42
1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

  • View
    216

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: 1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

1

Chapter 2

Technology, Costs

and

Market Structure

Page 2: 1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

2

Introduction• Industries have very different structures

– numbers and size distributions of firms• ready-to-eat breakfast cereals: high concentrationTop 4 firms account for about 80% of sales• Games and toys (not including video games): The largest 4 firms accounts for 35% to 45%

• How best to measure market structure– summary measure (p55, Figure 2-1)– concentration curve is possible– preference is for a single number– concentration ratio or Herfindahl-Hirschman

index (HHI)

Page 3: 1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

3

Measure of concentration• Compare two different measures of concentration:

Firm Rank Market Share Squared Market (%) Share

1 25

2 25

3 25

4 5

5 5

6 5

7 5

8 5

625

625

625

25

25

25

25

25

CR4 = 80Concentration Index HHI = 2,000

25

25

25

5

Page 4: 1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

4

• Concentration index is affected by, e.g. merger

Firm Rank Market Share Squared Market (%) Share

1 25

2 25

3 25

4 5

5 5

6 5

7 5

8 5

625

625

625

25

25

25

25

25

CR4 = 80Concentration Index HHI = 2,000

25

25

25

5} } }10

85

100

2,050

Assume that firms4 and 5 decide

to merge

The ConcentrationIndex changes

Market shareschange

Page 5: 1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

5

2.1.2 What is a market?• No clear consensus:To use CR4 or HHI as an

overall measure of a market’s structure, we need to be able to identify a well-defined market first.Example 1, the market for automobiles

• should we include light trucks; pick-ups SUVs?Example 2, the market for soft drinks

• what are the competitors for Coca Cola and Pepsi?– With whom do McDonalds and Burger King

compete?• Presumably define a market by closeness in

substitutability of the commodities involved– how close is close?

Page 6: 1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

6

Market definition (cont.)– how homogeneous do commodities have to be?

• Does wood compete with plastic? Rayon with wool?

• Definition is important– without consistency concept of a market is meaningless– need indication of competitiveness of a market: affected by

definition– public policy: decisions on mergers can turn on market

definition• Staples/Office Depot merger rejected on market definition• Coca Cola expansion turned on market definition

• Standard approach has some consistency– based upon industrial data– substitutability is production not consumption (ease of data

collection)

Page 7: 1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

7

• Government statistical sourcesCensus Bureau:

Standard Industrial Classification (SIC)North American Industry Classification System

(NAICS)• The measure of concentration varies across countries• Use of production-based statistics has limitations:

– can put in different industries products that are in the same market

• The international dimension is important– Boeing/McDonnell-Douglas merger– relevant market for automobiles, oil, hairdressing

Market definition (cont.)

Page 8: 1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

8

• Geography is important– barrier to entry if the product is expensive to

transport– but customers can move

• what is the relevant market for a beach resort or ski-slope?

• Vertical relations between firms are important– most firms make intermediate rather than final goods– firm has to make a series of make-or-buy choices– upstream and downstream production– measures of concentration may assign firms at

different stages to the same industry• do vertical relations affect underlying structure?

Market definition (cont.)

Page 9: 1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

9

– Firms at different stages may also be assigned to different industries

• bottlers of soft drinks: low concentration

• suppliers of sift drinks: high concentration

• the bottling sector is probably not competitive.

• In sum: market definition poses real problems

– existing methods represent a reasonable compromise

Market definition (cont.)

Page 10: 1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

10

2.2.1 The Neoclassical View of the Firm

• Concentrate upon a neoclassical view of the firm– the firm transforms inputs into outputs

Inputs Outputs

The Firm

• There is an alternative approach (Coase)– What happens inside firms?– How are firms structured? What determines size?– How are individuals organized/motivated?

Page 11: 1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

11

2.2.2 The Single-Product Firm• Profit-maximizing firm must solve a related problem

– minimize the cost of producing a given level of output

– combines two features of the firm• production function: how inputs are transformed into output

Assume that there are n inputs at levels x1 for the first, x2 for the second,…, xn for the nth. The production function, assuming a single output, is written:

Q = F(x1, x2, x3,…,xn)• cost function: relationship between output choice and

production costs. Derived by finding input combination that minimizes cost

Minimize subject to F(x1, x2, x3,…,xn) = Q1 wixii=1

n

Page 12: 1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

12

• Review input choice: one output and two inputs

x2

x1

Q0

Q1

Q2

The production functioncan be illustrated as a set of

isoquants, one foreach level of output

The production functioncan be illustrated as a set of

isoquants, one foreach level of output

Production cost can beillustrated as a set of

isocost lines, with slopew1/w2. The lower theisocost line, the lower

the cost.

