081 Housing New Zealand - Capacity and Feasibility Modelling _ MBIE - (David Hermans) _ Post Hearing Response

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/19/2019 081 Housing New Zealand - Capacity and Feasibility Modelling _ MBIE - (David Hermans) _ Post Hearing Response

    1/15

    1

    BEFORE THE AUCKLAND UNITARY PLAN INDEPENDENT HEARINGS PANEL

    IN THE MATTER of the Resource Management Act 1991 and the

    Local Government (Auckland Transitional

    Provisions) Act 2010

    AND

    IN THE MATTER of Proposed Auckland Unitary Plan Topic 081  – 

    Rezoning and Precincts (Geographic Areas)

    STATEMENT OF EVIDENCE OF THE MINISTRY OF BUSINESS, INNOVATION ANDEMPLOYMENT (SUBMITTER NO. 6319)

    15 MARCH 2016

    Contact:

    David Hermans

    Principal Advisor, Auckland Housing

    Construction and Housing Markets

    Ministry of Business, Innovation and Employment

    [email protected] 09 919 9323

    mailto:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]

  • 8/19/2019 081 Housing New Zealand - Capacity and Feasibility Modelling _ MBIE - (David Hermans) _ Post Hearing Response

    2/15

    2

    1. SUMMARY

    1.1. This statement of evidence from the Ministry of Business, Innovation and

    Employment (MBIE) addresses the matters being considered under Topic 081 -

    Rezoning and Precincts (Geographical Areas). It has a specific focus on the outputs

    of the residential development capacity modelling undertaken by the Topic 013Urban Growth Expert Conferencing Group (The 013 Group).

    1.2. We have reviewed the reports of the 013 Group, and the related evidence provided

    by Kyle Balderston and Doug Fairgray for the Auckland Council, Philip Osborne and

    Tim Heath for HNZC, and Adam Thompson, Director of Urban Economics Ltd and

    member of the 013 Group.

    1.3. We are comfortable that the 013 Group’s ACDCv3.7 model results are sufficiently

    robust to provide enough information to form a broad view on the development

    capacity provided through the PAUP, and how it can be enhanced through

    reconsidering the spatial application of zones.

    1.4. We have concerns about what the model results reveal, and these fall into three

    categories:

      The overall quantum of capacity : We consider that feasible development

    capacity provided by the PAUP for approximately 240,000 dwellings in existing

    urban areas is insufficient to ensure Auckland has a competitive well-functioning

    housing market and a competitive urban land market over the longer-term. A

    market that has confidence in the sufficiency of future capacity and supply is

    less likely to result in speculative activity, and will encourage development to

    occur sooner rather than waiting for values to keep appreciating.

      The spatial distribution of capacity : With the exception of the city centre and

    some other centres, the feasible development capacity is mostly provided in

    areas where land prices reveal lower relative housing demand, or which have

    lower levels of employment accessibility. Because of this, we do not consider

    that the PAUP currently provides a suitable spatial distribution of residential

    capacity to best support either a well-functioning housing market or an

    effectively-functioning urban economy in Auckland.

      The distribution and mix of typologies, sizes and prices:  The PAUP only

    provides for 20% of feasible development capacity through attached housing

    typologies, even though developers are currently building attached dwellings at

    more than twice that proportion; a proportion that is projected to be maintained

    over the longer term. These are the typologies more likely to result in smaller,

    more affordable dwellings. The low capacity for medium-density typologies (an

    under-represented typology in Auckland) is particularly concerning. Therefore

    we consider the PAUP does not provide sufficient housing choices to deliver a

    well-functioning housing market in Auckland. 

    1.5. Our analysis and views reveal that the PAUP as notified, even with the welcome

    changes to residential provisions proposed by the Council in previous evidence,does not give us comfort that the PAUP will enable a well-functioning housing

  • 8/19/2019 081 Housing New Zealand - Capacity and Feasibility Modelling _ MBIE - (David Hermans) _ Post Hearing Response

    3/15

    3

    market — and by extension, an effective-functioning urban economy. We consider

    this position lends weight to the need for further ‘up-zoning’ of geographic areas in

     Auckland for more density.

