at least rotating people

such that they have two or three five-year postings within the twenty-five years would likewise

begin to suggest a serious agenda. None of this is to suggest that the development industry might

become a serious player in the context of the other forces in play. It might, however, yield the sort

142

Some would suggest that the Paris Declaration and the aid harmonization agenda constitutes an attempt to give

primacy to host nation priorities. I tend to draw the opposite conclusion – that attempting to unite all donors behind

one plan owes more to a desire to gain control over agendas and strengthen donor negotiating positions with host

nation governments than it does to a desire to allow them to set the agenda.

Page 244: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

226

of personal relationships, contextual knowledge and time frames to enable a serious engagement

with a particular element of policy reform143

.

If that is a somewhat broad interpretation of „policy implications‟ which takes us quite a long way

from the specific empirical findings of this thesis, the research implications, with which I

conclude, can bring the discussion to a more specific intermediate level.

7.6 Implications for Research

I begin with the suggestion that the geographies of evasion thesis could be used to structure a

research agenda for critical geographies of development intervention, and finally I then leave the

reader with a question more specifically tied to the findings of this research.

7.6.1 A Research Agenda Shaped by Geographies of Evasion

Geographies of evasion, where development industry solutions are located away from the

problems that they claim to address, are presented in this thesis as being symptomatic of the

development industry being in overreach. And in the terms of this thesis, that means that the

development industry pushes agendas which are beyond what the host nation government is

comfortable with. In rights terms, then, the development industry tries to extend rights which host

nation governments have no intention of enforcing.

In this section I suggest a research agenda for critical geographies of development intervention

with three components (see Table 7-1).

1. The development industry in overreach

2. Alternatives to the development industry in overreach

3. The development industry not in overreach (in host country elite‟s comfort zone)

Item one on the agenda, “The development industry in overreach” would continue the same

direction as this thesis. It would examine more cases where the development industry appears to

be “pushing the envelope of policy reform”144

and look to see whether that overreach has resulted

in geographies of evasion of the type mentioned in this thesis. One item on the international

development agenda at present which presents the development industry in overreach is Reduced

Emissions from Deforestation and Degradation (REDD). This is clearly a western agenda which

is being pushed onto reluctant host country governments. If the arguments in this thesis are

correct, the consequence will be that REDD interventions will be diverted to places where there is

no deforestation, and meanwhile deforestation will continue for as long as it constitutes and elite

143

In some respects the discussion here might seem too influenced by Cambodian experience. Throughout my

engagement the ruling party has comfortably retained a grip on power, and development industry leverage has

always (notwithstanding „aid dependence‟ discussions referred to in Chapter 4) been able to resist development

industry overtures with some ease, even more so now that oil money and Chinese patronage appear to provide

alternatives to Western assistance. Such conditions may not be typical. I have, for example, little knowledge of the

impacts of structural adjustment on Africa and whether that managed to overcome elite resistance. Again, though, a

geographies of evasion hypothesis would provide a framework for analyzing those questions. 144

The phrase is borrowed from Shabbir Cheema who used it at a meeting at the Sida offices in Stockhom on 3rd

May 2010 when praising Sida for its leading role in promoting rights-based agenda and ensuring that the

development industry included governance and democratisation in its concerns.

Page 245: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

227

political project. The suggestion that there should be a capacity building and policy development

phase in a staged approach to REDD provides the opportunity for a temporary facade of progress

to be erected to cover such a geography of evasion. Given that REDD is a global project, it might

even be possible to see geographies of evasion at a global scale. The recent allocation by the

Government of Norway of up to 250 million USD to Guyana, a country without any reported

deforestation, for avoiding deforestation between 2010 and 2015 (so the solution travelling to a

place where the problem does not exist) does suggest that REDD may be a productive source of

geographies of evasion (Henders, 2010). Or more to the point, that geographies of evasion may

be an effective critical lens with which to analyse REDD.

Table 7-1: Research Agenda suggested by the Geograhies of Evasion thesis

Item Hypothesis Relation to host

nation political

elite

1 The development industry in overreach will be ineffective and will

generate geographies of evasion, where solutions will avoid problems and

facades will conceal this evasion and present success.

Discomfort

2 The development industry does not attempt to push government into

reform positions, other actors such as opposition parties and social

movements will play a substantially different role, leading to substantially

different outcomes.

Discomfort

3 The development industry, by operating comfortably within what is

acceptable to both official government policy and the agendas of the elite

is able to use its comparative advantages in technical aspects of poverty

reduction and make a substantial difference to the lives and livelihoods of

the people it intends to benefit.

Comfort

Source: Author’s derivation

Item two on the research agenda, “Alternatives to the Development Industry in overreach”

proposes enquiries into what would happen if the development industry did retrench. If the

western development industry stopped trying to extend rights that host country governments were

not prepared to enforce, and if it stopped giving unasked for advice (or stopped ventriloquising

requests for advice and then responding to them), would that change the political terrain? To

what extent would that change transnational political activities and movements? Li suggested that

development industry activities are taking space that would be rightfully occupied by opposition

political parties and by social movements. Is this true? Is development really an Anti-Politics

Machine, or is it more of a „doesn‟t make much difference either way‟ machine?

If item one builds up a case for the development industry being overextended and ineffective

because of its overreach, item two will provide insights into what will happen in the spaces left

after the development industry retreats from overreach. It is obviously not easy to research a

counterfactual, but there are historical and geographical possibilities to look at places from which

the development industry is absent or has retreated and to analyse reform movements there.

Item 3. The Development Industry Not in Overreach. Overreach has been linked in this thesis to

misrepresentation and failure. However, it is not likely that all development industry failures can

be linked to the industry going beyond where political elites are prepared for it to go. In

Page 246: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

228

Cambodia, for example, rice farming is not something where the political elite have an

accumulation project. If rice farming becomes marginally more secure or marginally more

productive, that does not challenge the interests of the elite. Agricultural extension for

smallholder rice farming is not a project that would exemplify the development industry in

overreach. Development industry interventions here will not need encounter quiet resistance from

elite interests. Rather, the industry will be able to mobilise its full range of technical mastery in

questions of agriculture and of poverty reduction, without having to deal with issues of political

will.

Whilst the hypothesis in such cases would be that the development industry will be able to be far

more effective in the absence of „political problems‟, we know enough from Chapter 1 to

understand that there is no reason to be over-optimistic about this possibility. However, other

factors than elite politics will explain success and failure here. Again, I think that critical

development geographies are well placed to identify these factors. Changes in rice farming

practice in the past decade could be mapped, and agricultural extension activities over the same

decade could be mapped. One could then look to see to what extent there is any relationship

between the geographical distribution of changes in agricultural practice and the geographical

distribution of agricultural extension activities.

While not all development failure is because of overreach, it may be very valuable analytically to

separate development industry in overreach from development industry operating well within the

comfort zones of host country political elites. Of course, even when not in overreach in the sense

that used in this thesis, there is much potential for overreach in any development journey that

involves people, technologies and finance travelling from the West to places like Cambodia in

order to improve rice farming.

7.6.2 A Simpler Question (with No Easy Answers)

The „geography of evasion‟ findings of this thesis have been linked to propositions about

development being in overreach in relation to host country political will, and to the idea of

„facades‟ as explaining how geographies of evasion may be able to occur despite being

predictable, and to persist despite being quite observable. All of this suggests a research focus on

the development industry, and indeed on host country governments. It suggests an opportunity for

critical research to contribute to ensuring that development policy is generated with far more

awareness of what the nature of the industry is, what its intrinsic limitations are, as well as the

context specific limitations of interventions in any given country at any given time.

As we saw in Chapter 1, Ferguson‟s first explanation of misrepresentation before he cast it into a

Foucauldian frame, was that the development industry needed to describe a world that was

amenable to the sort of solutions that it could provide. An alternative way to interpret the

contribution of this thesis is to read it as disrupting such simplifications and misrepresentations.

After reading this thesis it should no longer be quite as easy for development industry actors in

Cambodia or anywhere else to deploy the „rural caricature‟ of isolated, agriculture-dependent

smallholders or the „forest caricature‟ of forest-dwelling people as forest-dependent and forest-

preserving. My conclusion in reviewing Thaba-Tseka and Magarini experiences in Chapter 1 was

that a well-informed, historicised, re-politicised description of the contexts for those projects

would not have generated ideas for improving the design of the projects, but would rather have

Page 247: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

229

ensured that they would never have been implemented. Having read the accounts of Bey and

Buon in this thesis, what do you think could or should be done there? If a fourteen or fifteen year

old boy in England wanted to give some money or time to combat poverty in these two villages,

how do you think the development industry could or should spend his money such that a pound

of it might make ten pence worth of difference in Bey or Buon? And if the development industry

is not a suitable vehicle for that journey, what might the alternative be?

Page 248: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

230

Summary

This study of property rights interventions by the development industry in contemporary rural

Cambodia is motivated by an interest in the relationship between development interventions and

the livelihoods of poor people.

A departure point for the thesis was case study research from the 1990s which showed how the

development industry misrepresented the lives and livelihoods of people in rural areas. Those

misrepresentations overstated the role of agriculture and other local resource based livelihood

activities and understated the importance of labour migration. They also misrepresented rural

areas by depoliticising them, which resulted in depictions of places as unoccupied or without

history. Those earlier studies had taken place in an era when integrated rural development

projects were at the forefront of development intervention. Three decades later, when the

fieldwork for this thesis took place, institutional development set in a context of support to

sectors and budgets at national level had replaced projects as the primary modes of development

assistance. Property rights have been at the fore of this institutional turn in development

intervention, drawing inspiration from theoreticians as diverse as Hernan de Soto and Elinor

Oström.

This thesis used the case of property rights interventions in Cambodia, and their relationship to

the lives and livelihoods of poor rural people to ask whether, with a new approach and three

decades of experience, the development industry was still repeating the same patterns of

misrepresentation and failure. Had the lessons of past experience and the institutional turn

resulted in any change from the old pathologies? The aim of the study was therefore:

To describe and explain the relationship between property rights interventions and the

livelihoods of the rural poor in Cambodia.

The study was approached as a critical geography of development intervention. This incorporated

three elements: studies of the spatial distribution of interventions (intentional development) in

relation to key features of the political economy/ecology (immanent development);

contextualised studies of place providing an analytical lens through which to view the

generalising claims of theory and policy; a conceptualisation of interventions as journeys which

facilitate analysis of the interests and discourses at different locations and times which determine

which interventions travel to which places and why. The research consisted of three cases studies.

A national case study of Cambodia enabled regional differences in tenure insecurity to be

analysed in combination with the geographical spread of two property rights interventions,

systematic land titling and community forestry, designed to address tenure insecurity. The

specific questions that structured the national analysis were thus:

1. Where in rural Cambodia is tenure insecurity a problem? Why?

2. Where in Cambodia have tenure rights interventions been implemented? Why?

3. What is the relationship between the geography of tenure insecurity and the geography of

tenure security interventions?

Page 249: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

231

At national level, tenure insecurity was found to have been a problem in almost all provinces in

rural Cambodia. In the transition from a state planned to a market economy there had been no

initial means of legally transferring state land into private hands. Logging concessions and

economic land concessions were authorised at national level, with various degrees of secrecy.

This meant that rural villagers trying to settle former state land were extremely insecure in their

tenure, frequently pitted in conflicts with entrepreneurs who were able to mobilise state officials

and military forces in their support. There were particular tenure security problems in the north-

west of the country which following the conflicts of the 1980s had higher concentrations of both

military forces and returned refugees. In contrast to this apparently general insecurity was the

situation in the lowland rice farming areas of central Cambodia where the majority of the

country‟s population live. Peace had returned to these in the early 1980s and traditional norms

had quickly reasserted themselves in defiance of national policies of communal farming and state

ownership. These norms included privatised tenure (developed by inheritance and use and

enforced by community norms and local authority sanction), and a functioning market for land.