Production cost can beillustrated as a set of

isocost lines, with slopew1/w2. The lower theisocost line, the lower

the cost.

Cost of producing output Q1 is minimized

by finding the pointwhere an isocost line

is tangent to theQ1 isoquant

Cost of producing output Q1 is minimized

by finding the pointwhere an isocost line

is tangent to theQ1 isoquant

x11

x12

The input choiceis x1

1 of input 1and x1

2 of input 2

The input choiceis x1

1 of input 1and x1

2 of input 2

Now assume that input 1 becomes cheaper

This makes the isocost lines less steep

The new cost-minimizing point

The new cost-minimizing point

More ofinput 1 is

used and lessof input 2

More ofinput 1 is

used and lessof input 2 x2

1

x22

The cost-minimizing input combination changes

The cost-minimizing input combination changes

Page 13: 1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

13

• This analysis has interesting implications– different input mix across

• time: as capital becomes relatively cheaper

• space: difference in factor costs across countries

• Analysis gives formal definition of the cost function– denoted C(Q): total cost of producing output Q– average cost = AC(Q) = C(Q)/Q– marginal cost:

• additional cost of producing one more unit of output.

• Slope of the total cost function

• formally: MC(Q) = dC(Q)/d(Q)

Page 14: 1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

14

Cost curves: an illustration

$/unit

Quantity

AC

MC

Typical average and marginal cost curvesTypical average and marginal cost curves

Relationship between AC and MC

If MC < AC then AC is falling

If MC > AC then AC is rising

MC = AC at the minimum of the AC curve

Page 15: 1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

15

Economies of scale• Definition: average costs fall with an increase in output• Represented by the scale economy index

S =AC(Q)

MC(Q)• S > 1: economies of scale• S < 1: diseconomies of scale• S is the inverse of the elasticity of cost with respect to output

C =dC(Q)

C(Q)

dQ

Q=

dC(Q)

dQ

C(Q)

Q=

MC(Q)

AC(Q)=

1

S

Page 16: 1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

16

An example

• Take a simple example

Output Total Cost Average Cost Marginal Cost Scale Economy ($) ($) ($) Index5 725 145

6 816 13691}

11 1331 121

12 1488 124} 157

140.5 140.5/91 = 1.54

122.5/157 = 0.78Average cost is

taken as the mean of 145 and 136

Average cost istaken as the mean

of 145 and 136122.5

Check the relationship to the elasticity of the cost curve

Check the relationship to the elasticity of the cost curve

816 - 725Percentage increase in cost of increasing output from 5 to 6 (816+725)/2

= 11.8%

Percentage increase in output6-5

(6+5)/2= 18.2%

C = 11.8/18.2 = 0.65 and 1/ C = 1/0.65 = 1.54

Page 17: 1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

17

• Minimum efficient scale: – output at which economies of scale are first exhausted

$/unit

Quantity

AC1

MES1

AC2

MES2

With average cost curve AC1 minimum efficient

scale is MES1

With average cost curve AC2 minimum efficient

scale is MES2

Page 18: 1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

18

Natural monopoly• If the extent of the market is less than MES then the market is a

natural monopoly: S > 1 in such a market.• But a natural monopoly can exist even if S < 1.

Economies of scale• Sources of economies of scale

– “the 60% rule”: capacity related to volume while cost is related to surface area

– product specialization and the division of labor– “economies of mass reserves”: economize on inventory,

maintenance, repair– indivisibilities

Page 19: 1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

19

Indivisibilities• Some inputs can be employed

only in indivisible units– transport routes

– major items of capital equipment

$

$

Quantity

Quantity

Q1

Q1

FC

VC

AFC

AVCATC

• Three implications:– cost is “lumpy” or fixed at F1

– maximum rated capacity Q1

– average fixed cost F1/Q falls with output up to rated capacity

• Other inputs vary with output: variable costs

• Average total costs exhibit economies of scale over some range

F1

Page 20: 1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

20

• If projected output is greater than current capacity install higher-rated capacity equipment or add additional capacity

• It may be cheaper to have spare capacity than operate up to capacity

$/unit

AC1 AC2

QuantityQ1 Q2

If projected output is greater than Q* it is cheaper to

install higher capacity even though there is spare

capacity

Q*

Consistent with evidence on excess capacity: see

Federal Statistics

Page 21: 1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

21

• Indivisibilities make scale of entry an important strategic decision:– enter large with large-scale indivisibilities: heavy overhead– enter small with smaller-scale cheaper equipment: low overhead

• Some indivisible inputs can be redeployed– aircraft

• Other indivisibilities are highly specialized with little value in other uses– market research expenditures– rail track between two destinations

• The latter are sunk costs: nonrecoverable if production stops

• Fixed costs and sunk costs affect market structure by affecting entry

Fixed costs, indivisibilities and sunk costs

Page 22: 1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

22

Multi-Product Firms

• Many firms make multiple products– Ford, General Motors, 3M etc.