    2. INTRODUCTION

    2.1. MBIE develops and delivers policy, services, advice and regulation to support

    business growth and the prosperity and wellbeing of all New Zealanders. Housing

    policy — and in particular, housing supply and affordability in Auckland — is a core

    focus of MBIE and of the Government more generally. MBIE is working alongside

    other government agencies, local government, the private sector, and non-

    government organisations to enhance affordability, social housing and the quality of

    the built environment.

    2.2. A well-functioning housing market is important for both economic performance and

    social wellbeing. High housing costs increase social inequality, reduce labour

    mobility, divert investment from more productive economic activities, represent astability risk to the macro-economy, and — through the accommodation supplement

    and income-related rent subsidies — have a direct fiscal impact.

    2.3. While MBIE broadly has an interest in many aspects of the PAUP, housing is the

    central focus of MBIE’s submission and evidence. This reflects the importance that

    MBIE and the Government currently place on achieving housing policy outcomes,

    and also reflects the nationally important role the Auckland Unitary Plan will play in

    delivering housing outcomes.

    2.4. MBIE’s interest in Auckland housing  outcomes also reflects the important link

    between a well-functioning housing market and the performance of Auckland’seconomy more generally. MBIE’s three key objectives are: more competitive

    businesses; job opportunities for all; and affordable housing. Constraints on housing

    supply and on housing choices can reduce employment accessibility, firm

    productivity and performance (by constraining access to a larger labour pool), and

    ultimately living standards. Auckland’s importance in the national economy (36.6%

    of GDP in year-ended March 2015) therefore makes the performance of the city a

    matter of national importance.

    3. SCOPE

    3.1. This statement of evidence addresses the matters being considered under Topic

    081 - Rezoning and Precincts (Geographical Areas), namely the spatial application

    of residential zones within the Auckland Unitary Plan, but with specific focus on the

    outputs of the residential development capacity modelling undertaken by the Topic

    013 Urban Growth Expert Conferencing Group (The 013 Group).

    3.2. It builds on the primary submission that MBIE provided in February 2014, and on

    the subsequent statements of evidence provided in December 2014 for Topic 013

    (RPS Urban Growth), in September 2015 for Topics 059-063 (Residential objectives

    policies and controls), and in February 2016 for Topic 080 (Rezoning and Precincts

     – General). We revisit some key points from that evidence in this document wherepertinent.

  • 8/19/2019 081 Housing New Zealand - Capacity and Feasibility Modelling _ MBIE - (David Hermans) _ Post Hearing Response

    4/15

    4

    3.3. MBIE’s submission, this statement of evidence, and our participation in the

     Auckland Unitary Plan hearings process have been informed by the whole-of-

    Government submission from the Minister for the Environment (No. 318, dated 17

    December 2013). Where possible, we have also sought consistency with other

    government submitters, particularly Housing New Zealand Corporation (HNZC).

    3.4. In preparing this statement of evidence we have specifically reviewed the reports of

    the 013 Group, statements of evidence provided by Kyle Balderston and Doug

    Fairgray for the Auckland Council, Philip Osborne and Tim Heath for HNZC, and

     Adam Thompson, Director of Urban Economics Ltd and member of the 013 Group.

    4. OVERVIEW OF PRIMARY SUBMISSION AND PREVIOUS EVIDENCE

    4.1. In our primary submission from February 2014 we argued that the PAUP does not

    back up its creditable RPS-level objectives with appropriately aligned policies and

    rules at the ‘district plan’ level. In particular, the PAUP:

    4.1.1. Does not provide sufficient capacity through appropriate zoning and density

    provisions to meet Auckland’s forecast growth, particularly in locations of

    highest demand; and,

    4.1.2. Fails to free residential development from complicated policies and rules that

    will create high transaction costs, thereby limiting innovation and

    responsiveness of supply to demand.

    4.2. We argued that in doing so the PAUP does not provide for the population growth

    and changing household demographics and preferences that Auckland will face

    over the next thirty years.

    4.3. We noted that there was a deliberate ‘down-zoning’ apparent between the

    provisions and zones contained in the Draft Unitary Plan (released by the Auckland

    Council for public consultation in March 2013) and the version notified in September

    that same year. This widened the misalignment between the strategy and the

    detailed provisions. It also exacerbated the misalignment between the areas where

    demand for housing is highest (as expressed through land prices) and the areas

    where the PAUP provided for growth. In addition, we noted that an ostensible

    ‘design-focused’ approach to consenting medium-density residential development

    was instead encumbered by inflexible rules, overlays and controls that would limit

    housing supply and housing choices.