In rural areas systematic land titling by the Land Management and Administration Project

(LMAP) implemented by the Cambodian government with technical and financial support from

the World Bank and the governments of Finland and Germany has only been implemented in the

low land rice farming landscapes which are characterised by security of tenure, partly as the

result of a conscious strategy to avoid conflicts and to have some early successes. This I have

characterised as a geographical diversion of the programme away from its supposed focus. The

programme of community forestry in Cambodia was initiated by diverse national and

international NGOs in Cambodia with financial support from a range of multi-lateral and bilateral

agencies and international NGOs, and has gradually been formalised as a government sanctioned

initiative following the 2003 community forestry sub-decree and the related 2006 Community

Forestry Prakas. Only weak forms of tenure have been granted to communities, and these only

over forest lands that have already been degraded. In other words, where the tenure rights

interventions have been admitted into landscapes characterised by insecurity they have been in

diluted form. Meanwhile, the ability of the programmes to depict success in the fight against

tenure insecurity in the form of number of titles issued, and the number of community forestry

projects achieving formal recognition enables a facade of success to be co-produced by the

sponsors of the interventions both national and international. Behind the facade, however, is a

geography of evasion, where, unable to tackle the problems they set out to confront, interventions

find operational space in the places where those problems barely exist. A key trigger to

geographies of evasion is the tendency to overreach by the development industry, in the sense

that it attempts to promote initiatives for which there is not genuine political support from the

host country government.

While the national level enquiry could yield geographical insights at a regional level, it could not

provide detailed, contextualised account of people‟s livelihoods, nor of the changes wrought by

the interventions on those livelihoods. These were provided by two village studies: one in a

village in forest that had hosted a community forestry project; the other a village in a rice field

landscape where the national systematic land titling programme had been administered. The

questions which informed the village studies were:

Page 250: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

232

1. How do people in the village earn a living?

2. What factors constrain and enable villagers’ livelihoods, and what is the importance of

tenure security/insecurity in those livelihoods?

3. To what extent do tenure security interventions make a difference to rural tenure

security/insecurity and rural livelihoods? Why/why not?

Property rights interventions in Cambodia have been justified in terms of their ability to

transform rural livelihoods. Systematic land titling would bestow tenure security on smallholder

farmers enabling them to invest in their land, to raise capital with the formal credit sector and

potentially to become a third engine of growth for the Cambodian economy. A parallel and partly

conflicting justification was that titling would enable a land market, which would improve

productivity by allocating land to the most efficient farmers. Community forestry, meanwhile,

would enable communities to regain control of resources that they traditionally managed and to

thereby improve both forest management and local livelihoods.

The review of theoretical literature in the thesis established that these potentials are not available

at all times and in all contexts. Land titling must be supplemented by formal institutions that will

enforce ownership, provide credit, authorise transfers at a reasonable cost. Benefits, furthermore,

will only accrue to the extent that these conditions did not already exist prior to land registration

and titling. Common property regimes, meanwhile, rely on the community being able to exclude

outsiders at reasonable cost (otherwise they become open access regimes prone to „tragedies of

the commons‟), and are only likely to succeed when the commons resource is relatively important

in people‟s livelihoods, and when ecological, economic and demographic conditions are

reasonably stable.

In the village studies, the development interventions were found to have little or no influence on

villagers‟ livelihoods. In Bey village, people had undergone a process whereby the forests around

them were first logged, and then were being converted into agricultural land. They had

participated in both of these processes and, as a result of that participation, the decade up to and

including the research period had been one of economic boom for the villagers. It had also been a

time of population growth with the population of the village doubling between 2005 and 2008.

The community forestry project in the village intended to secure non-timber forest based

livelihoods for villagers by enabling them to manage an area of forest which would ensure that

they could continue their „historical‟ and „traditional‟ means of earning a living. Villagers‟

livelihoods had, however, long been dominated by logging and by agricultural labour. The

villagers‟ hopes for the future revolved around getting access to enough agricultural land to be

able to make a living by farming. This reality had no place in either the project document or in

the understandings of the NGO workers at various levels who supported the community forestry

programme. In practice, the community forestry project site was located 6 kilometers from the

village on a route rarely travelled by villagers, and was reportedly in the process of being sold off

by local authorities by the end of the research.

Buon village, located in a rice field landscape in central southern Cambodia had also undergone a

decade of economic success, and this was also culminating in a period of uncertainty by the end

of the research. Unlike Bey, however, the village economy in Buon did not revolve around local

resources but around economic opportunity in the national capital Phnom Penh, particularly

through work for young women in garment factories, young men in the construction industry and

Page 251: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

233

older men working as motorcycle taxi and tuk-tuk drivers. At the time of the last research visit

the global economic downturn was resulting in garment factory closures and the suspension of

work at many construction sites resulting in anxiety about future livelihoods for the villagers. In

Buon, the land registration and titling process did not have any substantial effect because tenure

was already secure, land was already being traded, and people were already able to secure loans

against their land at rates which were not noticeably different to those after titling. To some

extent, the new formal system appeared to become a focus (though not necessary a causal factor)

for disputes, as people who had sold land but only registered the transaction with the local

authorities, then exercised leverage over the new owners, weakening or limiting their tenure

rights. Even if systematic land titling had made a significant impact on rice farming in Buon that

would still not have had a major effect on the village economy because rice production

constituted such a small fraction of villagers‟ livelihoods.

In each of the three studies (both the national study and the two village studies), therefore, the

findings were consistent in showing that the property rights interventions were only able to

proceed in places where tenure was already secure and where there was not strong demand from

non-local actors. Meanwhile, the misrepresentation of rural people‟s livelihoods was vividly

reminiscent of the works of Ferguson and Porter et al. from the 1990s. Households who depended

overwhelmingly on remittance incomes from Phnom Penh, whose rice production was

insufficient even to put rice on their plates and whose tenure was secure, were characterised as

smallholder farmers constrained by tenure insecurity from being the potential third engine of

economic growth for the country. Households whose incomes were dominated by logging and by

agricultural labour, and whose future aspirations revolved around their ability to secure

agricultural land for their households, were portrayed as „forest-dependent‟ and needing to secure

„historical‟ and „traditional‟ livelihoods that had long since been extinguished by deforestation.

The thesis suggests that community forestry is ill-served by a determination to frame all

situations as ones in which livelihoods and forest management are in harmony. It raises the

question of whether community forestry proponents should not have a fallback position

prioritising either forest management or livelihood improvement. It also proposes the

Deforestation Livelihood Trajectory as an analytical tool to deter practitioners from adopting

some of the common simplifications in this regard. The thesis suggests that international support

for land titling has been ill-served by attempts to oversell its potential as a means to deliver tenure

security. This is not realistically within its compass. This distracts from other questions more

realistically within the scope of intervention. Do benefits in improved terms of credit to rural title

holders outweigh the cost of the titles? Does the register of transfers post-titling function in a way

that serves a broader public interest than the sporadic titling arrangements that preceded it?

Overall the thesis is a cautionary tale for the development industry. It suggests that the industry

may still be far too likely to deal in misrepresentations of the situations in which it intervenes,

dooming those interventions to irrelevance and ineffectiveness. It further suggests that the

industry may be far too insistent on trying to promote rights in situations where there is no

realistic prospect of them being enforced. The general implication, then, is that either the

development industry should refrain from trying to go further than host governments are willing

to and limit itself to the sort of „technical‟ projects that its current output-oriented and short-term

management arrangements are suited to, or, if it wishes to attempt to influence host country

politics, to undergo radical restructuring.

Page 252: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

234

References

ADB. (2000). Rural Asia: Beyond the green revolution. Manilla: Asian Development Bank.

Adler, D., Chhim, K., Heang, P., Hak, S., Heng, K., & Sou, K. (2006). Towards Institutional

Justice? A Review of the Work of Cambodia's Cadastral Commission in Relation to Land

Dispute Resolution. Phnom Penh: Centre for Advanced Study.

Adler, D., Porter, D., & Woolcock, M. (2008). Legal Pluralism and Equity: Some Reflections on

Land Reform in Cambodia. Justice for the Poor, 2.

Agergaard, J., Fold, N., & Gough, K. V. (2010). Introduction. In J. Agergaard, N. Fold & K. V.

Gough (Eds.), Rural-Urban Dynamics: Livelihoods, mobility and markets in African and

Asian frontiers. Abingdon: Routledge.

Agrawal, A. (2007). Forests, Governance and Sustainability: Common Property Theory and its

Contributions. International Journal of the Commons, 1(1), 111-136.

Alden Wily, L. (2008). Custom and commonage in Africa rethinking the orthodoxies. Land Use

Policy, 25(1), 43-52.

Anttonen, J. J. (2010). Successful Capacity Building of the Cambodian Land Administration:

Finnish Technical Assistance Combined with the Local Khmer Expertise, Traditions and

Culture Paper presented at the FIG Congress 2010.

Auty, R. M. (2001). The political economy of resource-driven growth. European Economic

Review, 45, 839-846.

Baaz, M. E. (2002). The white wo/man's burden in the age of partnership. University of

Gothenburg, Gothenburg.

Ballard, B., & Sovannarith, S. (2004). Cambodia Land Titling Programme: Baseline Survey

Project Final Report Rural Phase 1 (draft for comments). Ministry of Land Management,

Urban Planning and Construction and Cambodia Development Resource Institute.

Barnes, G. (2003). Lessons learned: an evaluation of land administration initiatives in Latin

America over the past two decades. Land Use Policy, 20(4), 367-374.

Barr, M. D. (2000). Lee Kuan Yew and the "Asian Values' Debate. Asian Studies Review, 24(3),

309.

Bebbington, A. (2000). Reencountering Development: Livelihood Transitions and Place

Transformations in the Andes. Annals of the Association of American Geographers, 90(3),

495-520.

Bebbington, A. (2003). Global Networks and Local Developments: Agendas for Development

Geography. Tijdschrift voor Economische en Sociale Geografie, 94(3), 297-309.

Bebbington, A. (2004). NGOs and Uneven Development: Geographies of Development

Intervention. Progress in Human Geography, 28(6), 725-745.

Bebbington, A., & McCourt, W. (Eds.). (2007). Development Success: Statecraft in the south.

Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.

Becker, E. (1998). When the War Was Over: Cambodia's Revolution and the Voices of its People.

2nd Edition New York: Simon and Schuster.

Page 253: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

235

Bekhechi, M. A., & Lund, L. (2009). Report of the LMAP Enhanced Review Mission. July 13,

2009. Phnom Penh: World Bank.

Benjaminsen, T. A., Holden, S., Lund, C., & Sjaastad, E. (2009). Formalisation of land rights:

Some empirical evidence from Mali, Niger and South Africa. Land Use Policy, 26(1), 28-

35.

Bernard, R. H. (2002). Research Methods in Anthropology: Qualitative and Quantitative

Approaches. Third Edition. Walton Creek: Alta Mira Press.

Bezemer, D., & Headey, D. (2008). Agriculture, Development and Urban Bias. World

Development, 36(8), 1342-1364.

Biddulph, R. (1996). Participatory Development in Autoritarian Societies: The Case of Two

Village Development Committees in the Province of Banteay Meanchey, Cambodia.,

Australian National University, Canberra.

Biddulph, R. (1998). Evaluation Report: Aphivat Strei. Phnom Penh: Oxfam GB.

Biddulph, R. (2000a). Evaluation Report: Rural Development and Resettlement Project. Phnom

Penh/Kuala Lumpur: UNDP/UNOPS.

Biddulph, R. (2000b). Evaluation Report: Save the Children Fund UK Community Development

Programme in Cambodia. Phnom Penh: SCF UK.

Biddulph, R. (2000c). Landlessness: a Growing Problem. Cambodia Development Review, 4(3),

1-2.

Biddulph, R. (2000d). Making the Poor More Visible. (No. 4). Phnom Penh: Oxfam GB.

Biddulph, R. (2001a). Civil Society and Local Governance: Learning Lessons from Seila

Communes. Phnom Penh: Seila Task Force Secretariat, Royal Government of Cambodia.

Biddulph, R. (2001b). Rapid Assessment of the PRSP Process in Cambodia: Two Banks, Two

Processes, Two Documents. Phnom Penh: NGO Forum on Cambodia.

Biddulph, R. (2003a). Evaluation of Human Rights Fund Projects in Cambodia. Phnom Penh:

British Embassy.

Biddulph, R. (2003b). PAT Empowerment Study. Phnom Penh: DFID/Sida Permanent Advisory

Team on the Seila Programme.

Biddulph, R. (2004). Poverty and Social Impact Assessment of Social Land Concessions in

Cambodia: Land Assessment. Limited distribution draft. Oxfam GB/World Bank.

Bigsten, A., Gunning, J. W., & Tarp, F. (2006). The Effectiveness of Foreign Aid: Overview and

Evaluation Proposal. Mimeo report prepared for Sida.