• What do we mean by costs and output in these cases?• How do we define average costs for these firms?

– total cost for a two-product firm is C(Q1, Q2)

– marginal cost for product 1 is MC1 = C(Q1,Q2)/Q1

– but average cost cannot be defined fully generally

– need a more restricted definition: ray average cost

Page 23: 1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

23

Ray average cost• Assume that a firm makes two products, 1 and 2 with the

quantities Q1 and Q2 produced in a constant ratio of 2:1.• Then total output Q can be defined implicitly from the

equations Q1 = 2Q/3 and Q2 = Q/3• More generally: assume that the two products are

produced in the ratio 1/2 (with 1 + 2 = 1).• Then total output is defined implicitly from the equations

Q1 = 1Q and Q2 = 2Q• Ray average cost is then defined as:

RAC(Q) =C(1Q, 2Q)

Q

Page 24: 1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

24

An example of ray average costs

• Marginal costs for each product are:

C(Q1, Q2) = 10 + 25Q1 + 30Q2 - 3Q1Q2/2• Assume that the cost function is:

MC1 =C(Q1,Q2)

Q1

= 25 -3Q2

2

MC2 =C(Q1,Q2)

Q2

= 30 -3Q1

2

Page 25: 1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

25

• Ray average costs: assume 1 = 2 = 0.5

C(Q1, Q2) = 10 + 25Q1 + 30Q2 - 3Q1Q2/2

Q1 = 0.5Q; Q2 = 0.5Q

RAC(Q) =C(0.5Q, 0.5Q)

Q

=10 + 25Q/2+ 30Q/2 - 3Q2/8

Q=

10

Q+

55

2-

3Q

8

Now assume 1 = 0.75; 2 = 0.25

RAC(Q) =C(0.75Q, 0.25Q)

Q

=10 + 75Q/4+ 30Q/4 - 9Q2/32

Q=

10

Q+

105

4-

9Q

32

Page 26: 1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

26

Economies of scale and multiple products

• Definition of economies of scale with a single product

S =AC(Q)

MC(Q)=

C(Q)

Q.MC(Q)

• Definition of economies of scale with multiple products

S =C(Q1,Q2,…,Qn)

MC1Q1 + MC2Q2 + … + MCnQn

• This is by analogy to the single product case– relies on the implicit assumption that output proportions are fixed– so we are looking at ray average costs in using this definition

Page 27: 1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

27

The example once againC(Q1, Q2) = 10 + 25Q1 + 30Q2 - 3Q1Q2/2

MC1 = 25 - 3Q2/2 ; MC2 = 30 - 3Q1/2

Substitute into the definition of S:

S =C(Q1,Q2,…,Qn)

MC1Q1 + MC2Q2 + … + MCnQn

=10 + 25Q1 + 30Q2 - 3Q1Q2/2

25Q1 - 3Q1Q2/2 + 30Q2 - 3Q1Q2/2

It should be obvious in this case that S > 1

This cost function exhibits global economies of scale

Page 28: 1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

28

Economies of Scope• Formal definition

SC =C(Q1, 0) + C(0 ,Q2) - C(Q1, Q2)

C(Q1, Q2)

• The critical value in this case is SC = 0

– SC < 0 : no economies of scope; SC > 0 : economies of scope.

• Take the example:

SC =10 + 25Q1 + 10 + 30Q2 - (10 + 25Q1 + 30Q2 - 3Q1Q2/2)

10 + 25Q1 + 30Q2 - 3Q1Q2/2 > 0

Page 29: 1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

29

• Sources of economies of scope• shared inputs

– same equipment for various products

– shared advertising creating a brand name

– marketing and R&D expenditures that are generic

• cost complementarities– producing one good reduces the cost of producing another

– oil and natural gas

– oil and benzene

– computer software and computer support

– retailing and product promotion

Economies of Scope (cont.)

Page 30: 1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

30

Flexible Manufacturing

• Extreme version of economies of scope• Changing the face of manufacturing• “Production units capable of producing a range of

discrete products with a minimum of manual intervention”– Benetton– Custom Shoe– Levi’s– Mitsubishi

• Production units can be switched easily with little if any cost penalty– requires close contact between design and manufacturing

Page 31: 1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

31

Flexible Manufacturing (cont.)• Take a simple model based on a spatial analogue.