    4.4. We sought that — where necessary to achieve alignment with the objectives of the

     Auckland Plan and RPS sections of the PAUP — the zoning, overlays, development

    controls and other provisions in the PAUP should be adjusted and amended such

    that they do not constrain provision of sufficient residential development to meet

     Auckland’s growth projections, and to proactively enable efficient growth in areas of

    high market demand.

    4.5. In our evidence for Topic 013 we re-stated our qualified support for the RPS-level

    urban growth policies and objectives. We noted that notwithstanding the need for

    sufficient peripheral greenfield capacity to increase housing supply and meet

  • 8/19/2019 081 Housing New Zealand - Capacity and Feasibility Modelling _ MBIE - (David Hermans) _ Post Hearing Response

    5/15

    5

    demand in certain sub-markets, managing towards an intensified urban form is

    consistent with urban economic theory, with global patterns of urbanisation, greater

    centralisation of employment in the growing service sector, and with the social and

    economic choices and trade-offs that households make in a growing city. That is,

    intensification is an efficient market response to rising land prices in areas of high

    demand. We stated that the locations experiencing the highest land values, and byimplication the highest levels of demand, should be considered primary locations for

    intensification, and therefore should be supported by plan provisions and zoning

    that reduce development constraints.

    4.6. In our evidence for Topics 059-063 we stated our support for the Auckland Council

    evidence that sought changes to the PAUP to uplift development capacity across

    the residential zones. In particular, we supported the Auckland Council’s proposed

    amendments that sought to enable a significant increase in housing capacity in

     Auckland by:

    4.6.1. Removing restrictions on density and height within areas identified as

    appropriate for intensification;

    4.6.2. Clarifying and narrowing the purpose and application of the Single House

    zone (SHZ); and

    4.6.3. Rationalising development controls and assessment criteria to provide more

    flexibility to developers while still achieving built character, quality living

    environments and residential amenity objectives.

    4.7. In that evidence, we also stated that despite the ostensible uplift in total feasible

    development capacity generated by the Council’s proposed changes to residentialprovisions, we remained concerned that the modelled feasible capacity still does

    not provide enough opportunities for attached, medium-density housing typologies

    to meet underlying and projected demand. We stated that while we supported the

    Council’s proposed changes to residential provisions, we considered more still

    needed to be done, and that the main way in which capacity will be further improved

    is through adjustments to the spatial application of zones.

    4.8. In a statement provided for Topic 080, in support of HNZC’s evidence, we re-

    iterated the Government’s interest in ensuring the Unitary Plan delivers sufficient

    market-feasible residential development capacity in Auckland. We also stated that,despite the number of new homes consented in Auckland (9,200 in the 12 months

    to December 2015) being already above the long-term average, and characteristic

    of a residential construction boom, it is still not nearly enough to meet the new

    household formation resulting from current and projected population growth. To

    meet this ongoing demand, the Unitary Plan needs to provide for much greater

    levels of both intensification and greenfield expansion than has historically been the

    case under legacy plans. We also stated that the feasible capacity provided by the

    Unitary Plan needs to be much greater than underlying demand, given not all

    opportunities will be taken up.

    4.9. The following evidence provides more detail about MBIE’s views on the final point above in the context of the 013 Group development capacity modelling exercise. 

  • 8/19/2019 081 Housing New Zealand - Capacity and Feasibility Modelling _ MBIE - (David Hermans) _ Post Hearing Response

    6/15

    6

    5. DISCUSSION OF DEVELOPMENT CAPACITY MODELLING OUTPUTS

    5.1. MBIE, alongside the Ministry for the Environment, acted in an observer capacity

    during the 013 Group’s development of the  Auckland Council Development

    Capacity 2015 (ACDC15) model and analysis. We are grateful to the Panel for this

    opportunity.

    5.2. We consider the ACDC15 model provides a good basis for making a broad

     judgement about plan effectiveness, and for estimating the general effects of further

    changes to provisions or changes to the spatial application of zones.