Blaikie, P. (2006). Is Small Really Beautiful? Community-based Natural Resource Management

in Malawi and Botswana. World Development, 34(11), 1942-1957.

Block, F. (2001). The Great Transformation - An introduction. In The Great Transformation: The

political and economic origins of our time. Boston: Beacon Press.

Blue, R., & Underwood, R. (2008). Evaluation of the Program on Rights and Justice. Final

Report. Phnom Penh: USAID-Cambodia.

Borras, S. M. (2009). Agrarian change and peasant studies: changes, continuities and challenges -

an introduction. Journal of Peasant Studies, 36(1), 5-31.

Boserup, E. (1965). The Conditions of Agricultural Growth: The Economics of Agrarian Change

under Population Pressure Chicago: Aldine.

Page 254: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

236

Bradley, A. (2009). Communities and Carbon: Establishing a community forestry-REDD project

in Cambodia. Phnom Penh: PACT/Focali.

Brickell, K. (2008). 'Fire in the House': Gendered Experiences of Drunkenness & Violence in

Siem Reap, Cambodia. Geoforum, 39(5), 1667-1675.

Bromley, D. W. (2006). Property Rights and Development. In D. A. Clark (Ed.), The Elgar

Companion to Development Studies (pp. 5-10). Cheltenham: Eward Elgar.

Bromley, D. W. (2009). Formalising property relations in the developing world: The wrong

prescription for the wrong malady. Land Use Policy, 26(1), 20-27.

Bryant, R. (2002). Non-governmental Organizations and Governmentality:'Consuming'

Biodiversity and Indigenous People in the Philippines. Political Studies, 50(2), 268.

Bryceson, D. (2006). Growing out of Spatial Poverty: Growth, Sub-National Equity and Poverty

Reduction Policies - A Five-Country Comparison. Synthesis paper prepared for DFID

Rural-Urban Change team Brighton: The Policy Practice Limited.

Brydon, L. (2006). Ethical Practices in Doing Development Research. In V. Desai & R. B. Potter

(Eds.), Doing Development Research. London: Sage.

Burnside, C., & Dollar, D. (2000). Aid, Policies, and Growth. The American Economic Review,

90(4), 847-868.

Carney, D. (1999). Approaches to Sustainable Livelihoods. London: Overseas Development

Institute.

Center for Advanced Study. (2006). Justice for the Poor? An explanatory study of collective

grievances over land and local governance in Cambodia. Phnom Penh: CAS/World

Bank.

Chakrya, N. (2009). Shooting injured people in land dispute at Chikreng District, Siem Reap

Province. Retrieved 19 June 2009, 2009, from http://www.adhoc-

chra.org/article.php?language=english&art_id=60&currentpage=1

Chambers, R. (1983). Rural Development: Putting the Last First. Harlow: Longman.

Chambers, R. (1997). Whose Reality Counts? Putting the First Last. London: ITDG Publishing.

Chambers, R., & Conway, G. (1992). Sustainable Rural Livelihoods: Practical Concepts for the

21st Century. Brighton: Institute of Development Studies.

Chandler, D. (1992). A History of Cambodia, Second Edition. Chiang Mai: Silkworm Press.

Chandler, D. (1998). The Burden of Cambodia's Past. In F. Z. Brown & D. G. Timberlake (Eds.),

Cambodia and the International Community: The Quest for Peace, Development and

Democracy. New York: Asia Society.

Chang, H.-J. (2006). Understanding the Relationship between Institutions and Economic

Development: some key theoretical issues. Discussion paper No. 2006/05. Washington

DC: UNU-WIDER.

Charya, C., Pithou, S., Sovannarith, S., McAndrew, J., Sokunthea, N., Dorina, P., et al. (2001).

Learning from Rural Development Programmes in Cambodia. In A. Straub (Ed.),

Insitutions, Livelihoods and the Environment. Copenhagen: Nordic Institute of Asian

Studies.

Page 255: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

237

Chauveau, J.-P., & Colin, J.-P. (2007). Changes in Land Transfer Mechanisms: evidence from

West Africa. In L. Cotula (Ed.), Changes in "customary" land tenure systems in Africa.

Stevenage: IIED/SMI(Distribution Services Ltd).

Chens, C.-Y., Sok, P., & Sok, K. (2008). Evaluating the Competitiveness of the Tourism Industry

in Cambodia: Self-assessment from Professionals. Asia Pacific Journal of Tourism

Research, 13(1), 41 - 66.

Chhieng, Y. (2001). "Reforming Technical Cooperation for Cambodia: Lessons from Cambodia".

Speech delivered at Turin, Italy on 3-7 December. Turin: UNDP.

CHRAC. (2005). High Price of Land: The Deadly Eviction of Kbal Spean. Report by the

Cambodian Human Rights Action Committee, A Coalition of 18 NGOs. Phnom Penh:

USAID/East West Centre.

Christophers, B. (2010). On voodoo economics: theorising relations of property, value and

contemporary capitalism. Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers, 35(1), 94-

108.

Chung-In, M., & Rashemi, P. (1994). Beyond the Developmental State: Networks, Politics, and

Institutions. Governance, 7(4), 360-386.

Cock, A. (2004). Forest Destruction for Poverty Reduction: The Tum Ring rubber plantation.

Watershed, 9(3), 30-39.

COHRE. (2009). Request for Inspection by World Bank Inspection Panel (Land Management and

Administration Project - Project ID: P070875). Duluth: COHRE.

Cooper, G. (2002). Land Policy and Conflict: The Cambodia Portion of an Eight-Country Study

by the North-South Institute for the World Bank. Phnom Penh: World Bank.

Corbridge, S. (2007). The (im)possibility of development studies. Economy and Society, 36(2),

179-211.

Cousins, B. (2007). Land and agrarian reform in the 21st century: changing realities, changing

arguments? Paper presented at the Global Assembly of Members, International Land

Coalition., from

http://www.oxfam.org.uk/what_we_do/issues/livelihoods/landrights/downloads/land_agra

rian_reform_in_c21.rtf

Cousins, B. (2009). Capitalism obscured: the limits of law and rights-based approaches to poverty

reduction and development. Journal of Peasant Studies, 36(4), 893 - 908.

Cowen, M. P., & Shenton, R. W. (1996). Doctrines of Development. London: Routledge.

Craig, D. (1997). Familiar Medicine: Local and Global Health and Development in Vietnam.,

Australian National University, Canberra.

Craig, D., & Kimchoeun, P. (2009). Learning from party financing of local investment projects in

Cambodia: Elite and mass patronage, accountability and decentralized governance. A

discussion paper.

Craig, D., & Porter, D. (2006). Development Beyond Neoliberalism? Governance, Poverty

Reduction and Political Economy. London: Routledge.

Crush, J. (1995). Imagining Development. In J. Crush (Ed.), Power of Development. London:

Routledge.

Page 256: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

238

Curtis, G. (1994). Transition to What? Cambodia, UNTAC and the Peace Process. In P. Utting

(Ed.), Between Hope and Insecurity. Geneva: UNRISD.

Dalton, R. J., & Ong, N.-N. T. (2005). Authority Orientations and Democratic Attitudes: A test of

the 'Asian Values' Hypothesis. Japanese Journal of Political Science, 6(2), 211-231.

de Soto, H. (2000). The Mystery of Capital: why capitalism triumphs in the West and fails

everywhere else New York: Basic Books.

Deininger, K. (2003). Land Policies for Growth and Poverty Reduction Oxford: OUP/World

Bank.

Deininger, K. (2005). Quantifying the poverty impact of land policy interventions: The Case of

Cambodia (Mimeo). World Bank.

Deininger, K., Ali, D. A. A., & Alemu, T. (2009). Impact of Land Certification on Tenure,

Security, Investment, and Land Markets. Gothenburg: Environment for Development.

Delvert, J. (1961). Le Paysan Cambodgien. Paris.

Deutsch, R. (2006). Beneficiary Assessment of Land Title Recipients under the Land Management

and Administration Project (LMAP). Phnom Penh: Ministry of Land Management Urban

Planning and Construction.

Deutsch, R., & Makathy, T. (2009). Beneficiary Assessment (BA-II) for the Land Administration

Sub-Sector Program (LA-SSP), GTZ Land Management Project (PN 03.2250.3). Phnom

Penh: GTZ.

Dietz, T., Ostrom, E., & Stern, P. C. (2003). The Struggle to Govern the Commons. Science,

302(5652), 1907-1912.

Doyle, M. (1995). UN Peacekeeping in Cambodia: UNTAC's Civil Mandate. . Boulder: Lunne

Rienner Publishers.

Ear, S. (2005). Political Economy of Pro-Poor Livestock in Cambodia. PPLI Working Paper No.

26. Rome: FAO.

Easterly, W. (2005, Sunday March 13). A Modest Proposal. The Washington Post. Retrieved 3rd

April 2010, from http://www.washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/articles/A25562-

2005Mar10.html

Easterly, W., Levine, R., & Roodman, D. (2004). New data, new doubts: A comment on Burnside

and Dollar's 'Aid, policies, and growth'. The American Economic Review, 94(3), 774-780.

Ebihara, M. (1968). Svay, A Khmer Village in Cambodia. Unpublished PhD Dissertation. Ann

Arbor.

EC. (2005). Promoting Community Forestry in Cambodia. Retrieved 16th September, 2008

Edwards, P. (2008). Cambodge: The Cultivation of a Nation 1860–1945. Honolulu: University of

Hawai'i Press.

Ellis, F. (1998). Household strategies and rural livelihood diversification. Journal of

Development Studies, 35(1), 1 - 38.

Erdmann, G., & Engel, U. (2006). Neopatrimonialism Revisited: Beyond a Catch-All Concept.

Hamburg: German Institute of Global and Area Studies.

Erdmann, G., & Engel, U. (2007). Neopatrimonialism Reconsidered: Critical Review and

Elaboration of an Elusive Concept. Commonwealth & Comparative Politics, 45(1), 95 -

119.

Page 257: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

239

Escobar, A. (1995). Encountering Development. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Feder, G., & Nishio, A. (1998). The benefits of land registration and titling: Economic and social

perspectives. Land Use Policy, 15(1), 25-43.

Feder, G., & Onchan, T. (1987). Land Ownership Security and Farm Investment in Thailand.

American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 69(2), 311.

Ferguson, J. (1994). The Anti-Politics Machine: "Development", De-politicisation, and

Bureaucratic Power in Lesotho. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.

Ferguson, J. (2005). Seeing Like an Oil Company: Space, Security, and Global Capital in

Neoliberal Africa. American Anthropologist, 107(3), 377-382.

Fichtenau, J., Beang, L. C., Sothea, N., & Sophy, D. (2002). An Assessment of Ongoing

Community Forestry Initiatives in Cambodia - Implications for the Development of a

Forestry Extension Strategy. . Phnom Penh: GTZ/Department of Forestry and Wildlife.

Findlay, T. (1995). Cambodia: The Lessons and Legacy of UNTAC. Oxford: Oxford University

Press.

FINNMAP. (2008, 21st February 2008). LMAP and FINNMAP Celebrate the Achievement of

the 1 Million Parcel Target in Cambodia. Retrieved 12th March, 2008, from

http://www.finnmap.com/news.htlm

Fitzgerald, I., & Sovannarith, S. (2007). Moving out of Poverty? Trends in Community Well-

being and Household Mobility in Nine Cambodian Villages. Phnom Penh: CDRI.

Fold, N., Gough, K. V., & Agergaard, J. (2010). Conclusion. In J. Agergaard, N. Fold & K. V.

Gough (Eds.), Rural-Urban Dynamics: Livelihoods, mobility and markets in African and

Asian frontiers. Abingdon: Routledge.

Fold, N., & Tacoli, C. (2010). Agricultural frontier settlements: Markets, livelihood

diversification and small town development. In J. Agergaard, N. Fold & K. V. Gough

(Eds.), Rural-Urban Dynamics: Livelihoods, mobility and markets in African and Asian

frontiers. Abingdon: Routledge.

Forestry Administration. (2004). National Report to the Fifth Session of the United Nations

Forum on Forests. Phnom Penh: Royal Government of Cambodia.

Foucault, M. (1979). Discipline and Punish: The Birth of the Prison. New York: Vintage.

Fukuyama, F. (2004). State Building: Governance and World Order in the Twenty-First Century.

Cornell: Cornell University Press.