– There is some characteristic that distinguishes different varieties of a product• sweetness or sugar content• color• texture

– This can be measured and represented as a line– Individual products can be located on this line in

terms of the quantity of the characteristic that they possess

– One product is chosen by the firm as its base product– All other products are variants on the base product

Page 32: 1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

32

Flexible Manufacturing (cont.)

• An illustration: soft drinks that vary in sugar content

0 10.5

This is the characteristics

line

Each product is locatedon the line in termsof the amount of thecharacteristic it has

Low High

(Diet) (LX) (Super)

Page 33: 1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

33

The example (cont.)

• Assume that the process is centered on LX as base product.

0 10.5Low High

(Diet) (LX) (Super)

A switching cost s is incurred in changing the process to either of the other products.

There are additional marginal costs of making Diet or Super - from adding or removing sugar. These are r per unit of “distance” between LX and the other product.

There are shared costs F: design, packaging, equipment.

Page 34: 1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

34

The example (cont.)

• In the absence of shared costs there would be specialized firms.

• Shared costs introduce economies of scope.

Total costs are: C(zj, qj) = F + (m - 1)s + j=1

m[(c + rzj - z1)qj]

If production is 100 units of each product:

C3 = 3F + 300cone product per firm with three firms

one firm with all three products C1 = F + 2s + 300c + 100r

C1 < C3 if 2s + 100r < 2F F > 50r + s

This implies a constraint on set-up costs, switching costs and marginal costs for multi-product production to be preferred.

Page 35: 1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

35

Economies of scale and scope

• Economies of scale and scope affect market structure but cannot be looked at in isolation.

• They must be considered relative to market size.

• Should see concentration decline as market size increases

• For example, entry to the medical profession is going to be more extensive in Chicago than in Oxford, Miss

Page 36: 1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

36

Network Externalities

• Market structure is also affected by the presence of network externalities– willingness to pay by a consumer increases as the

number of current consumers increase• telephones, fax, Internet, Windows software• utility from consumption increases when there are more

current consumers

• These markets are likely to contain a small number of firms– even if there are limited economies of scale and scope

Page 37: 1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

37

The Role of Policy

• Government can directly affect market structure– by limiting entry

• taxi medallions in Boston and New York

• airline regulation

– through the patent system– by protecting competition e.g. through the

Robinson-Patman Act

Page 38: 1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

38

Market Performance• Market structure is often a guide to market

performance• But this is not a perfect measure

– can have near competitive prices even with “few” firms

• Measure market performance using the Lerner Index

LI =P-MC

P

Page 39: 1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

39

Market Performance (cont.)• Perfect competition: LI = 0 since P = MC• Monopoly: LI = 1/– inverse of elasticity of

demand• With more than one but not “many” firms, the

Lerner Index is more complicated: need to average.– suppose the goods are homogeneous so all firms

sell at the same price

LI =P-siMCi

P

Page 40: 1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

40

$/unit

Quantity

AC1

Assume two identical firms each with costs AC1

If they are to produce a given output at lowest cost, they must operate at the same marginal

costMC Why? Assume firm A is operating at MCA and firm B is operating at MCBMCA

MCB

Transferring one unit of output from A to B lowers total costMC´A

MC´B

If the two firms operate at the same marginal cost they must produce identical

outputs

Suppose not: firm A has output QA and firm B has output QB

Transferring one unit of output from A to B lowers total cost

QAQB

Page 41: 1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

41

$/unit

Quantity

AC1 AC2

It follows that AC2 represents the lowest possible average cost if output is produced by two firms: AC2 is

obtained by adding AC1 to itself horizontally

This market is a natural

monopoly up to output QM even though this is greater than

MES Q*: it is less costly for output to be produced by

one rather than two firms:

subadditivity

Q* 2Q*QM

AC1 is average cost ifoutput is produced by

one firm.

Now assume thatoutput is produced by

two firms.If total output is 2Q1 thenwe know that each firm has to produce Q1 and average

cost is AC1

If total output is 2Q1 thenwe know that each firm has to produce Q1 and average

cost is AC1

AC1

2Q1Q1

2Q2Q2

If total output is 2Q2 thenwe know that each firm has to produce Q2 and average

cost is AC2

If total output is 2Q2 thenwe know that each firm has to produce Q2 and average

cost is AC2

If total output is 2Q* thenwe know that each firm has to produce Q* and average

cost is AC*

If total output is 2Q* thenwe know that each firm has to produce Q* and average

cost is AC*AC2

AC*

Page 42: 1 Chapter 2 Technology, Costs and Market Structure

42

0 4 8

12 16 20

0

8

16

0100200

300

400

500

600

700

800

Total Cost

Output 1

Output 2

Illustration of ray average costs