    5.3. We have reviewed the reports of the 013 Group, and the related evidence provided

    by Kyle Balderston and Dr JDM Fairgray for the Auckland Council, Philip Osborne

    and Tim Heath for HNZC, and Adam Thompson, Director of Urban Economics Ltd

    and member of the 013 Group.

    5.4. We note that in his evidence Mr Thompson raises concerns about the recent modelruns, in that they have been undertaken by the Council without the full participation

    or peer review of some members of the 013 Group. MBIE has not formed a detailed

    view on the specific methodological concerns raised by Mr Thompson.

    Nevertheless, our confidence in the model results would be strengthened by the

    knowledge that all 013 Group members, and particularly those with property

    development and economic expertise, are comfortable with the methodology

    applied in each application of the model.

    5.5. Despite this, we are comfortable that the model results are sufficiently robust to

    provide us with enough information to form a broad view on the development

    capacity provided through the PAUP, and how it can be enhanced through thespatial application of zones.

    5.6. As with our previous evidence, we consider that the modelling outputs should be

    used with appropriate qualification. As the reports of the 013 Group state, the model

    is a static analysis, with no feedback mechanisms. It does not factor in matters such

    as ‘development chance’ and sub-optimal development occurring on sites (which

    could reduce capacity), and the opportunities that can arise from land aggregation

    and increased land values (which could increase feasible capacity). Mr Balderston’s

    most recent evidence further clarifies the limitations of the model results: he

    describes it as providing a starting point for making forecasts, but it does notconstitute a forecast in itself.

    5.7. We consider it is useful to use the model outputs to understand the relative change

    in market-feasible capacity afforded by changes to planning provisions and zoning,

    and also to assess whether the overall modelled capacity is of sufficient quantity

    and quality   to more likely result in a well-functioning housing market and urban

    economy. This suggests we should not place the emphasis on determining whether

    there is an absolute match between plan-enabled feasible development capacity

    and specific medium- or long-term demand projections and/or supply targets.

    5.8. The latest version of the ACDC15 model (ACDC15v3.7) is described in theevidence of Mr Balderston and Dr Fairgray. It shows that the PAUP —  with the

  • 8/19/2019 081 Housing New Zealand - Capacity and Feasibility Modelling _ MBIE - (David Hermans) _ Post Hearing Response

    7/15

    7

    modifications to residential zone controls proposed by Council in its 059-063

    evidence —  enables a commercially feasible development capacity of between

    223,802 and 307,817 dwellings, depending on the scenario chosen (e.g. highest

    return, lowest price, most dwellings).

    5.9. We agree with the evidence of Mr Osborne and Mr Heath for HNZC that the filter for‘highest return’ represents the most likely market response to development

    opportunities afforded by the PAUP. The ‘highest return’ scenario provides a

    capacity of 239,682 dwellings, comprising (as outlined in the evidence of Dr

    Fairgray) 30,533 apartments, 19,322 terraces or attached townhouses, and 189,827

    standalone houses. References from here on in this paper to the ACDCv3.7 model

    results are usually a reference to the ‘highest return’ scenario results.

    5.10. Mr Balderston’s  evidence also provides a spatial rendering of the results by

    typology, including useful ‘heat maps’ that demonstrate the relative increase in

    development capacity that the PAUP provides over existing densities. We have

    found that the presentation that Mr Balderston and Dr Fairgray gave the Panel on 4

    March 2016 also contains particularly useful information.

    5.11. We recognise that the feasible development capacity described by ACDCv3.7 is a

    significant improvement on the 64,000 commercially-feasible dwellings that the

    original ACDC results indicated were available to the market. However, despite this

    improvement, all of our original concerns remain as to what the modelling results

    actually tell us. We note that some of these concerns appear to be similarly

    reflected in the evidence provided by Mr Balderston and Dr Fairgray.

    5.12. Our concerns about the model results fall into three categories:

      The overall quantum of capacity

      The spatial distribution of capacity

      The distribution and mix of typologies, sizes and prices

    The overall quantum of capacity

    5.13. In our statement of evidence for Topic 080 we noted that, despite Auckland

    currently consenting dwellings at above the long-term average, demand continues

    to exceed supply. Our estimate is that the accumulated shortfall of dwellings (in thesense of a latent demand for households that might have otherwise formed had

    sufficient housing been available) is likely to climb to over 30,000 by June 2016.