Gardner, K., & Lewis, D. (2003). Anthropology, Development and the Post-Modern Challenge.

London: Pluto Press.

Gasper, D. (1994). Book Review. Development in Practice - Paved with Good Intentions. .

Development and Change, 25(4), 907-909.

Gilbert, A. (2002). On the Mystery of Capital and the Myths of Hernando de Soto: What

difference does legal title make? International Development Planning Review, 24(1), 1-

19.

Godfrey, M., Sophal, C., Kato, T., Piseth, V., Dorina, P., Saravy, T., et al. (2002). Technical

Assistance and Capacity Development in an Aid-dependent Economy: the Experience of

Cambodia. . World Development, 30(3), 353-373.

Page 258: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

240

Gottesman, E. (2004). Cambodia after the Khmer Rouge: Inside the politics of nation-building. .

Bangkok: Silkwork.

Gough, K. V., & Rigg, J. (2010). Handicraft and Manufacturing Frontier: Transforming

Livelihoods, Re-shaping Settlements. In J. Agergaard, N. Fold & K. V. Gough (Eds.),

Rural-Urban Dynamics: Livelihoods, mobility and markets in African and Asian frontiers.

Abingdon: Routledge.

Gould, B. (2006). Working with Partners: Educational Institutions. In V. Desai & R. B. Potter

(Eds.), Doing Development Research (pp. 79-86). London: Sage.

Grainger, A. (2008). Tropical moist forests and development. In R. B. P. Vandana Desai (Ed.),

The Companion to Development Studies. Second Edition (pp. 324-330). Oxford: Oxford

University Press.

Grimsditch, M., & Henderson, N. (Artist). (2009). Untitled: Tenure Insecurity and Inequality in

the Cambodian Land Sector

Grindle, M. S. (2004). Good Enough Governance: Poverty Reduction and Reform in Developing

Countries. Governance: An International Journal of Policy, Administration and

Institutions, 17, 525-548.

Haan, A. d. (2009). How the Aid Industry Works: An Introduction to International Development:

Kumarian Press.

Hancock, G. (1989). Lords of Poverty: The Power, Prestige and Corruption of the International

Aid Business: Atlantic.

Hansen, H., & Tarp, F. (2000). Aid effectiveness disputed. Journal of International Development,

12(3), 375-398.

Hardin, G. (1968). The Tragedy of the Commons. Science, 162, 1243-1248.

Hart, G. (2001). Development critique in the 1990s: cul de sac and promising paths. Progress in

Human Geography, 25(4), 649-658.

Hart, G. (2010). D/developments after the Meltdown. Antipode, 41(s1), 117-141.

Harvey, D. (1973). Social justice and the city Oxford: Blackwell.

Harvey, D. (1982). The Limits to Capital. Oxford: Blackwell.

Harvey, D. (2006). Spaces of Global Capitalism. New York: Verson.

Hasselskog, M. (2000). Local Governance in Transition. Villagers' Perceptions and Seila's

Impact. Phnom Penh: UNDP CARERE.

Hay, L. M. (2007). Commentary: Cambodia's war against the powerful brings terror to the

powerless Retrieved 19 June, 2009, from

http://www.cambodia.org/blogs/editorials/2007/05/commentary-cambodias-war-

against.html

Hayami, Y. (2001). Ecology, History and Development: A Perspective from Rural Southeast

Asia. . The World Bank Research Observer, 16(2), 169-198.

Heder, S. (2005). Hun Sen's Consolidation: Death or Beginning of Reform? Southeast Asian

Affairs, 114-130.

Heltberg, R. (2002). Property Rights and Natural Resource Management in Developing

Countries. Journal of Economic Surveys, 16(2), 189-218.

Henders, S. (2010). Focali Country Brief - Guyana. Gothenburg: Focali.

Page 259: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

241

Hendrix, S. E., & Rockcliffe, L. O. (1998). The Deeds Registry in Guyana, its legal and

institutional framework with recommendations for promoting transaction efficiency. Land

Use Policy, 15(1), 67-82.

Heng, S., & Sokhun, T. (2005). Cambodia Community Forestry 2005. Phnom Penh: Ministry of

Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries.

Ho, P., & Spoor, M. (2006). Whose land? The political economy of land titling in transitional

economies. Land Use Policy, 23(4), 580-587.

Hodder, R. (2000). Development Geography. London: Routledge.

Holme, I. M., & Solvang, B. K. (1997). Forskningsmetodik. Lund: Studentlitteratur.

Hughes, C. (2003a). The Political Economy of Cambodia's Transition 1991-2001 London:

Routledge.

Hughes, C. (2003b). The Political Economy of Cambodia's Transition 1991-2001. . London:

Routledge.

Hughes, C. (2009). Dependent Communities: Aid and Politics in Cambodia and East Timor. New

York: Cornell University.

Hydén, G. (1995). Review. The Anti-Politics Machine: "Development, Depoliticization, and

Bureaucratic Power in Lesotho by James Ferguson. The American Political Science

Review, 89(1), 226-227.

IMF. (2009). Cambodia: 2009 Article IV Consultation—Staff Report; Staff Supplement; Public

Information Notice on the Executive Board Discussion; and Statement by the Executive

Director. Phnom Penh: IMF.

Johnston, R. J. (1997). Geography & Geographers: Anglo-American Geography since 1945.

Fifth edition. London: Arnold.

Johnston, R. J., Gregory, D., Pratt, G., & Watts, M. (Eds.). (2000). The Dictionary of Human

Geography. Fourth edition. Oxford Blackwell.

Jomo, K. S. (2005). Economic Reform for Whom? Beyond the Washington Consensus. post-

autistic economics review, 35(5), 11-18.

Kanyinga, K. (2000). Redistribution from Above: The Politics of Land Rights and Squatting in

Coastal Kenya. Uppsala: Nordic Africa Institute.

Kato, E. (1999). We have rights, they have power. Phnom Penh: Oxfam Great Britain.

Kerkvliet, B. J. T. (1995). Village-State Relations in Vietnam: The Effect of Everyday Politics on

Decollectivization. The Journal of Asian Studies, 54(2), 396-418.

Kiernan, B. (1996). The Pol Pot Regime: Race, Power, and Genocide in Cambodia under the

Khmer Rouge, 1975-79 Chiang Mai: Silkworm Books.

Kiernan, B. (2002). Introduction: Conflict in Cambodia, 1945-2002. Critical Asian Studies, 34(4),

483-495.

Kimchoeun, P., Vuthy, H., Netra, E., Sovatha, A., Sedara, K., Knowles, J., et al. (2007).

Accountability and Neo-patrimonialism in Cambodia: a Critical Literature Review.

Working Paper 34. Phnom Penh: Cambodia Development Resource Institute.

Korten, D. (1982). Community Organisation and Rural Development: A Learning Process

Approach. Public Administration Review, 40(5), 480-511.

Page 260: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

242

Kusakabe, K., Yunxian, W., & Kelkar, G. (1995). Women and Land Rights in Cambodia.

Economic and Political Weekly, 30(43), 87-92.

Land Information Centre. (2008). Land Dispute Database - Pilot Study Report. Phnom Penh:

NGO Forum on Cambodia.

Land Information Centre. (2009). Statistical Analysis on Land Dispute Occuring in Cambodia

2008. Phnom Penh: NGO Forum on Cambodia.

Le Billon, P. (2000). The Political Ecology of Transition in Cambodia 1989-1999: War, Peace

and Forest Exploitation. Development and Change, 31, 785-805.

Le Billon, P. (2002). Logging in Muddy Waters: The Politics of Forest Exploitation in Cambodia.

Critical Asian Studies, 34(4), 563-586.

Ledgerwood, J. (2002). Cambodia Emerges from the Past: Eight Essays (Vol. 3). DeKalb:

Northern Illinois University.

Li, T. M. (2002). Engaging Simplifications: Community-Based Resource Management, Market

Processes and State Agendas in Upland Southeast Asia. World Development, 30(2), 265-

283.

Li, T. M. (2005). Beyond "the State" and Failed Schemes. . American Anthropologist, 107(3),

383-394.

Li, T. M. (2007). The Will to Improve: Governmentality, Development, and the Practice of

Politics. London: Duke University Press.

Li, T. M. (2010). Revisiting "The Will to Improve". Annals of the Association of American

Geographers, 100(1), 233 - 235.

Licadho. (2009). Land Grabbing and Poverty in Cambodia: They Myth of Development. Phnom

Penh: Licadho.

Macan-Markar, M. (2009). Land Grabbing - A Serious Concern. Retrieved 19 June, 2009, from

http://ipsnews.net/news.asp?idnews=40954

Makin, J. (2006). Women and Factory Work in Cambodia. ILO/World Bank.

Markussen, T. (2006). Land Titling in Cambodia - Findings From a Field Trip. Phnom Penh:

World Bank.

Markussen, T. (2008). Property Rights, Productivity, and Common Property Resources: Insights

from Rural Cambodia. World Development, 36(11), 2277-2296.

Marshall, A. (2009, 12th December). Khmer Riche. Good Weekend Magazie for the Sydney

Morning Herald,

Martens, B. (2002a). Introduction. In B. Martens, U. Mummert, P. Murrell & P. Seabright (Eds.),

The Institutional Economics of Foreign Aid (pp. 1-33). Cambridge: Cambridge University

Press.

Martens, B. (2002b). Some policy conclusions regarding the organisations involved in foreign

aid. In B. Martens, U. Mummert, P. Murrell & P. Seabright (Eds.), The Institutional

Economics of Foreign Aid (pp. 178-195). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Martens, B., Mummert, U., Murrell, P., & Seabright, P. (2002). The Institutional Economics of

Foreign Aid. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Matheson, M. J. (2001). United Nations Governance of Postconflict Societies. The American

Journal of International Law, 95(1), 76-85.

Page 261: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

243

Mayoux, L. (2006). Qualitative, Quantitative or Participatory? Which Method, for What and

When? In V. Desai & R. B. Potter (Eds.), Doing Development Research (pp. 115-129).

London: Sage.

McAndrew, J. (2007). Land Titling and Poverty Reduction: A Study of Two Sangkat in Prey Nup

District, Sihanoukville Municipality Phnom Penh: NGO Forum on Cambodia &

Cooperation Committee for Cambodia

McKenney, B., Chea, Y., Tola, P., & Evans, T. (2004). Focusing on Cambodia's High Value

Forests: Livelihood and Management Phnom Penh: Cambodia Development Resource

Institute/Wildlife Conservation Society.

Mehrvar, M., Kim Sore, C., & Sambath, M. (2008). Women‘s Perspectives: A Case Study of

Systematic Land Registration in Cambodia. Phnom Penh: Heinrich Boll Foundation.

Meinzen-Dick, R. S., & Pradhan, R. (2002). Legal Pluralism and Dynamic Property Rights.

CAPRi Working Paper No.22. Washington: IFPRI.

Minder, R. (2008, November 21). Cambodia holds land deal talks. Financial Times,

Mitchell, D., Clarke, M., & Baxter, J. (2008). Evaluating land administration projects in

developing countries. Land Use Policy, 25(4), 464-473.

Mitchell, T. (1995). The Object of Development: America's Egypt. In J. Crush (Ed.), Power of

Development. London and New York: Routledge.

Mitchell, T. (2004). The Properties of Markets: Informal Housing and Capitalism's Mystery.

Cultural Political Economy Working Paper Series, Working Paper No.2. Lancaster:

Institute for Advanced Studies in Social and Management Sciences.

MLMUPC. (2002). Sub decree on the Procedures to establish Cadastral Index Map and Land

Register. Phnom Penh: Ministry of Land Management, Urplan Planning and Construction.

Mosse, D. (2005). Cultivating Development: An Ethnology of Aid Policy and Practice. London:

Ann Arbor.

Mosse, D., & Lewis, D. (2006). Theoretical Approaches to Brokerage and Translation in

Develoment In D. Lewis & D. Mosse (Eds.), Development Brokers and Translators: The

Ethnography of Aid and Agencies. . Bloomfield: Kumarian Press.

Murray, C. (2001). Livelihoods research: some conceptual and methodological issues.

Manchester: Chronic Poerty Research Centre.

Mysliwiec, E. (1988a). Punishing the Poor: The International Isolation of Kampuchea Oxford:

Oxfam.

Mysliwiec, E. (1988b). Punishing the Poor: The International Isolation of Kampuchea. . Oxford:

Oxfam.

