41
1 ECON6021 Microeconomic Analysis Consumption Theory I

1 ECON6021 Microeconomic Analysis Consumption Theory I

  • View
    243

  • Download
    1

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

1

ECON6021 Microeconomic Analysis

Consumption Theory I

2

Topics covered

1. Budget Constraint

2. Axioms of Choice & Indifference Curve

3. Utility Function

4. Consumer Optimum

3

Y

X

YA

YB

XA XB

A

B

Bundle of goods

• A is a bundle of goods consisting of XA units of good X (say food) and YA units of good Y (say clothing).

• A is also represented by (XA,YA)

4

Convex Combination

B

AC

(xA, YA)

(xA, YB)

x

y))1(,)1((),( BABAcc yttyxttxyx

5

BBA

BBA

xxttx

yytty

))1((

))1((CB of Slope

C is on the st. line linking A & B

AB of Slope

BA

BA

BA

BA

xx

yy

txtx

tyty

Conversely, any point on AB can be written as

[0,1] t where))1(,)1(( BABA yttyxttx

Convex Combination

6

Slope of budget line

y

x

P

P

dx

dy (market rate of substitution)

Unit: $) ofnt (independejar per loaves loafper $

jarper $

7

Example:

jar of beer Px=$4loaf of bread Py=$2

jarper loaves 2loafper 2$

jarper 4$

y

x

P

P

Both Px and Py double,

xP

I0

feasible consumption set

yP

I0|Slope|=

y

x

P

P

jarper loaves 2loafper 4$

jarper 8$'

'

y

x

P

PNo change in market rate of substitution

8

Tax: a $2 levy per unit is imposed for each good

2

3

2$2$

2$4$

tP

tP

y

x Slope of budget line changes

y

x

20I

40I

40I

60I

after levy is imposed

80I

After doubling the prices

9

Axioms of Choice

& Indifference Curve

10

Axioms of Choice

• Nomenclature: : “is preferred to” : “is strictly preferred to” : “is indifferent to”

• Completeness (Comparison)– Any two bundles can be compared and one of the

following holds: AB, B A, or both ( A~B)• Transitivity (Consistency)

– If A, B, C are 3 alternatives and AB, B C, then A C; – Also If AB, BC, then A C.

11

Axioms of choice• Continuity

– AB and B is sufficiently close to C, then A C.

• Strong Monotonicity (more is better)– A=(XA , YA), B=(XB , YB) and XA≥XB, YA≥YB with at

least one is strict, then A>B.

• Convexity– If AB, then any convex combination of A& B is

preferred to A and to B, that is, for all 0 t <1,– (t XA+(1-t)XB, tYA+(1-t)YB) (Xi , Yi), i=A or B.– If the inequality is always strict, we have strict

convexity.

12

Indifference Curve• When goods are divisible and there are only

two types of goods, an individual’s preferences can be conveniently represented using indifference curve map.

• An indifference curve for the individual passing through bundle A connects all bundles so that the individual is indifferent between A and these bundles.

13

Properties of Indifference Curves

• Negative slopes• ICs farther away from

origin means higher satisfaction

X

Y

A

I

II

Not preferred bundles

Preferred bundles

14

• Non-intersection– Two indifference

curves cannot intersect

• Coverage– For any bundle, there

is an indifference curve passing through it. X

Y

AQ

P

Properties of Indifference Curves

15

• Bending towards Origin– It arises from

convexity axiom

– The right-hand- side IC is not allowed

X

Y

Properties of Indifference Curves

16

Utility Function

17

Utility Function

• Level of satisfaction depends on the amount consumed: U=U(x,y)

• U0 =U(x,y)– All the combination of x & y that yield U0 (all

the alternatives along an indifference curve)

• y=V(x,U0), an indifference curve U(x,y)/x, marginal utility respect to x,

written as MUx.

18

X

Y

A

B

YA

YB

XA XB

U0

dyy

yxUdx

x

yxUdU

),(),(

0

( , ) ( , )0

U x y U x ydU dx dy

x y

(by construction)

Slope: /

0/

xU U

y

dy U x MU

dx U y MU

(if strong monotonicity

holds)

19

Bxy

Axy MRSMRS A

B

X

Y

0U

The MRS is the max amount of good y a consumer would willingly forgo for one more unit of x, holding utility constant (relative value of x expressed in unit of y)

20

• Marginal rate of substitution

0

/0

/x

xyU U y

dy dy U x MUMRS

dx dx U y MU

DMRS: 0 constant 0U

dMRS

dx

21

U=10

U=20

U=30

V=100

V=200V=2001

An order-preserving re-labeling of ICs does not alter the preference ordering.