    5.14. Statistics New Zealand projects that  Auckland’s population will grow by a further

    939,600 people by 2043 based on its high-growth scenario, and will have an

    average household size of 2.7 persons. Combined with our estimated housing

    shortfall, this suggests that the rough Auckland Plan estimate of 400,000 additional

    dwellings being required over 30 years —  or approximately 13,000 per year — 

    remains an appropriate yardstick. The Statistics New Zealand medium household

    growth projection (736,100 additional people) may be the most likely scenario to

    occur. In the context of zoning decisions, we consider there is little cost or risk to

    erring on the side of over-capacity, particularly as it can help reduce land

  • 8/19/2019 081 Housing New Zealand - Capacity and Feasibility Modelling _ MBIE - (David Hermans) _ Post Hearing Response

    8/15

    8

    speculation by reducing perceptions of artificial scarcity. We also note that at the

    moment Auckland’s population is growing at a rate greater than the Statistics New

    Zealand high projection, with 43,500 people added in the year to June 2015.

    5.15. The ACDC15 model focuses on the existing urban area, within which the Auckland

    Plan and PAUP RPS-level growth strategy suggests 60-70% of Auckland’s dwellinggrowth will, or should, occur. This suggests a required capacity of 240,000 to

    280,000 dwellings in this area, with approximately 120,000 to 160,000 dwellings

    occurring in new greenfield areas and satellite towns. We note that despite this

    being the agreed urban growth strategy, the ‘70:40’ strategy is broadly consistent

    with what urban economics tells us that a relatively unconstrained urban land and

    housing market might otherwise deliver.

    5.16. We note that the evidence of Dr Fairgray tends to focus on supply and demand

    dynamics over the next ten years, out to 2026, rather than the 30-year horizon of

    the Auckland Plan and PAUP RPS. We concur that projecting supply and demand

    accurately beyond 10 years is difficult, given the uncertainties around market

    conditions, land prices, and the nature of demand. The following graph illustrates

    the nature of the problem, where the red-dashed line represents projected demand

    for housing (based on the medium-growth) scenario and the bars represent known

    Crown-led and private-led residential developments. You can see that the growth in

    known development plans rapidly falls away after about 5 years, leaving the

    shortfall to be plugged by developments not yet known or imagined:

    5.17. It is true that as land prices increase, and as public investment in transport

    infrastructure and other amenity-enhancing investments bear fruit, then more areas

    will become sufficiently market-attractive over time to increase the feasibility of

    development. It is also true that as the Unitary Plan is reviewed after (or within) the

    statutory 10-year period required by the Resource Management Act, then additional

    areas can be zoned for higher densities and yield. Nevertheless, for the purpose of

    assessing the sufficiency of development capacity provided by the Auckland Unitary

    Plan, we prefer the larger demand projection provided by the longer 30-yeartimeframe. This is for the following related reasons:

  • 8/19/2019 081 Housing New Zealand - Capacity and Feasibility Modelling _ MBIE - (David Hermans) _ Post Hearing Response

    9/15

    9

    5.17.1. We consider a well-functioning housing market requires a large number of

    potential development opportunities to be available, so that developers and

    prospective homeowners have a wide variety of choices, and so that

    downward competitive pressure is applied to land prices across the city. If

    the market has confidence in the sufficiency of future development

    capacity and supply over the long term, then this would help reducespeculation-driven price increases, as well as encouraging landowners to

    develop their land sooner rather than hold out for higher prices later (i.e.

    land-bank). We note that 240,000 dwellings is approximately equal to, or

    slightly less than, the 30-year demand projection, and only about 200% of

    the 10-year demand. Notwithstanding the additional opportunities that may

    arise over time, this would require every currently-feasible development

    opportunity to be taken up within 30 years to the maximum feasible

    capacity of each site, or for every other opportunity to be taken up over a

    10-year period.

    5.17.2. In addition, given ‘development chance’ — that is, the observation that the

    owners of feasible sites may not wish to realise the development potential,

    or may wish to develop to a sub-optimal density for lifestyle reasons — 

    then the feasible capacity in existing urban areas needs to be significantly

    more than projected demand in order to ensure enough redevelopment

    opportunities are realised. Focusing on the longer-term demand

    projections as the benchmark provides a larger figure to aim towards.