NPA. (2003). Cambodia: Sharing Experiences about Land Struggles, Asia Land Meeting.

December 13-16. Phnom Penh: Norwegian People's Aid.

O'Leary, D. (2005). Pilot Independent Review of Systematic Land Titling Field Systems and

Procedures (Transparency and Accountability). . Phnom Penh: Land Management and

Administration Project.

O'Leary, D. (2007). Mid-Term Evaluation of the Promoting Community Forestry - Cambodia

Project. Phnom Penh: Oxfam GB.

Osborne, M. (1978). The 1916 Affair. Modern Asian Studies, 12(2), 217-243.

Page 262: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

244

Osborne, M. (1994). Sihanouk. Prince of light, prince of darkness. Sydney: Allen and Unwin.

Osborne, M. (1997). The Frence Presence in Cochinchina and Cambodia. Bankgok: White Lotus

Press

Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the Commons: the evolution of institutions for collective action.

Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Ostrom, E. (1999). Revisiting the Commons: Local Lessons, Global Challenges. Science,

284(5412), 278-282.

Ostrom, E. (2005). Understanding Institutional Diversity. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Ostrom, E. (2007). A diagnostic approach for going beyond panaceas. Proceedings of the

National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America, 104(39), 15181-15187.

Ostrom, E., Gibson, C., Shivakumar, S., & Andersson, K. (2002). Aid, Incentives, and

Sustainability: An Institutional Analysis of Development Cooperation. Main Report.

Stockholm: Sida.

Ovesen, J., Trankell, I.-B., & Öjendal, J. (1996). When Every Household is an Island.

Stockholm/Uppsala: Sida/University of Uppsala.

Oxfam GB. (2005). Grant Application Form: Promoting Community Forestry in Cambodia.

Phnom Penh/Oxford: Oxfam GB/European Commission.

Payne, G., Durand-Lasserve, A., & Radoki, C. (2009). The limits of land titling and home

ownership. Environment and Urbanization, 21(2), 443-462.

Peou, S. (1997). Conflict Neutralization in the Cambodian War: From Battlefield to Ballot Box.

Kuala Lumpur: Oxford University Press.

Pieterse, J. N. (2009). Twenty-First Century Globalization, Paradigm Shifts in Development. In

M. Kremer, van Lieshout, P., & Went, R (Ed.), Doing Good or Doing Better:

Development Policies in a Rapidly Changing World. Amsterdam: Amsterdam University

Press.

Poffenberger, M. (2006). People in the forest: community forestry experiences from Southeast

Asia. International Journal of Environment and Sustainable Development, 5(1), 57-69.

Polanyi, K. (2001). The Great Transformation: The political and economic origins of our time.

Boston: Beacon Press.

Ponchaud, F. (1978). Cambodia: Year Zero, translated by Nancy Amphoux. New York: Holts

Rinehart and Winston.

Porter, D., Allen, B., & Thompson, G. (1991). Development in Practice: Paved with Good

Intentions London: Routledge.

Porter, D., & Craig, D. (2003). Poverty Reduction Strategy Papers: A New Convergence. World

Development, 31(1), 53-69.

Porter, D., & Craig, D. (2004). The third way and the third world: poverty reduction and social

inclusion in the rise of 'inclusive' liberalism. Review of International Political Economy,

11(2), 387-423.

Potter, R., Binns, T., Elliott, J., & Smith, D. (1999). Geographies of Development. Harlow:

Longman.

Power, M., & Sidaway, J. D. (2004). The Degeneration of Tropical Geography. Annals of the

Association of American Geographers, 94(3), 595-601.

Page 263: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

245

Putzel, J. (2000). Land Reforms in Asia: Lessons from the past for the 21st Century. London:

London School of Economics.

Rattanabirabongse, V., Eddington, R. A., Burns, A. F., & Nettle, K. G. (1998). The Thailand land

titling project--thirteen years of experience. Land Use Policy, 15(1), 3-23.

Reno, W. (1995). Corruption and State Politics in Sierra Leone. Cambridge: Cambridge

University Press.

Reno, W. (2000). Clandestine Economies, Violence and States in Africa. Journal of International

Affairs, 53(2), 433.

Riddell, R. C. (2009). Does Foreign Aid Work? In M. Kremer, van Lieshout, P., & Went, R

(Ed.), Doing Good or Doing Better: Development Policies in a Rapidly Changing World.

Amsterdam:: Amsterdam University Press.

Rigg, J. D. (1997). Southeast Asia: the human landscape of modernization and development.

London: Routledge.

Rigg, J. D. (2001). More than the Soil: Rural change in Southeast Asia. Harlow: Prentice Hall.

Rigg, J. D. (2006). Land, Livelihoods and Farming: Rethinking the Links in the Rural South.

World Development, 34(1), 180-202.

Rigg, J. D., & Salamanca, A. (2009). Managing risk and vulnerability in Asia: A (re)study from

Thailand, 1982–83 and 2008. Asia Pacific Viewpoint, 50(3), 255-270.

Rigg, J. D., Veeravongs, S., Rohitarachoon, P., & Veeravongs, L. (2010). From farm to factory:

Village change in a rice-growing region. In J. Agergaard, N. Fold & K. V. Gough (Eds.),

Rural-Urban Dynamics: Livelihoods, mobility and markets in African and Asian frontiers.

Abingdon: Routledge.

Rist, G. (1997). The History of Development: from Western origins to global faith. London: Zed.

Roberts, D. W. (2001). Political transition in Cambodia 1991-1999 : power, elitism and

democracy. Richmond: Curzon.

Rodrik, D. (2004). Getting Institutions Right. Retrieved 2 July 2007, from

http://ksghome.harvard.edu/~drodrik/ifo-institutions%20article%20_April%202004_.pdf

Rodrik, D., Subramainan, A., & Trebbi, F. (2002). Institutions Rule: The Primacy of Institutions

over Geography and Integration in Economic Development. Cambridge, Ma: National

Bureau of Economic Research.

Roe, E. (1994). Narrative policy analysis: Theory and practice. . Durham: Duke University

Press.

Ross, M. L. (1999). Review: The Political Economy of the Resource Curse. World Politics,

51(2), 297-322.

Ross, M. L. (2001). Timber Booms and Institutional Breakdown in Southeast Asia. New York:

Cambridge University Press.

Royal Government of Cambodia. (2003). Sub Decree No.19 ANK/BK of March 19, 2003 on

Social Land Concessions Phnom Penh: Ministry of Land Management, Urplan Planning

and Construction.

Rutherford, S. (2000). The Poor and Their Money. New Delhi: Oxford University Press.

Sachs, J. (2003). Institutions Don't Rule: Direct Effects of Geography on Per Capita Income .

National Bureau of Economic Research.

Page 264: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

246

Sachs, J. (2005). The end of poverty : how we can make it happen in our lifetime. London:

Penguin.

Sachs, W. (1992). The Development Dictionary: a guide to knowledge as power. London: Zed

books.

Sakada, C. (2008, 2 December 2008). Migrant Workers to get Free Passports. VOA Khmer,

Salinger, L. (2006). Garment Industry Workforce Assessment. Phnom Penh: USAID.

Sanger, D. (1991, 27th December). Corrupt Officials in Cambodia Put the Country Up for Sale.

New York Times,

Schlager, E., & Ostrom, E. (1992). Property-Rights Regimes and Natural Resources: A

Conceptual Analysis. Land Economics, 68(3), 249-262.

Schuurman, F. J. (Ed.). (1993). Beyond the Impasse: New Directions in Development Theory.

London: Zed.

Scoones, I. (1998). Sustainable Rural Livelihoods A Framework for Analysis. IDS Working

Paper 72. Brighton: Institute for Development Studies.

Scott, J. C. (1977). Scott, James: The Moral Economy of the Peasant: Rebellion and Subsistence

in Southeast Asia. Yale: Yale University Press.

Scott, J. C. (1985). Weapons of the Weak: Everyday Forms of Peasant Resistance Yale: Yale

University Press.

Sen, H. (1998). Hun Sen on Land Issue in Kampot. Cambodia New Vision,

Sen, H. (1999a). Closing Remarks. Cambodia New Vision,

Sen, H. (1999b). Extensive Excerpts of the Opening and Closing Addresses by Samdech Prime

Minister Hun Sen to the Donor Monitoring Meeting on June 14, 1999. Cambodia New

Vision,

Sen, H. (2000a). Address of Samdech Hun Sen to the Consultative Group Meeting (Paris, 25-26

May 2000). Cambodia New Vision,

Sen, H. (2000b). Addresses of Samdech Hun Sen to the Government-Donor Meeting: Opening

Address. Cambodia New Vision,

Sen, H. (2006). Selected comments at the Inauguration of New Buildings for the Ministry of

Relations with Parliament, Senate and Inspection, 29th May 2006. Unofficial translation.

Retrieved 6 September, 2006, from http://www.cnv.org.kh

Shawcross, W. (1979). Sideshow: Kissinger, Nixon and the destruction of Cambodia. New York:

Simon and Schuster.

Simon, D. (2006). Your Questions Answered? Conducting Questionnaire Surveys. In V. Desai &

R. B. Potter (Eds.), Doing Development Research (pp. 163-171). London: Sage.

Simon, D. (2007). Beyond antidevelopment: Discourses, convergences, practices. Singapore

Journal of Tropical Geography, 28(2), 205-218.

Sjöberg, Ö., & Sjöholm, F. (2007). The Cambodian economy: ready for take-off? The Pacific

Review, 19(4), 495-517.

Slocomb, M. (2001). The K5 Gamble: National Defence and Nation Building under the People's

Republic of Kampuchea. Journal of Southeast Asia Studies, 32(2), 195-210.

Slocomb, M. (2003). The People's Republic of Kampuchea, 1979-1989. Bankgok: Silkwork

Books.

Page 265: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

247

Slocomb, M. (2007). Colons and Coolies: the development of Cambodia's rubber plantations. .

Bangkok: White Lotus Press. .

Smith, N. (2008). Uneven Development: Nature, Capital and the Production of Space. Third

Edition. Athens: University of Georgia Press.

So, S. (2009). Political Economy of Land Registration in Cambodia. Northern Illinois University.

Sovann, S. (2005). Systematic Land Registration in Cambodia: Participation, Capacity Building

and Team Work. Paper presented at the Expert Group Meeting on secure land tenure: 'new

legal framework and tools', Bangkok 8-9 December.,

Sovannarith, S., Sopheap, R., Utey, U., Rathmony, S., Ballard, B., & Acharya, S. (2001). Social

Assessment of Land in Cambodia: A Field Study. Phnom Penh: CDRI.

Timmer, C. P. (2006). Agriculture and Economic Growth. In D. A. Clark (Ed.), The Elgar

Companion to Development Studies (pp. 5-10). Cheltenham: Eward Elgar.

Turner, S., & Caouette, D. (2009). Shifting fields of rural resistance in Southeast Asia. In D.

Caouette & S. Turner (Eds.), Agrarian Angst and Rural Resistance in Contemporary

Southeast Asia. Abingdon: Routledge.

Törhönen, M. (2001). Developing land administration in Cambodia. Computers, Environment

and Urban Systems, 25, 407-428.

UNDP. (2007). Land and Human Development in Cambodia. Phnom Penh: UNDP.

UNOHCHR. (2007). Economic Land Concessions in Cambodia: A human rights perspective.

Phnom Penh: United Nations Cambodia Office of the High Commissioner for Human

Rights.

Uphoff, T. N., Esman, M. J., & Krishna, A. (1998). Reasons for Success: Learning from

Instructive Experiences in Rural Development. West Hartford, Connecticut: Kumarian

Press.

Walker, A. (2004). Seeing Farmers for the Trees: Community Forstry and the arborealisation of

agriculture in northern Thailand. Asia Pacific Viewpoint, 45(3), 311-324.

Walker, A. (2009). Local values and contract farming in northern Thailand. In D. Caouette & S.

Turner (Eds.), Agrarian Angst and Rural Resistance in Contemporary Southeast Asia.

Abingdon: Routledge.

Van Acker, F. (1999). Hitting a Stone with an Egg? Cambodia's rural economy and land tenure

in transition. Antwerp: Centre for Asian Studies & Centre for International Management

and Development.

Vickery, M. (1984). Cambodia: 1975-82. Boston: South End Press.