Measurability of Utility

22

11

22

66

222''''

'''

''

222'

yxUU

xyUU

xyUU

yxUU

xyU

Positive monotonic (order-preserving) transformation

• They are called positive monotonic transformation

23

Positive Monotonic Transformation

What is the MRS of U at (x,y)?

How about U’?

xy

U

yx

U

/MRS

/

U x y

U y x

yxy

U

xyx

U

2'

2'

2

2

2

2

'/ 2MRS'

'/ 2

U x xy y

U y x y x

24

Positive Monotonic Transformation

• IC’s of order-preserving transformation U’ overlap those of U.

• However, we have to make sure that the numbering of the IC must be in same order before & after the transformation.

25

Positive Monotonic Transformation

• Theorem: Let U=U(X,Y) be any utility function. Let V=F(U(X,Y)) be an order-preserving transformation, i.e., F(.) is a strictly increasing function, or dF/dU>0 for all U. Then V and U represent the same preferences.

26

Proof

Consider any two bundles and

Then we have:

( , )A AA x y

( , ).B BB x y

( , ) ( , )

( ( , )) ( ( , ))

( , ) ( , )

U

A A B B

A A B B

A A B B

V

A B

U x y U x y

F U x y F U x y

V x y V x y

A B

Q.E.D.

27

Consumer Optimum

28

Constrained Consumer Choice Problem

• Preferences: represented by indifference curve map, or utility function U(.)

• Constraint: budget constraint-fixed amount of money to be used for purchase

• Assume there are two types of goods x and y, and they are divisible

29

Consumption problem• Budget constraint

– I0= given money income in $– Px= given price of good x– Py= given price of good y

• Budget constraint: I0Pxx+Pyy• Or, I0= Pxx+Pyy (strong monotonicity)

dI0= Pxdx+Pydy=0 (by construction)

Pxdx=-Pydy

30

D

BYB

YD

XB XA XD

C

A

BA

DBxy XX

yyMRS

Psychic willingness to substitute

At B, my MRS is very high for X. I’m willing to substitute XA-XB forYB-YD. But the market provides me more X to point D!

y

xxy P

PMRS

31

Consumer Optimum

• Normally, two conditions for consumer optimum:

• MRSxy = Px/Py (1)

• No budget left unused (2)

32

Y

X

A

C

U1U0

Both A & C satisfy (1) and (2)

Problem: “bending toward origin” does not hold.

33

coffee

teaU0

U1

U2

Generally low MRS

tea

coffee

Generally high MRS

y)(x, allfor y

xxy P

PMRS y)(x, allfor

y

xxy P

PMRS

Special Cases

34

Quantity Control

• Max U=U(x,y)

Subject to (i) I ≥Pxx+Pyy

(ii) R≥x

35

y

x

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(1) Corner at x=0(2) Interior solution 0<x<R(3) “corner” at R(4) “corner” at R

36

,max

subject to (1)

,

MRS market rate of sub. (2)

or

Hence ,

x y

x y

x y

x x

y y

y x

x y

U xy

I P x P y

MU y MU x

MU y P

MU x P

P y P x

I Ix y

P P

( (1))

An Example: U(x,y)=xy

37

C

D

B

A

A satisfies (1) but not (2)B, C satisfy (2) but not (1)Only D satisfies both (1) &(2)

1 11

2 2 / 2x x x

x I I I

I x P x P I P

38

Other Examples of Utility Functions

},min{),(

),(

yxyxU

yxyxU

39

An application: Intertemporal Choice

• Our framework is flexible enough to deal with questions such as savings decisions and intertemporal choice.

40

Intertemporal choice problem

C1

C2

1600

1000

500 Slope = -1.1

u(c1,c2)=const

Income in period 2

Income in period 2

41

1000-C1=S (1)

500+S(1+r)=C2 (2)Substituting (1) into (2), we have

500+(1000-C1)(1+r)=C2

Rearranging, we have

1500+1000r-(1+r) C1=C2 > C

Using C1=C2=C, we finally have 1600 1500 1000 500

10002.1 2 2

rC

r r

r C (S )