    5.17.3. Perhaps more importantly, we consider that focusing only on the capacity

    required over ten years risks foregoing future redevelopment opportunities,

    by locking in sub-optimal housing typologies and sizes which will not besubsequently redeveloped within the 30-year horizon of the Unitary Plan.

    For example, we consider there will be scenarios where a market-attractive

    area has a constrained zoning, but where the economics could feasibly

    support development at higher densities (say, medium-density apartment

    typologies). The low-density development may still be considered feasible,

    and there may still be sufficient demand for some  wealthy households to

    purchase the resulting expensive, large houses. If the area has a less

    constraining zoning, the higher-density option that yields a greater number

    of dwellings may provide the higher development return. However, the

    zoning precludes this option, and pushes developers towards the sub-optimal outcome. Re-zoning the area in 10 years’ time could be a fruitless

    exercise given the lower-density development that occurred in the interim

    will have many more decades of economic life before it is suitable for

    redevelopment once more. This dynamic, experienced across enough

    areas, could exclude a large number of current and future redevelopment

    opportunities if the Unitary Plan is too conservative in its residential zoning.

    It distorts investment incentives, affects productivity on that investment and

    carries real economic cost.

    5.17.4. We also note the importance of having more than 10 years’ worth of

    dwelling capacity in a plan even with a 10-year life span. Even if the PAUP

    had sufficient capacity for 10-years’ worth of household growth, by the

  • 8/19/2019 081 Housing New Zealand - Capacity and Feasibility Modelling _ MBIE - (David Hermans) _ Post Hearing Response

    10/15

    10

    ninth year of its life there might only be one year’s worth of that capacity

    left. The market may anticipate the shortages in capacity and supply that

    could occur through such an approach, and reflect this through unhelpful

    land-banking and higher house prices. In this regard, we note that the

     Auckland Plan calls for the Unitary Plan to have 20 years’ “forward view” of

    housing supply.

    5.18. Given the above discussion, we consider that the feasible capacity for

    approximately 240,000 dwellings provided by the PAUP, according to the

     ACDCv3.7 outputs, is insufficient to ensure Auckland has a well-functioning housing

    market and a competitive urban land market over the longer-term.

    The spatial distr ibut io n of capacity

    5.19. As we have noted in previous evidence, increased prices are both a signal to use a

    resource more efficiently (in the example of land values) and to produce more of a

    good or service (in the example of houses). In urban areas, these dynamics playout in tandem — increased land values and house prices will lead to intensification

    of the land-use, by increasing the ratio of dwellings to land area. Land values are a

    clear indicator of the demand for that land, and thus the urban locations with the

    highest land values are usually by implication the areas with the highest levels of

    housing demand.1 

    5.20. The high demand is usually explained by proximity to and/or accessibility to

    employment opportunities, urban and natural amenities, and transport links. In an

     Auckland context, this is easily revealed through land-value maps which show the

    highest land values in the central isthmus and coastal areas:

     Auckland land value ‘heat map’ (source: Auckland Council GIS) 

    1  We note that whether that underlying demand is being met or not could be determined by examining

    improvement values. You would expect that high value land would be used more intensively (by way of greater

    improvements to land) and provide the highest economic returns. The ratio of improvements value to land

    value, therefore, can signal the areas with the highest levels of unmet housing demand. High value land areas

    with relatively low improvements value to land value ratios might indicate that land supply is particularlyconstricted in those areas. We haven’t had time to undertake this analysis for this evidence.

  • 8/19/2019 081 Housing New Zealand - Capacity and Feasibility Modelling _ MBIE - (David Hermans) _ Post Hearing Response

    11/15

    11

    5.21. These high-value areas are therefore the primary locations for intensification, and

    should be supported by commensurate plan provisions in order to support an

    efficient and well-functioning housing market. In contrast, intensification is less likely

    to be viable where land is cheaper, even if planning provisions enable it to occur. Mr

    Balderston notes this in his evidence, where he states “denser developments are

    able to moderate the cost of new floorspace on expensive land (compared to lessdense developments) but are more expensive on lower value land”.