Vickery, M. (1999, 17th October). Revisiting the Legalities of '93. Phnom Penh Post,

Williams, G. (1981). The World Bank and the Peasant Problem. In J. Heyer, P. Roberts & G.

Williams (Eds.), Rural Development in Tropical Africa. New York: St Martin's Press.

Williams, S. (1999). Review of Land Issues Literature in Cambodia. Phnom Penh: Oxfam GB.

Williams, S. (2003). The Thailand Land Titling Program: Challenges to Land Administration.

Paper presented at the Thailand Land Ttiling Programme - Challenges to Land

Admninstration. Retrieved 1 July 2007, from

http://www.passlivelihoods.org.uk/site_files/files/reports/project_id_60/The%20Thailand

Page 266: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

248

%20Land%20Titling%20Programme%20Challenges%20to%20Land%20Conference%20

Report_LT0062.pdf

Williamson, J. (1993). Democracy and the "Washington consensus". World Development, 21(8),

1329-1336.

Willis, K. (2006). Interviewing. In V. Desai & R. B. Potter (Eds.), Doing Development Research

(pp. 144-152). London: Sage.

Woodruff, C. (2001). Review of de Soto's The Mystery of Capital. Journal of Economic

Literature, 39(4), 1215-1223.

Woodsome, K. (2005). Evictions Fuel Social Unrest in Cambodia. Retrieved 20 June 2009,

2009, from http://www.voanews.com/english/archive/2005-04/2005-04-07-

voa30.cfm?moddate=2005-04-07

World Bank. (2002). Project Appraisal Document on a Proposed Credit to the Kingdom of

Cambodia for a Land Management and Administration Project. Manila: World Bank,

East Asia and Pacific Region.

World Bank. (2006). Cambodia Poverty Assessment 2006: Halving poverty by 2015? Phnom

Penh.

World Bank. (2007a). Land Titles Give People a State in their Country. Retrieved 10th May

2010, from http://go.worldbank.org/OOMD0WCVX0

World Bank. (2007b). Sharing Growth: Equity and Development In Cambodia: Equity Report

2007. Phnom Penh: World Bank.

World Bank. (2009a). Land Management and Administration Project (LMAP) Eleventh Multi-

Donor Supervision Mission January to January 23, 2009. Phnom Penh: World Bank.

World Bank. (2009b). Management Response to the Request for an Inspection Panel Review of

the Cambodia Land Management and Administration Project (received by the Inspection

Panel on September 4, 2009). Phnom Penh: World Bank.

World Bank Inspection Panel. (2009). Report No. 51921. Report and Recommendation.

Cambodia: Land Management and Administration Project (Credit No. 3650-KH).

December 2, 2009. Washington DC: World Bank Inspection Panel.

Zoellick, R. B. (2009). Notice of Registration. Inspection Panel Request RQ 09/08. Washington,

D.C.: International Bank for Reconstruction and Development.

Zucker, E. M. (2007). Memory and (Re)making Moral Order in the Aftermath of Violence in a

Highland Khmer Village in Cambodia. London School of Economics and Political

Science, London.

Öjendal, J., & Lilja, M. (Eds.). (2009). Beyond Democracy in Cambodia: Political

Reconstruction in a Post-Conflict Society. Copenhagen: NIAS.

Önis, Z. (1991). The Logic of the Developmental State. Comparative Politics, 24(1), 109-126.

Page 267: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

249

Appendices

Appendix 1. List of Interviews Cited

Interviews are grouped: Bey 1-169; non-village 170-269; Buon 270-405

Some interviews were audio-recorded – those are indicated in the remarks column.

A small number of „interviews‟ were not formal interviews but were either conversations which

were written up later or conversations observed during the research. Where that was the case it is

likewise specified both in the remarks column and the text of the thesis.

Interviews covering land transactions are recorded as separate interviews, one per transaction,

although (as the dates and remarks make clear) they were one interview, e.g. Interviews 310, 311

and 312 were carried out at one sitting.

Numb

er

Date F/M145

146Inter

-viewer

HH147

Remarks148

3 070921 FM SD 4 Older couple and adult daughter. Came to Bey in 2000s

6 081023 FM OS 4 Daughter and son-in-law

11 080122 M RB 16 Middle-aged man, resident since 1990s

12 090215 M RB 16 Older man. Local, born in next commune.

13 081027 M RB 16 Same as 12

15 070315 F RB 28 Woman came to Bey in 2000s

17 080123 M RB 28 Man came to Bey in 2000s

18 081023 F RB 28 As for 15

21 061105 F RB 31 Middle-aged woman came to village in 1990s

22 070301 F TS 31 As 21

26 080122 F TS 31 As 21

31 080123 FM HC 43 Couple. Both born in the village.

41 080124 F HC 65 Young woman, came to village as child

43 090215 F HC 65 As 41

45 081024 F OS 74 Middle-aged woman, came from Mekong in 1990s

51 090216 F RB 2 Middle-aged woman, came from Mekong in 1990s

54 080125 F RB 18 Middle-aged woman came from Mekong in 1990s

145

F=female; M=male; FM=male and female interviewees together; FF=female interviewees together. 146

RB = Mr Robin Biddulph; TS = Ms Ton Saroth; SD = Mr Sang Dina; HC = Ms Hem Chanreth; OS = Mr Oueun

Sokra 147

HH = household number. This is from my own cataloguing and mapping, but enables the reader to see which

responses have come from the same person. 148

For Bey villagers, origins of interviewees are given as they are of explanatory value. In Buon with an

overwhelmingly locally born population this information is not provided.

Page 268: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

250

55 080125 FM RB 18 Middle-aged couple came from Mekong in 1990s

57 070301 FM RB 20 Younger couple from came from Kampong Cham early 2000s

61 081024 FM RB 25 Young couple came from Mekong in 1990s

62 081025 M TS 26 Middle-aged man married to native of village.

64 060802 M RB 29 Middle-aged man, came to village in 1990s

70 081023 M OS 29 As 64

71 081026 M RB 29 As 64. Audio-recorded

77 081024 FM TS 34 Younger couple, she born in Bey, he from another province

80 070919 F RB 36 Middle-aged woman, born in village

83 090218 F HC 36 As 80

85 081026 M HC 39 Younger man, born in the village

87 081026 M HC 48 Middle-aged man born in Bey (as is his wife)

91 070916 M RB 51 Older man, born in village

96 060726 M RB 62 Older man, came to village from Mekong in 1990s

100 070919 F RB 62 Conversation observed by RB

101 080124 FM RB 62 Middle-aged couple, came from Mekong in 1990s

103 081023 M RB 62 Older man, came to village from Mekong in 1990s

104 081024 F RB 62 Middle-aged woman, came from Mekong in 1990s

108 090217 M RB 62 Older man, came to village from Mekong in 1990s

109 080124 F TS 66 Old woman born in the village

110 081025 F HC 66 Old woman born in the village

112 081025 F HC 67 Old woman born in the village

115 080124 M RB 73 Older man, born in village

127 081026 M OS 88 Young man came to village in 2000s

145 081025 M RB 11

5

Young man came to village in 2000s. Information given in

conversation at river, not a deliberate interview.

Beginning of Bey village interviews

172 090220 M RB - RECOFTC official, Kracheh province

174 070912 M RB - Donor representative engaged with forestry issues

179 070911 M RB - Oxfam, old manager of the CF project

181 090304 M RB - Oxfam, new manager of the CF project

182 060717 M RB Oxfam, programme assistant

183 070223 M RB - Oxfam, proramme

184 081102 M RB - Oxfam, programme assistant

185 081030 M RB - Oxfam, programme officer

186 081030 F RB - Oxfam, programme officer

187 081029 M RB - EU Attaché, Natural Resource Management

193 081029 M RB - Provincial Land Management official

203 070921 M RB - BLO director

Page 269: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

251

204 081029 M RB - BLO director (audio-recorded interview)

208 070226 M RB - Forestry Administration officials, Kracheh province

210 070920 M RB - Forestry Administration official, Kracheh province

218 081028 M RB - Casotim company representative, Chhlong district

219 070912 M RB - LMAP National Director

220 081105 M RB - LMAP National Director

230 061102 M RB - Provincial LMAP official, Takeo province

231 080116 M RB - Provincial and district LMAP officials, Takeo province

232 081104 M RB - Provincial LMAP official, Takeo province

234 070213 M RB - District Chief, Bati, Takeo province

237 070925 M RB - Commune chief, Buon village

245 081015 M RB - Active Communities director (audio-recorded)

Beginning of Buon Interviews.

270 070928 FM HC 7 Older couple

271 080115 F HC 7 Older woman

273 080115 F HC 7 Older woman

276 070927 FM HC 9 Middle-aged couple

277 090210 F HC 9 Middle-aged woman

278 090210 F HC 9 Middle-aged woman

281 070926 F TS 16 Older woman

283 090211 FF RB 16 Older woman and young adult daughter

284 090211 F RB 16 Older woman

285 090211 F RB 16 Older woman

286 070927 M RB 21 Older man

287 070928 M TS 21 Older man

288 080115 M TS,RB 21 Older man

289 080118 M RB 21 Older man

290 090211 F RB 21 Older woman

291 070926 F SD 22 Young woman

292 081018 FM SD 22 Young couple

295 070927 FM SD 46 Middle-aged couple

298 090210 F OS 46 Middle-aged woman

300 061101 FM RB 52 Middle-aged couple

301 070217 FM RB 52 Middle-aged couple

302 070926 FM RB 52 Middle-aged couple

303 080117 FM RB 52 Middle-aged couple

305 070216 F RB 55 Middle-aged woman

306 080115 F RB 55 Middle-aged woman

309 090210 F RB 55 Middle-aged woman

Page 270: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

252

310 090211 F HC 1 Middle-aged woman

311 090211 F HC 1 Middle-aged woman

312 090211 F HC 1 Middle-aged woman

313 090211 F HC 4 Middle-aged woman

314 070928 F RB 5 Older woman

319 090211 F HC 13 Middle-aged woman

320 090211 F HC 13 Middle-aged woman

321 081016 F RB,HC 17 Young woman

322 090211 F RB,

HC

17 Young woman

323 090211 F HC 18 Younger woman

325 061030 M RB 20 Older man

326 060216 M RB 20 Older man

328 080116 M TS 20 Older man

329 080118 M RB 20 Older man

332 080115 M RB 23 Middle-aged woman

333 080125 F RB 25 Middle-aged woman

336 070213 F RB 27 Middle-aged woman

340 070216 F RB 27 Middle-aged woman

341 070926 F RB 27 Middle-aged woman

342 070926 F RB 27 Middle-aged woman

343 070927 F RB 27 Middle-aged woman

346 090210 F RB 27 Middle-aged woman

347 090212 F OS 27 Middle-aged woman

348 090212 F OS 27 Middle-aged woman

349 070927 FM II 28 Young couple

353 070927 FM II 31 Middle-aged couple

355 090212 FM OS 31 Middle-aged couple

357 080117 F RB 35 Old woman

364 090211 F OS 37 Middle-aged woman

365 090212 FM RB 38 Older couple

369 061031 M RB 43 Old man

371 090211 F OS 45 Younger woman

374 080115 M RB 47 Older man

378 070926 F RB 50 Middle-aged woman

383 081017 M RB 51 Old man

393 081016 F RB,TS 58 Young woman

394 090211 F OS 59 Younger woman

395 070216 F RB 60 Old woman

Page 271: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

253

396 070926 F RB 60 Old woman

401 090211 F OS 62 Middle-aged woman

402 090211 F OS 62 Middle-aged woman

405 090211 F OS 63 Older woman

406 090211 F OS 63 Older woman

410 090211 F OS 64 Old woman

Page 272: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

254

Appendix 2. Village Census Form

C1. Number of household on map ___________ (also C8 in data entry)

C2. Is the household recognised as belonging to the village?______ C3. If not, where is it recognised?_______________________

C4 Year HH formed in village ________ C5 Year current land occupied ___________ C6 Year current house built__________

C7. HH owns motorcyle? ____________ C8. HH owns television?

C9. HH owns health card?_____ C9a. If yes, give colour_________

C11.

Year of

birth

C12.

Place of

birth

C13.

Sex

C14.

Relation to

head of

HH

C15. Name C16.

Nickname

(if

different

to given

name)

C17. Location of the

person on the day of

interview

C18. Main activity of the

person on the day of

interview

Page 273: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

255

Appendix 3. 25% Livelihood Survey.