    5.22. From MBIE’s perspective, reducing the rules that constrain residential intensification

    in these more in-demand areas is desirable not just from a narrow housing market

    perspective; it also speaks to our interests in the efficient and productive functioning

    of the Auckland economy, and the opportunities that brings for all its current and

    future residents, and for New Zealand.

    5.23. Auckland benefits from the advantages that cities bring in terms of scale, diversity

    and specialisation. Because of its size, and because of agglomeration economics

    that work in its favour, Auckland is on average more productive than the rest of New

    Zealand. Its economic performance will be increasingly important for New Zealand’s

    future wellbeing. But Auckland’s success and advantages rest on the ability for its

    firms and people to connect easily with one another in the region: for firms to be

    able to maximise the number of skilled workers they have access to, and for people

    to be able to maximise the number of employment opportunities, and opportunities

    for specialisation, that they have access to. Accessibility, therefore, is a key

    component of city performance, and economic and social wellbeing.

    5.24. The Auckland Transport Alignment Project (ATAP) is an ongoing collaboration

    between central government and the Auckland Council. The ATAP FoundationReport was released in February 2016, and amongst other things revealed that

    access to employment in Auckland varies significantly by location and declines

    comparatively rapidly beyond the central area. It notes that “by 2046 more than a

    million people will be living in the western and southern parts of Auckland, nearly

    half the region’s population. However, these areas see relatively little improvement

    in their access to employment over time, particularly by private vehicle. The wider

    implications of these areas being at least partly excluded from the benefits of

     Auckland’s expanding employment base over the next 30 years are potentially

    significant, particularly given they include parts of Auckland with higher levels of

    deprivation, as well as a number ofkey future urban growth areas.”

     

    5.25. This reveals a transport investment challenge for central and local government,

    which ATAP is focused on solving, but it also reveals important information about

    the preferred locations for residential growth from an employment-accessibility

    perspective. In contrast to areas in the South and West, the report notes that

    “access to employment by both car and public transport for those living in the

    central (isthmus) part of Auckland appears to improve throughout the next 30 years,

    reflecting the general growth in employment as well as its projected centralisation”.

    5.26. This finding contrasts with the spatial rendering of the ACDC15v3.7 results and the

    accompanying ‘heat maps’ provided by Mr Balderston. In Mr Balderston’s own

  • 8/19/2019 081 Housing New Zealand - Capacity and Feasibility Modelling _ MBIE - (David Hermans) _ Post Hearing Response

    12/15

    12

    words, they show that the development capacity constraints in the PAUP resemble

    a “donut with a candle in the middle”: 

    Extracted from the Evidence of Kyle Balderston for Auckland Council

    5.27. The results reveal there is feasible capacity provided for standalone dwellings in a

    large number of more peripheral suburban areas, particularly in the southern and

    western parts of Auckland, and there is much feasible capacity for higher-density

    apartments in the central city area and in Takapuna and some other centres and

    corridors. However, there is very little feasible capacity in most of the more central

    isthmus locations that, from the land-value and employment accessibility

    perspective outlined above, are the most desirable areas to be focusing

    development opportunities. This reveals that large parts of the central area have a

    constraining single-house zoning as well as restrictive heritage and other overlays

    under the PAUP.

    5.28. With the exception of the city centre and some other centres such as Takapuna, the

     ACDCv3.7 modelling reveals that development capacity is mostly provided in areas

    where land prices reveal lower relative housing demand, or which have lower levels

    of employment accessibility. Because of this, we do not consider that the PAUP

    currently provides a suitable spatial distribution of residential capacity to support

    either a well-functioning housing market or an effectively-functioning urban

    economy in Auckland.

  • 8/19/2019 081 Housing New Zealand - Capacity and Feasibility Modelling _ MBIE - (David Hermans) _ Post Hearing Response

    13/15

    13

    The distr ibut ion and m ix of typolo gies, sizes and p rices

    5.29. The ACDC15v3.7 modelling reveals that the PAUP provides a lot of feasible

    capacity for standalone houses in many suburbs (80% of feasible capacity), a lot of

    capacity for apartments in the city centre and some other centres (12%), but very

    little in the way of capacity for terraced housing and other attached, medium-densitytypologies (8%):

    5.30. We do not consider this is an accurate reflection of the mix of current or anticipated

    demand for these typologies. Nor does it reflect the Auckland Plan growth strategy,

    which expects that around 60% of all new dwellings will be attached if the Council

    achieves its strategic aim for 70% of new dwellings to be supplied in existing urban

    areas. In that scenario, the Auckland Plan calls for an average of over 8,000

    attached dwellings per year over 30 years.

    5.31. In our evidence for Topics 059-063 we highlighted the third National Construction

    Pipeline Report, produced for MBIE in July 2015 by BRANZ. This forecasts 94,000

    new dwelling consents in Auckland between January 2013 and December 2020

    (about 13,000 a year), but importantly it projects the number of multi units (attached

    typologies such as terraces and apartments) to grow to over 6,000 a year, to be

    almost the same number as attached dwellings in 2020:

  • 8/19/2019 081 Housing New Zealand - Capacity and Feasibility Modelling _ MBIE - (David Hermans) _ Post Hearing Response

    14/15

    14

    Number of consents for detached and multi-unit dwellings in Auckland

    5.32. In our previous evidence we also showed that the rate of building consents for

    attached dwellings in Auckland has grown rapidly since 2013, and was about 3,000

    in 2015 — as seen in the building consent data from Statistics New Zealand below:

    5.33. Since highlighting that data we can confirm that this upward trend is continuing, and

    in the three months between October and December 2015 1,281 dwellings in multi-

    unit buildings accounted for 47% of all new dwellings consented in Auckland.

    5.34. In contrast to the above figures, the ACDCv3.7 modelling reveals that the PAUP

    only provides for 20% of current feasible capacity through attached typologies, even

    when developers are currently building attached dwellings at more than twice that

    proportion (utilising legacy plans and special housing areas), a proportion that is

    projected to be maintained over the longer term.

  • 8/19/2019 081 Housing New Zealand - Capacity and Feasibility Modelling _ MBIE - (David Hermans) _ Post Hearing Response

    15/15

    15

    5.35. The Housing We’d Choose Study   undertaken for the Auckland Council in 2015

    confirms what has been observable across Auckland for some time: that people are

    willing to trade off house size for location, affordability and quality, and that there is

    an under-supply of quality medium- and higher density housing in most Auckland

    suburbs. Although it’s true that buyers show a preference for larger homes (and

    large sections) wherever possible, that preference is still constrained by what theycan afford.

    5.36. These typologies are more likely than standalone houses to be smaller and more

    affordable, given that land price makes up a lower portion of the overall house price,

    something that can hold true even when the house is located in a more desirable,

    higher-value area. They are also a typology that are in increasing demand from

    renters and investors, first-home buyers, and elderly households wishing to down-

    size but remain in their familiar neighbourhoods. The low capacity for medium-

    density typologies (an under-represented typology in Auckland) is particularly

    concerning. This is the typology that best suits the more central suburbs outside thecity centre.

    5.37. Certainly, when looking historically, the fact that new homes were smaller and a

    much greater proportion were priced below the median value of existing stock

    suggests that the residential construction market once supplied significant demand

    from first home buyers and less wealthy households. As there is little to suggest

    that this market has disappeared, tapping this latent demand once more by

    removing restrictions on smaller, denser dwellings (which can also provide greater

    returns for developers) would increase the breadth of the target market for

    residential construction and thus increase the likelihood of supplying sufficient

    additional housing.

    5.38. Our analysis of the ACDCv3.7 results reveals that the PAUP does not provide

    sufficient capacity for medium-density and other attached typologies to meet

    projected demand, and as a result does not provide sufficient housing choice to

    deliver a well-functioning housing market in Auckland.

    6. CONCLUSION

    6.1. The analysis and views above reveal that the PAUP as notified, even with the

    changes to residential provisions proposed by the Council in previous evidence,

    does not provide sufficient feasible development capacity to give us comfort that awell-functioning housing market — and by extension, an effective-functioning urban

    economy — will result. We consider this position lends weight to the need for further

    ‘up-zoning’ of geographic areas in Auckland for higher density. Alongside the well-

    managed greenfield expansion that the PAUP (and the Council’s Future Urban

    Land Supply Strategy) promises, this will ensure there is appropriate balance and

    choices in Auckland’s housing market.