Introductory information

1. Date

2. Number of household on village map

3. Name(s) of household members interviewed

4. Names of interviewers

Land

5. House land

How big is your house land?

When did you get it?

How did you get it? 1 = Allocated; 2 = Bought (give price); 3 = Other (explain)

What (if anything) do you grow on your house land?

6. Other land that the family owns

For each plot

How big is this plot

When did you get it?

How did you get it? 1 = Allocated; 2 = Bought (give price); 3 = Other (explain)

What (if anything) are you currently growing on that land?

7. Land sales

Since living in the village have you ever sold land?

If a = yes,

How large was the land?

Was the buyer already living in the village or from outside?

What was the price of that land?

Why did you sell?

Livelihoods

Page 274: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

256

8. Our team is in this village from Monday to Friday this week. What will members of your

family do during this week to earn money? (List the activities, the members who do them and

how much money is earned during the week)

9. What other things do members of your family do to earn money during the rainy season?

10. What other things do members of your family do to earn money in the dry season?

11. During the five days our team is in this village, what food will your household eat? How will

you get that food? (List the types of food and whether it is bought – and for what prices – or

collected)

12. What else does your family eat during the rainy season and how do you get it?

13. What else does your household eat during the dry season and how do you get it?

Health

14. Who was the last person in your family to get seriously ill? What happened? (What were the

symptoms? Who did you go to? What was the treatment? What did it cost? How did you get

the money? What happened to that person?)

15. How many children have you given birth to in this village? How many of them died before

they were five? For each one who died, give the year and cause of death.

16. Has anyone in your household ever been to the health centre when they were sick?

Debt

17. Do you owe money? If yes, for each debt get the following information:

Does the lender live in the village?

What is your relationship to the lender?

How much money did you borrow?

What is the interest rate?

Why did you borrow the money?

How much capital have you paid back so far?

About the village

18. Why did you come to this village? Why do you live in this village now?

19. What are the good things about living in this village?

20. What are the bad/difficult/worrying things about living in this village?

About other places

Page 275: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

257

21. For each member of your family, when was the last time they left the village and why?

Name Month/Year Reason for travelling How long were

they away

Now you have finished the interview. Close the books and put away the pens and sit and chat

with your interviewees for a while. Take your time!

Page 276: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

258

Appendix 4. Case Study Households in Bey and Buon: Incomes and Expenditures 2006-7.

Data obtained through administration of Moving Out of Poverty questionnaire based on recall of

information since the previous Cambodian New Year (approximately 12 months). No onus was

placed on interviewers or interviewees to make sure that income and expenditures tally. The

figures are of indicative value only and are used with caution in the dissertation.

Data obtained through administration of Moving Out of Poverty questionnaire based on recall of

information since the previous Cambodian New Year (approximately 12 months). No onus was

placed on interviewers or interviewees to make sure that income and expenditures tally. The

figures are of indicative value only and are used with caution in the dissertation.

Bey village

Household HH4 HH16 HH28 HH31 HH43 HH56 HH65 HH74

Reported

Income 5 619 000 4 007 500 3 370 000 5 158 500 3 010 000 2 878 000 4 824 000 5 410 000

Reported

Expenditure 4 545 000 7 380 000 2 505 000 4 465 500 2 498 100 2 801 500 3 182 900 5 184 000

Income minus

Expenditure 1 074 000 -3 372 500 865 000 693 000 511 900 76 500 1 641 100 226 000

Buon village

Household HH7 HH9 HH16 HH21 HH22 HH46 HH52 HH55

Reported

Income 5 207 400 2 696 900 3 340 000 7 880 000 2 568 000 3 922 800 2 655 000 3 590 000

Reported

Expenditur

e

3 950 000 3 536 000 4 725 000 4 300 000 550 000 3 451 000 2 130 000 1 940 000

Income

minus

Expenditur

e

1 257 400 -839 100 -1 385 000 3 580 000 2 018 000 471 800 525 000 1 650 000

Page 277: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

259

Appendix 5. Question List for Land and Livelihood Survey I (Bey village version)

Household Number_______ Name ________________________________________

Name of informant(s) ______________________________________________________

Interviewer ______________________________________________

Date_______________________________

How much srai rice land does the household own? _____________

What was the yield this year? ______________

What is the best yield you could get from this land in a good year? _____________

How much chamcar land does your household own? _____________________

How much of this chamcar did you farm last year? _____________________

If not all, why not?

_________________________________________________________________________

_________________________________________________________________________

___________________________________________________________________________

What crops did you harvest?

Name of crop Amount Sold or ate or shared?

Page 278: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

260

(Appendix 5 continued).

Household livelihood activity matrix. Krouch January 2008.

Activity Number of Household member HH number _____________

Hiring out agricultural

labour

Selling agricultural

produce

Cattle raising

Pig raising

Poultry raising

Cutting wood

Transporting wood

Selling goods (shop)

Making and selling things

(handicrafts)

Wages (police, soldier,

village chief)

Income from checkpoints

etc

Income sent by HH

members in PNP

Income sent by HH

members elsewhere

Other

Other

Other

Page 279: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

261

(Appendix 5 continued).

Buon Household Income Sources 2007149

Activity Per

month

Per

Annum

Remarks

1 Hiring out agricultural labour

2 Selling agricultural produce

3 Cattle raising

4 Pig raising

5 Poultry raising

6 Cutting wood

7 Transporting wood

8 Selling goods (shop)

9 Making and selling things (handicrafts)

10 Wages (police, soldier, village chief)

11 Income from checkpoints etc

12 Income sent by HH members in PNP

13 Income sent by HH members

elsewhere

14 Other

15 Other

16 Other

149

Only administered in Buon. Results there so untrustworthy that it was deemed wasteful to repeat the exercise in

Bey.

Page 280: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

262

Appendix 6. Sample Structured Interview Questions: Spring 2008 (Bey version)

Case Study Family interviews:

1. What has changed since the September 2007 visit?

2. How large was the harvest? What have you done with it?

3. Current indebtedness.

a. How much borrowed?

b. From whom?

c. What rate of interest?

d. How much have you repaid so far?

e. When do you think you will be able to repay?

4. What are the main changes you have noticed in the village since you were small?/Since

you came to the village?

Key Informant Interviews

Selected interviews with „key informants‟ (researcher‟s discretion to identify people who would

be able to give reliable answers)

a. Pagoda/monks

b. Education services

c. Health services (private and public)

d. Police

e. Commune Council

f. Village chief

g. Political parties

h. Tong tin

Appendix 7. Land and livelihood Survey (II) in Bey, October 2008

Follow-up to Survey in January 2008 and administered as supplementary questions during the

implementation of Village Census (II).

1. What has been your household‟s main livelihood activity since the rains began this year?

2. How much agricultural land have you planted this year?

3. How much agricultural land do you own?

4. Are you a member of the community forestry?

Page 281: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

263

Appendix 8. Survey of Land Transactions in Buon 2009. Summary Data

Land Transactions (1980-2008) Reported During the 2008 Land and Livelihood Survey in

Buon. Table 1: Reported Sales (n=4).

Int Year Reason How authorized Issues since Other

310 1998 Illness None She signed a letter at

time of titling. No

money changed hands.

Just 10a at the

edge of village

319 1996 Illness/poverty None No (interviewer forgot

to ask!)

Regrets selling

as would be

valuable now

355 1993 To buy other land

near their house

Letter from village

chief (requested by

buyer)

No problems

395 1985 To pay for an

operation

None (Sale was to their

daughter)

No problems Daughter used

for house land

Land Transactions (1980-2008) Reported During the 2008 Land and Livelihood Survey in

Buon. Table 1: Reported Purchases (n=26).

Int Year Reason How authorized Issues since Other

311 2003 Reclaiming

unpaid debt

Village chief knew,

because involved in

trying to persuade

villager to honour his

debt. No paper

Former owner tried to

reclaim during titling

but village chief

supported her against

him. However, she

signed an agreement that

she now regrets150

.

Land in nearby

village. 531 m2

of rice land

312 2003 Reclaiming

unpaid debt

Village chief knew but

no paper

Same as for 217 case. 1893 m2 of

poor land in

same village

313 2006 Needed more rice

land for her

children

Just informed the

village and commune

chief verbally.

No, and she is not

concerned even though

the seller‟s mother‟s

name is on the title.

Did not register

the transaction

or change the

name on the

title.

150

At the time of titling, title was awarded to her, but she signed an agreement witnessed by the village chief that

when his children were older they would have the right to get the land back if they paid the 2,000,000 riels (500

USD) that were owed to her, and that she would not sell to anyone else in the meantime. She worries that this may

have been a mistake because prices are going up and in a few years time 2,000,000 may not be worth much at all

compared to the value of the land.

Page 282: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

264

273 1998 Wanted more

agricultural land

to be able to give

to their children

Just word of mouth. Had been a bit worried

that the old owner

would try and get it back

but that never happened.

278 ? (Pre-

2005)

Land near their

house and they

wanted more

when her

husband came

back.

No authorization with

the authorities at all.

She became anxious that

the seller might try and

get the land back, and

was especially worried

when the titling

programme was

announced. And then

relieved when it was not

a problem.

320 2007 She had extra

money and would

like more land

No formal witnessing

but friends and

neighbours know about

it.

No problems. And she

says she would just

accept the loss if there

was a problem.

Not a sale but

she was the

pawnee

284 1999 Had extra money

from her business

Got authorities

signatures and paid

them 3000 riels.

Repeated the process

during titling, but paid

5000 to village chief and

15000 to commune

chief.

285 2004 Land for her

married daughter

Land was already titled

in that village. She

bought from her niece

and the transaction was

not authorized.

She now wants to sell

the land so that her

daughter can move

home. But her niece is

obstructing by saying

that it will cost 300 to

400 USD to transfer the

title.

(Niece wants to

get the land

back for the

original sale

price, although

it has now gone

up in value).

322 1997 All four

purchases were in

order to have

more land to

distribute to their

children.

Village chief wrote a

letter to authorize the

purchase

At titling they lied to

officials pretending the

land had been allocated

by the state

(To avoid

paying land

transfer tax

retrospectively)

1999 Village chief wrote a

letter to authorize

Land has not been titled

yet, but she does not

know why. She is not

worried because she

trusts the seller.

Land is in a

neighbouring

village.

2000 Village chief wrote a

letter to authorize

At titling they called the

seller to come and

witness the fact that he

had sold to them.

They have

never felt

anxious about

the process.

2001 Missing information Missing information Land was in

neigbouring

village

Page 283: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

265

323 2000 They didn‟t have

much rice land

No witnessing of the

transaction, but the

village chief is her

father

When the land was titled

the seller came and

signed a letter

confirming the sale

347 1994 Plot was near

their land and

they wanted more

rice land

No official letter

because they trusted the

seller

Seller‟s father tried to

claim the land back

during the titling

process. Resolved in

their favour and now

they are not worried.

348 1995 Two plots as

repayment of

debts

No authorization. They

were not worried

because they trusted the

seller.

Titled in their name

now. Never any issues

and they were never

worried.

341 1990 To increase land

holdings and

have more for

their children

No authorization. They

thought it was enough

that their neighbours

knew.

No worries at any time,

including during titling.

364 1987 Bought as house

land for children

because it was

cheap at the time

Secured with a letter

from the village chief.

They have lost the letter

but are not worried.

Especially as the former

owner has left the

village.

371 1987 As payment for

helping a nephew

move house

No authorization

because it was in the

family and they have

good relations

It has never been a

worry or a problem

since

394 2005 Bought from her

sister to help her

and to keep the

land in the family

Did not register

because it was bought

from a family member.

No problems Their mothers

name was and

remains on the

land title.

401 1992 Bought land for

house when they

moved to the

village

Letter from the village

chief.

Systematic land titling

made them worried that

the old owner might

come and try and claim

the land, but that didn‟t

happen, so no problems.

402 2004 To buy rice land

for now and for

their children to

inherit

Letter from the village

chief.

No problems. Did not

think the letter was

necessary to secure the

transaction, just did it

because it is the right

thing to do.

Land in a

neighbouring

village.

405 2007 To get rice land

now and to have

more to leave for

their children

Got a letter from the

village chief.

Never even thought of

changing the name on

the title

Land is in

neighbouring

village

Page 284: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

266

406 Pre-

2005

Bought from her

parents

Did not get transaction

authorized as they are

family.

Their name is now on

the title

Title is

currently with

ACLEDA

credit

organization as

collateral

410 1987 Bought land that

she had given to

her daughter back

again in order to

keep it in the

family

Letter from the village

chief, and the commune

chief. Paid 5000 to

village chief and

30000151

to commune

chief.

151

From author‟s notes: “She paid 30 000 to the commune chief and 5000 to the village chief. None of them fixed a

price. But when she gave 10 000 to the commune chief he didn‟t look at the document. When she gave him 20 000

riels he picked it up but still had difficulty with it and read slowly. After 30 000 he could read it quickly and fix

everything” (Interview 349).

Page 285: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

267

Appendix 9. LMAP Written Questions and Response, April 2010

The following seven questions were submitted to selected people close to the LMAP project on

4th

April 2010. One respondent provided written answers to the questions, another respondent

provided links to an anonymous commentator who did not answer the questions but provided

generous comments on a chapter draft. The World Bank‟s Task Manager‟s response is provided

below the questions.

Questions text.

1. Are you aware of any places where systematic land titling made a clear difference to

agricultural investment and farming strategies? (Please provide names of commune, district,

province).

2. Systematic land titling was promoted, particularly by the World Bank, as having the potential

to transform the smallholder agriculture sector by giving farmers the security and confidence

to invest in their land, and thereby improve agricultural productivity. When you began your

engagement with LMAP, did you expect titling to have such a transformative effect? Have

your expectations changed at all over time?

3. As I have understood (from my own and others‟ research findings), most subsequent

transactions are not being registered with the cadastral authorities. Did you personally

believe that this would probably be a problem when you first became involved? Do you

personally believe that systematic land titling is worthwhile even if subsequent transactions

are not registered? Why/why not?

4. My focus is rural. The LMAP project document suggests that land titling is promising both in

regard to improving security in areas afflicted by appropriations and conflicts, and also in the

relatively secure smallholder rice plains. Thus far the project has been implemented in the

relatively secure smallholder rice plains. Do you believe that systematic registration should

be pursued now in rural areas characterised by insecurity and conflict (eg newly-settled

populations in forested provinces in the north-west and north-east; populations settled along

the Thai border in Banteay Meanchey province etc)? Why/why not?

5. For some people, development work is about pursuing the objectives in the project document.

For others, the project document is a formal agreement that is necessary to enable work to

proceed, but what is possible and desirable are shaped by other ideas. For you personally, do

you see your role as closely pursuing the project document objectives, or do you have other

ideas and priorities? What are these and where do they come from? (Your employer? Your

conversations with colleagues and clients? Your own judgements and experience?)

Page 286: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

268

6. As you see it (based on your own observations, or on research and evaluation reports, or on

educated guess work), what difference (if any) is systematic land titling likely to make to

rural poverty in Cambodia in the short or long term?

7. If I cite/refer to your answers above, how would you prefer that I identify them?

a. With your name and job title (please provide):

b. As a „Ministry Official working on the LMAP project‟

c. As an „International Technical Advisor working on the LMAP project‟

d. As a „Confidential source close to the LMAP project‟

e. Other (please provide) :

Final questions from Robin Biddulph

[email protected] <[email protected]> 21 April 2010 06:50

To: Robin Biddulph <[email protected]>

Cc: [email protected], [email protected], Cyprian Selebalo <[email protected]>

Dear Robin,

In light of the ongoing Inspection Panel Review of LMAP Bank staff and consultants are not able to provide

responses to your questions but we would like to draw your attention to the Management Response that has

already been prepared and posted on the Inspection Panel Website (www.worldbank.org/inspectionpanel ) and we hope that this document will be helpful as you finalize your research.

With best regards,

Peter

_____________________________________

Peter Jipp

Sr. Natural Resources Management Specialist

World Bank Office

30th Floor, Siam Tower

989 Rama 1 Road

Pathumwan, Bangkok 10330

Tel +66(0)2686-8392 Fax +66(0)2686-8301

Cell Numbers

Thailand +66840036814

Lao PDR +856203397865

Cambodia +85592578059

Page 287: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

269

Meddelanden från Göteborgs Universitets Geografiska Institutioner, Serie B. Doktorsavhandlingar från institutionen för kulturgeografi och ekonomisk geografi, Göteborgs universitet Nr 1 Olof Wärneryd: Interdependence in urban systems. 1968

Nr 17 Lennart Andersson: Rumsliga effekter av organisationsförändringar. Studier i lokalisering med exempel

från skolväsendet. 1970

Nr 23 Lars Nordström: Rumsliga förändringar och ekonomisk utveckling. 1971

Nr 43 Kenneth Asp: Interregionala godstransporter i ett rumsligt system. 1975

Nr 44 Jan Lundqvist: Local and central impulses for change and development. A case study of Morogoro

District, Tanzania. 1975

Nr 56 Staffan Öhrling: Rural change and spatial reorganization in Sri Lanka. Barriers against development of

traditional Sinhalese local communities. 1977

Nr 57 Ulf Halloff: Inköpsresor i ett rumsligt system. Metodstudier på grundval av empiriskt material från några

stadsdelar i Göteborg. 1977

Nr 59 Lage Wahlström: Naturvården i regional och lokal planering. Geografiska studier med exempel från

Göteborgsregionen och övriga delar av de västsvenska länen. 1977

Nr 60 Kent Persson: Sysselsättningen i centrum. Sysselsättningsförändringar i stadscentrum, deras orsaker och

verkan - med exempel från Göteborg.1977

Nr 63 Claes Göran Alvstam: Utrikeshandel och rumslig dynamik. En studie av den väst-europeiska interna

utrikeshandelns ländersammansättning 1955-1975. 1979

Nr 64 Sten Lorentzon: Ortsstruktur, arbetsresor och energiförbrukning. Förändringar i bebyggelsestrukturen och

energikonsumtionen vid arbetsresor belysta med exempel från västra Sverige.1979

Nr 65 Bengt Holmgren: Transportförändringar och rumslig utveckling. Geografiska studier av

järnvägsnedläggningars effekter med exempel från två västsvenska kommuner.1980

Nr 66 Rolf Pettersson: Omlokalisering av statlig verksamhet. Effekter på arbetsmarknaden i mottagande orter.

1980

Nr 69 Åke Forsström: Commuting accidents. A study of commuting accidents and casualties in some Swedish

regions during 1971. 1982

Nr 71 Christina Nordin: Marchés, commerçants, clientèle. le commerce non sédentaire de la région Parisienne -

Etude de géographie humaine. 1983

Nr 72 Kajsa Ellegård: Människa - produktion. Tidsbilder av ett produktionssystem. 1983

Nr 73 Kjell Gustafsson: Tekoindustrin och förändringarna i den internationella arbetsfördelningen.

Konsekvenser för lokalisering och sysselsättning i Sverige. 1983

Nr 74 Ingrid Johansson: Arbetsplatslokalisering i staden: dåtid-nutid-framtid. Exempel från några stadsdelar i

Göteborg. 1984

Nr 75 Magnus Torell: Fisheries in Thailand. Geographical studies about the utilization of resources in semi-

enclosed seas. 1984

Nr 77 Bertil Vilhelmson: Resurser och resor. Äldres aktivitet och handikapp i trafiken. 1985

Nr 78 Gerhard Gustafsson: Etik och lokala utvecklingsstrategier. Bevaring eller förändring av människans

livsvillkor. 1986

Nr 79 Lars Aronsson: Turism och lokal utveckling. En turism-geografisk studie. 1989

Nr 80 Peter de Souza: Territorial production complexes in the Soviet Union - with special focus on Siberia.

1989

Nr 81 Bertil Lundberg: Industriella beroenden. Rumslig och strukturell förändring i ett värmlandsperspektiv.

1991

Nr 82 Thomas Jordan: Flows of pumps: Structure and change in the international division of labour. 1992

Nr 84 Joel Yrlid: Mission och kommunikation. Den kristna missionen och transportnätets utveckling i Belgiska

Kongo/Zaire 1878-1991. 1993

Nr 85 Martin Gren: Earth writing: Exploring representation and social geography in-between meaning/matter.

1994

Nr 86 Sören Eriksson: Global shift in the aircraft industry. A study of airframe manufacturing with special

reference to the Asian NIEs. 1995

Nr 87 Gabriel Bladh: Finnskogens landskap och människor under fyra sekler. En studie av natur och samhälle i

förändring. 1995

Nr 88 Anders Närman: Education and nation building in Kenya. Perspectives on modernization, global

dependency and local development alternatives. 1995

Page 288: 100517 Thesis Biddulph Geographies of Evasion

270

Nr 89 Thomas Blom: Perspektiv på kunskap och utveckling. Om högskoleutbildningens betydelse i perifera

regioner. 1996

Nr 90 Inge Ivarsson: Integrated international production. A study of foreign transnational corporations in

Sweden. 1996

Nr 91 Sang Chul Park: The technopolis plan in Japanese industrial policy. 1997

Nr 92 Johan Dahl: A cry for water. Perceptions of development in Binga district, Zimbabwe. 1997

Nr 94 Margareta Espling: Women's livelihood strategies in processes of change. Cases from urban

Mozambique. 1999

Nr 95 Lars-Gunnar Krantz: Rörlighetens mångfald och förändring. Befolkningens dagliga resande i Sverige

1978 och 1996. 1999

Nr 96 Per Assmo: Livelihood strategies and land degradation. Perceptions among small-scale farmers in Ng'iresi

village, Tanzania. 1999

Nr 97 Anders Larsson: Proximity matters? Geographical aspects of changing strategies in automotive

subcontracting relationships: The case of domestic suppliers to Volvo Torslanda assembly plant. 1999

Nr 98 Mikael Jonasson: The creation of places in traffic through performative action. 2000

Nr 99 Matilde Mordt: Livelihoods and sustainability at the agrarian frontier. The evolution of the frontier in

Southeastern Nicaragua. 2001

Nr 101 Kersti Nordell: Kvinnors hälsa – en fråga om medvetenhet, möjlighet och makt. Att öka förståelsen för

människors livssammanhang genom tidsgeografisk analys. 2002

Nr 102 Åsa Westermark: Informal livelihoods: Woman's biographies and reflections about everyday life. A time-

geographic analysis in urban Colombia. 2003

Nr 103 Bodil Jansund och Ulrika Blom-Mondlane: Geografi-didaktik-praktik. Interaktiva studier av för-

loppslandskapet. 2003

Nr 104 Alf Brodin: Baltic Sea ports and Russian foreign trade. Studies in the economic and political geography of

transition. 2003

Nr 105 Eva Thulin: Ungdomars virtuella rörlighet. Användningen av dator, internet och mobiltelefon i ett

geografiskt perspektiv. 2004

Nr 107 Patrik Ström: The 'lagged' internationalization of Japanese professional business service firms:

Experiences from the UK and Singapore. 2004

Nr 108 Jonas Lindberg: Education for all in times of global transformations: Aspirations and opportunities of

poor families in marginal areas of Sri Lanka. 2005

Nr 109 Ulf Ernstson: Kontrakt med naturen. Om spridning och implementering av miljöledningssystem. 2006

Nr 110 Jerry Olsson: Responses to change in accessibility. Socio-economic impacts of road investment: the

distributive outcomes in two rural peripheral Philippine municipalities. 2006

Nr 111 Iraê Baptista Lundin: Negotiating transformation: Urban livelihoods in Maputo adapting to thirty years of

political and economic changes. 2007

Nr 112 Curt Nestor: Foreign direct investment in the Socialist Republic of Vietnam 1988-2000: Geographical

perspectives. 2007

Nr 113 Lena Lindberg: The regionalisation process in Southeast Asia and the economic integration of Cambodia

and Laos into ASEAN. 2007

Nr 114 Kristina Thorell: Naturvårdsplanering med förankring i det lokala. Villkor för delaktighet och under-

ifrånperspektiv i vården av värden i landskapet. 2008

Nr 115 Jean Paul Dushimumuremyi: Spatial distribution of water resources and accessibility to water. The case

of Bugesera District in Rwanda. 2009

Nr 116 Théophile Niyonzima: Land use dynamics in the face of population increase. A study in the districts of

Gatsibo and Nyagatare, Eastern Province, Rwanda. 2009

Nr 117 Robin Biddulph: Geographies of Evasion. The Development Industry and Property Rights Interventions in

Early 21st Century Cambodia. 2010